Skip to main content

Full text of "The land systems of British India : being a manual of the land-tenures and of the systems of land-revenue administration prevalent in the several provinces"

See other formats


the  ppesence  of  this  Book 


thej.m.  kelly 
has  Been  ma6e  possiBle 
thpouqh  the  qeneposity 


Stephen  B.  Roman 

From  the  Library  of  Daniel  Binchy 


LAND-SYSTEMS 


OF 


BRITISH    INDIA 


YOL.  I. 


HENRY    FROWDE 

OXFORD  UNIVERSITY  PRESS  WAREHOUSE 
AMEN  CORNER,  E.G. 


(JUw  ?)orft 
112  FOURTH  AVENUE 


THE 


LAND-SYSTEMS 


OF 


BRITISH    INDIA 


BEING 

A    MANUAL    OF    THE    LAND-TENURES    AND    OF    THE 

SYSTEMS   OF  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION 

PREVALENT  IN   THE  SEVERAL   PROVINCES 


BY 

B.    H.    BADEN-POWELL,    C.I.E. 

F.R.S.E.,  M.R.A.S. 

LATE  OF  THE  BENGAL  CIVIL  SERVICE,   AND  ONE  OF  THE  JUDGES  OF  THE 
CHIEF  COURT  OF  THE  PANJ^B 


WITH   MAPS 

VOL.    \ 

BOOK  I:  GENERAL.       BOOK  II:   BENGAL 


AT    THE    CLARENDON    PRESS 

1892 


PRINTED    AT    THE    CLARENDON    PRESS 

BY  HORACE   HART,   PRINTER  TO  THE  UNIVERSITY 


SIR  DIETRICH  BRANDIS,  K.C.I. E.,  PH.D.,  F.R.S. 

(LATE   INSPECTOR-GENERAL  OF   FORESTS   TO  THE   GOVERNMENT   OF  INDIA) 

I    DEDICATE   THESE   VOLUMES 

AS   A   TRIBUTE    OF    PERSONAL    FRIENDSHIP 

AND   OF   ADMIRATION   FOR   AN   OFFICIAL  CAREER 

WHICH,   MARKED   THROUGHOUT    BY    DEVOTION   TO   THE    PUBLIC   GOOD 

HAS   BORNE    FRUIT    IN    LASTING   BENEFITS 

TO   THE    INDIAN    EMPIRE 


NOTICE 


IN  1882,  the  Government  of  India  printed  at  Calcutta 
a  Manual  of  the  Land -Tenures  and  Land-Revenue 
Systems  of  British  India,  which  was  written  by  me  under 
the  orders  of  Government.  The  edition  was  exhausted  in 
two  or  three  years  ;  but  as  about  that  time  great  changes 
in  the  law  were  under  consideration,  it  was  thought 
desirable  to  await  the  passing  of  the  Bengal  Tenancy  Act 
(1885),  the  Oudh  Rent  Act  (1886),  and  the  Panjab  Land- 
Revenue  and  Tenancy  Acts  (1887) — to  say  nothing  of 
minor  enactments — before  preparing  a  new  edition. 

When  (in  1888-9)  things  seemed  ripe  for  a  new  issue 
corrected  and  brought  up  to  date,  I  found  that  so  much 
had  to  be  altered  and  added,  and  that  such  improvements 
might  be  made,  especially  in  the  chapters  on  Land- 
Tenures,  that  it  would  be  better  to  write  a  new  book. 
The  present  work  is  therefore  independent  of  the  original 
volume,  except  as  regards  a  very  few  pages.  It  has  also 
been  illustrated  by  maps.  In  this  form  it  is  much  larger, 
and  may  be  less  adapted  for  the  purposes  of  some  officials 
who  have  to  pass  an  examination  in  Land-Revenue  subjects  : 
on  the  other  hand,  it  will  have  become,  I  hope,  much  better 
suited  to  the  needs  of  others  ;  and  it  is  certainly  more 


Vlll  NOTICE. 

complete  as  a  general  handbook  of  the  Land-Systems  of 
British  India. 

As  regards  Forest-Officers  and  others  for  whom  the 
present  work  is  too  detailed,  or  contains  too  much  on 
branches  of  Revenue  work — such  as  Assessment — with 
which  they  are  not  practically  concerned,  it  will  be  easy 
to  meet  their  requirements  by  the  subsequent  issue  of  a 
'  Primer '  or  Shorter  Manual  especially  written  for  them. 


B.  H.  B.  P. 


OXFORD  : 

March,  1892. 


TABLE    OF    CONTENTS 


L.R.  =  Land- Revenue.        S.  =  Settlement. 

VOL.    I.— GENERAL,    BENGAL. 
BOOK  L— GENERAL. 

;HAP.  PAGE. 

I. — INTRODUCTORY        .         .         .         .         .         .  1-29 

II. — OF  THE  PROVINCES  UNDER  THE  GOVERNMENT  OF 

INDIA,  AND  HOW  THEY  WERE  CREATED       .  30-75 
III. — OF  THE  INDIAN  LEGISLATURES,  AND  THE  LAWS 

BY  WHICH  INDIA  is  GOVERNED          .         .  76-93 
IV. — A  GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURES  OF 

BRITISH  INDIA         .....  94-240 

SECT.   i. — Nature  of  the  Subject         ...  94 

,,      n. — The  Village       .....  104 

,,     in. — Tenures    arising  out   of  L.-R.  grants 

and  L.-R.  farming          .         .         .  179 
„      iv. — Modification   of  tenures   by  super  im- 
position of  new  interests          .          .  191 
„       v. — The  relation  of  Landlord  and  Tenant  .  206 
,,      vi. — The  nature  of  property  in  land    .          .  216 
V. — A   GENERAL   VIEW    OF    THE   LAND -REVENUE 

SYSTEMS          ......  241-386 

SECT.    i. — Introductory     .         .         .         .         .  241 

„      ii. —  Origin  of  the  L.-R.   ....  246 

„     in. — Ancient     authorities     regarding    the 

'King's  share'       ....  264 


X  TABLE    OP   CONTENTS. 

CHAP.  PAGE 

SECT.    iv. — The  beginning  of  regular  Assessment 

under  Native  rule  .         .         .  274 

„         v. — The  beginning  of  British  Systems      .  281 

„  vi. — The  main  principles  of  the  Bengal 
Settlement  and  what  has  resulted 
from  them  .....  286 

„      vn. — Eesults  of  the  acquisition   of   other 

Provinces      .         .         .         .         .  291 

„  vizi. — The  machinery  of  British  L.-K.  Ad- 
ministration.  .  .  .  .  323 

„       ix. — Resum£   of  the   principles   of   L.-R. 

Assessment  .         .         .         .         .  328 

„        x. — The  modern   question   of  a   general 

Permanent  Settlement    .         .         .  340 

„       xi. — The  Department  of  Agriculture  and 

Revenue        .....  349 

„  xii. — Reform  in  Procedure  for  Re-Settle- 
ments    355 

,,  xui. — Suspension  and  remission  of  Land- 
Revenue  .....  369 

„     xiv. — Conclusion      .         .         .         .         .  373 

Appendix. — (Extract  from  the  Gazette  of  India  of 
3  ist  March,  1888,  being  a  review  of  the  later  L.-R. 
Administration  by  the  Finance  Member  of  the  Governor- 
General's  Council)  .  .  .  .  .  .  .  376 

BOOK  II.— BENGAL. 

I. — THE  PERMANENT  SETTLEMENT.         .         .  .  389-442 
II. — THE  TEMPORARY  SETTLEMENTS         .         .  .  443-500 
SECT.    i. — Introductory     .          .          .          .  .  443 
,,     n. — The  Temp.  S.  Law  and  Procedure  .  450 
,,    m. — The  Orissa  Settlements      .         .  .  473 
„     iv. — The  Waste  Land  Rules      .         .  .  479 
„      v. — The  L.-R.  System  of  Chittagong  .  489 
„     vi. —            „           „        of  the  Chutiya  Nag- 
pur  Districts     .         .         .         .  .  493 


TABLE    OF    CONTENTS.  XI 

CHAP.  PAGE 

SECT.  vii. — The  L.-E.  System  of  the  Santal  Per-  496 
gunnahs  ...... 

,,    vin. —          ,,  „          of  Jalpaiguri  and 

Darjiling           .....  498 

III. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  501-597 

SECT.     i. — General  remarks       .         .         .         .  501 

„         ii. — The  Zammdar  Landlord  .          .          .  504 

,,       in. — Other  proprietary  tenures          .          .  524 

,,       iv. — Eevenue-free  Holdings      .         .         .  527 

„         v. — Proprietary  tenures  of  modern  origin  .  532 

,,       vi. — '  Tenures '  (in  a  special  sense)    .         .  533 

,,      vn. — Laud-tenures  of  Chittagong       .         .  554 

„    vin. —         „          „  .    Orissa       .          .          .  561 

ix.—         „          „       Chutiya  Nagpur          .  574 

,,         x. —          ,,          „       Santal  Pergunnahs     ,  588 

IV. — THE  KELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT        .  598-661 

V. — THE  LAND-EEVENUE  OFFICERS         .         .         .  662-680 

VI. — LAND-KEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE       .  681-699 


VOL.   II. 

BOOK  IIL—THE  SYSTEM  OF  VILLAGE  OH 
MAHAL  SETTLEMENTS. 

PART   I.— THE   NOETH-WESTEEN   PEOVINCES 
AND   OUDH. 

I.— THE  L.-E,  SETTLEMENT  (N.-W.  P.)        .          .  1-97 

SECT.  i. — Introductory     .....  i 

,,       ii. — Early  Eevenue  History  (1801-1833)    .  11 

„     in. — L.-R.  Settlement  Procedure         .  27 

,,      iv. — Principles  of  Assessment     ...  41 

,,       v. — Arrangements  following  the  Assessment  81 

„      vi. — Land  Eecords  prepared  at  S.                 .  84 

Appendix. — Eules  for  Assessment  framed  under 

Act  XIX  of  1873  .  92 


Xll  TABLE    OP   CONTENTS. 

CHAP.  PAGE 

II. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  98-194 

SECT.    i. — General  Remarks      ....  98 

„       ii. — The  Village-Tenures  ....  108 

,,      in. — Revenue-free  Holdings        .         .         .  154 

„      iv. — The  Taluqdari  or  Double  Tenure         .  157 

„        v. — Tenants    ......  167 

III. — THE  OUDH  LAND-SYSTEM        ....  195-267 

PART   i. — The  Land-Tenures     ....  196-255 

„      ii. — The  L.-R.  Settlement          .          .          .  255-267 
IV. — LAND-EEVENUE     OFFICERS,     THEIR    BUSINESS 

AND  PROCEDURE  (N.-W.  P.  AND  OUDH)    .  268-305 

V. — ON  CERTAIN  SPECIAL  DISTRICTS  IN  THE  N.-W.  P.  306-3 18 

SECT.    i. — South  Mirzapur         ....  306 

,,       ii. — Kumaon  and  Garhwal         .          .          .  308 

,,      in. — The  Tarai 315 

„       iv. — Jaonsar  Bawar .          .          .          .          .  316 

PART  II.— AJMEE-MEEWAEA. 

I. — HISTORY  OF  THE  PROVINCE    ....  319-326 

II. — THE  TENURE  OF  LAND  .....  327-330 

III. — THE  BRITISH  LAND  SYSTEM  ....  331-341 

IV. — ADMINISTRATIVE  AND  L.-E.  SYSTEM        .         .  342—367 

PART  III.— THE   CENTEAL   PEOVINCES. 

I. — THE  OLD  SETTLEMENTS  .....  368-405 

II. — THE  NEW  SETTLEMENTS          ....  406—439 

III. — THE  LAND-TENURES       .....  440-499 
IV. — THE    L.-E.    OFFICERS,    THEIR    BUSINESS   AND 

PROCEDURE        ......  500-531 

PART  IV.— THE   PAN  JAB. 

I. — THE  L.-E.  SETTLEMENTS         .         .         .         .  532-608 

II. — THE  LAND  TENURES      .....  609-726 

SECT.  i. — General  Considerations       .         .         .  609 

„     ii.— The  N.-W.  Frontier  Tract           .         .  633 


I                                     TABLE    OF    CONTENTS.  Xlll 

CHAP.  PAGE 

SECT.    in. — The  Southern  River  Tract        .         .  657 

„       iv. — The  Central  Districts       .         .  665 

„         v. — The  Cis-Sutlej  Districts    .                   .  677 

vi.— The  S.-E.  Frontier  (Delhi  Districts)  .  684 

„      vn. — The  Hill  Districts   .         .         .         .  692 

„     viii. — The  Double  Tenure           .         .         .  697 

,,       ix. — Revenue-free  Holdings     .         .         .  698 

„         x. — Tenants           .....  703 
,,       xi. — The  Special  Law  and  Local  features 

of  the  Hazara  District    .         .         .         .  722 
III. — THE   L.-R.    OFFICIALS,    THEIR  BUSINESS   AND 

PROCEDURE 727-771 


VOL.    III. 

BOOK  IV.— THE  EAIYATWAEl  AND 
ALLIED  SYSTEMS. 

PART  I— MADRAS. 

I. — THE  EARLY  SYSTEM  OF  L.-R.  ADMINISTRATION  1-50 

IT. — THE  MODERN  SETTLEMENT  SYSTEM         .         .  51-83 
III. — THE   L.-R.    OFFICIALS,    THEIR   BUSINESS   AND 

PROCEDURE        ......  84—107 

IV. — THE  LAND-TENURES       .....  108-194 

SECT.    i. — History  of  the  Madras  Village    .         .  109 

,,       ii. — The  Raiyatwari  Tenure  of  the  present  day  128 
„      in. — The  Zamindari  and  other   Landlord 

Tenures         .....  130 

,,     iv. — The  Tenures  depending  on  L.-R.  grant  139 

,,       v. — The  Tenure  of  Waste  Lands       .         .  141 

„      vi. — Tenancies  and  Under-Tenancies .         .  142 

„     vn. — South  Canara  .         .         .         .         .  143 

„    vin. — Malabar  .         .         .         .         .         .  151 

„      ix. — The  Nflgiri  District           .         .         .  184 


XIV  TABLE    OF    CONTENTS. 

CHAP.          PART  II.— BOMBAY  (AND  SINDH).  PAGE 

I. — THE  SURVEY  SETTLEMENT       ....  197-247 

II. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  248-306 

SECT.    I. — Introductory     .....  248 

„       ii. — Village  Tenures          .          .          .          .  251 

,,     in. — Modern  legal  definition  of  the  Village 

Landholder's  right          .         .          .  269 

„      iv. — Double  Tenures         .          .          .          .  275 

,,       v. — '  Alienated '  Lands    .          .          .          .  298 

,,      vi. — Eights  in  Trees          ....  304 

III. — THE    L.-E.    OFFICERS,    THEIR    BUSINESS    AND 

PROCEDURE        ......  307-320 

IV. — THE  LAND-TENURES  AND  S.  OF  SINDH    .         .  321-344 

PART  III.— BEEAE. 

I. — THE  SETTLEMENT   ......  345-356 

II. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  357-382 

SECT.    i. — Introductory    .         .         .         .         .  357 

„       n. — Village  Tenures         .          .          .          .  358 

,,     ni. — Tenure  by  Office         .         .         .         .  372 

,,      iv. — Tenure  by  Grant       .          .          .          .  376 

III. — THE  L.-E.    OFFICERS,  THEIR   BUSINESS   AND 

PROCEDURE        ......  383-391 

PART  IV.— ASSAM. 

I. — INTRODUCTORY   ......  392-395 

II. — THE     ASSAM    VALLEY    OR    ASSAM     PROPER 

(History,  Land-Tenures,  L.-E.  Settlement)       .  396-429 

III. —  THE  SPECIAL  DISTRICTS          ....  430-457 

SECT.    i. — Goalpara          .....  430 

n.— Cachar     .                                     •         •  433 

„     in.— Sylhet      .  443 

„      iv. — The  Hill  Districts     .          .          .          .  451 

IV. — THE    L.-E.    OFFICERS,    THEIR    BUSINESS  AND 

PROCEDURE       ......  458-464 


TABLE    OF    CONTENTS. 


XV 


CHAP.                             PART  V.— COOEG.  PAGE 

I. — GENERAL  HISTORY          .....  465-468 

IT. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  469-479 

TIT.  —  L.-K.  ADMINISTRATION    .....  480-482 

PART  VI.-BUEMA. 

I. —  GENERAL  FEATURES  or  THE  PROVINCE  .         .  483-488 

II. — THE  LAND-TENURES        .....  489-508 

III. — THE  L.-E.  SETTLEMENT           ....  509-526 

IV. — THE    L.-E.    OFFICERS,    THEIR    BUSINESS    AND 

PROCEDURE        .         .                   .                   .  527-533 

V. — UPPER  BURMA        ......  534—544 

VI. — THE  ANDAMAN  AND  NICOBAR  ISLANDS  .         .  545-548 

INDEX  OF  SUBJECTS  (ENGLISH)         .         .         .  549-587 

INDEX    OF  SUBJECTS    AND   GLOSSAEY   OF 

TEEMS  (VERNACULAR)     ....  589-632 


LIST   OF   MAPS,   ETC. 


VOL.   I. 

India,  showing  the  sequence  of  Territorial  acquisition 
India,  showing  the  different  systems  of  Land-Revenue 

Settlement 

Table  showing  Surveyed  and  Assessed  Area  in  1886-87. 
Sketch  map  of  Bengal 

VOL.   II. 

Sketch  map  of  the  North-West  Provinces  and  Oudh 
Soils  classified  by  Settlement  officers       .... 
Tract  as   further  classified  by  Settlement  officers  for 

purposes  of  assessment     ...... 

Sketch  map  of  Central  Provinces  showing  distribution 

of  area       ......... 

Panjab  and  surrounding  countries          .... 

Sketch  map  showing  distribution  of  tribes  in  the  Gujrat 

district      ......... 


VOL. 

Madras  Presidency  . 
Bombay  Presidency 

Assam 

Burma  and  adjacent  countries 


III. 


in  a  pocket. 

in  a  pocket. 

to  face  page  375 

»         389 

to  face  page       3 
78 


368 

532 

671 


to  face  page      3 
»  Z97 

»  392 

»  483 


ERRATA 
VOL.  I 

P.  15,  1.  26.     Panjab  also,  dele  also 

P.  19,  1.  6.  The  closing  bracket  should  be  at  the  end  of  the  sentence, 
just  before  the  full  stop. 

P.  103. 1.  6  from  the  bottom,  for  for  read  from 

P.  104,  1.  i,  for  has  read  have 

P.  no,  1.  9,  for  is  read  are 

P.  118, 1.  3,  for  for  instance  read  possible 

P.  172, 1.  3,  for  and  read  or 

P.  183,  note  (last  line  but  one),  for  were  read  was 

P.  197,  1.  20,  for  for  read  from 

P.  232,  1.  n,  after  Malleson  says  insert  (2)  note  reference. 

P.  301,  1.  ii,  for  Sec.  VII.  read  Sec.  VI. 

P.  323  (heading  of  section),  for  Sec.  IX.  read  Sec.  VIII.  and  so  on,  to  the 
end. 

P.  407,  §  8,  shoidd  be  headed  SECTION  II.  THE  PROCEDURE  OF  THE 
SETTLEMENT. 

P.  412,  1.  29,  for  were  read  had  been 

P.  466,  1.  i,  for  from  read  for 

P.  552,  1.  1 8,  for  it  at  all  read  it  all 


LIST  OF  ABBREVIATIONS 


EMPLOYED  TO  INDICATE  CERTAIN  WORKS  FREQUENTLY  REFERRED  TO. 


FULL  TITLE.  REFEKRED  TO  AS 

Fifth  Eeport  of  the  Select  Committee  of  the 

House  of  Commons  on  the  Affairs  of  the 

East  India  Company  (1812).  This  was  re- 
printed at  Madras  in  1866  and  1883  (2  vols.)  '  Fifth  Eeport.' 
Harington's  Analysis  of  the  Bengal  Begula- 

tions,  1821  (3  vols.).    (I  have  used  also  a 

Eeprint    of    the    portion    relating    to    the 

Ee venue    System,    published    at    Calcutta, 

Government  Press,  1866)  .  .  .  'Harington.' 

A  Memoir  of  Central  India,  including  Malwa 

and  adjoining  Provinces,  &c.,  by  Major- 
General  Sir  John  Malcolm,  1824.  (Eeprint 

from  the   3rd  Edition.     2  vols.    Calcutta, 

Thacker  &  Spink,  1880)  ....  « Malcolm.' 

Annals  and  Antiquities  of  Eajast'han,  or  the 

Central  and  Western  Eajpoot  States  of  India, 

by  Lieutenant-Colonel    James   Tod,    1829, 

(Third    Eeprint.     2    vols.  Madras,  Higgin- 

botham,  1880) "Tod.' 

The  Present  Land-Tax  in  India,  &c.  (Lt.-Col.) 

John   Briggs.  (i  vol.  London,  Longmans, 

1830) 'Briggs.' 

VOL.  I.  1> 


XV1U 


LIST   OF   ABBREVIATIONS. 


FULL  TITLE.  EEFERBED  TO  AS 

The    Administration     of    the     East      India 

Company.     John  William  Kaye.   (London, 

R,  Bentley,  1853) 'Kaye.' 

The  Land  Tax  of  India,  by  Neil  B.  E.  Baillie. 

(London,  Smith  &  Elder,  1873)  .         .         .         .       'Baillie.' 
Lectures    on    Indian   Law,    by  W.  Markby, 

M.A.,  one  of  the  Judges  of  the  High  Court. 

(Calcutta,  1873) 'Markby.' 

The  Law  relating  to    the  Land-Tenures    of 

Lower     Bengal.       Tagore    Law    Lectures, 

1 874-7 5,    by   Arthur    Phillips.    (Calcutta, 

1876) 'Phillips.' 

Eeport  on  the  Land-Kevenue  System,  Bengal, 

Behar,  and  Orissa,   1882-83,  submitted  by 

the  Board  to  Government  of  Bengal,  Octo- 
ber 31  st,  1883.    (Calcutta,  Secretariat  Press)     'Report,  1883.' 
Landholding    and    the    Relation    of    Land- 
lord and  Tenant  in  Various  Countries,  by 

C.  D.  Field,  LL.D.     2nd  edition.  (Calcutta, 

Thacker  and  Spink,   1885) 'Field.' 

The  Bengal  Tenancy  Act,  VIII  of  1885  (as 

amended  by  Act  VIII  of  1886),  with  notes 

and   rulings,    &c.,  by  R.   F.  Rampini  and 

M.  Finucane.  2nd  edition.  (Calcutta,  Thacker,    '  R.  and  F.  Ten- 

Spink  &  Co.,  1889) ancyAct.' 

'  Settlement  Report '  (of  various  districts)         .          .         'S.  R.' 


BOOK  L 
GENERAL. 


CHAPTER  I.       INTRODUCTORY. 

„        II.      THE   PROVINCES    UNDER    THE    GOVERNMENT    OF 
INDIA  AND  HOW  THEY  WERE  CREATED. 

„        III.    THE  INDIAN  LEGISLATURE   AND   THE  LAWS   BY 
WHICH  INDIA  is  GOVERNED. 

„        IV.    A    GENERAL  VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURES   OF 
INDIA. 

„        V.      A  GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  SYS- 
TEMS OF  INDIA. 


CHAPTER    I. 

INTEODUCTOEY. 

THE  student  who  approaches  the  subject  of  Indian  Land- 
tenures,  and  of  the  systems  under  which  the  State  levies 
a  revenue  from  the  land,  has  probably  a  vague  idea  that 
he  is  about  to  enter  on  a  terra  incognita  or  to  plunge  into 
some  mysterious  and  unintelligible  darkness.  A  few  words 
of  encouragement  at  the  outset  seem  therefore  desirable. 
I  do  not  wish  to  pretend  that  the  subject  of  land-tenure 
is  free  from  difficulty,  still  less  that  it  is  impossible  to 
be  in  doubt  regarding  many  questions  which  have  to  be 
decided  on  a  comparison  of  more  or  less  fragmentary 
evidence,  some  of  which  is  traditional  and  much  of  it 
matter  of  direct  or  indirect  inference.  Holt  Mackenzie,  an 
eminent  authority  on  Revenue  matters — he  was  Secretary 
to  the  first  Revenue  Commission  which  originated  the  Board 
of  Revenue  for  the  North- West  Provinces — said  that  he 
had  been  all  his  life  studying  land-tenures  without  under- 
standing them ;  and  the  older  text-books  abound  with 
remarks  to  the  same  general  effect.  But  it  should  be 
remembered  that  Holt  Mackenzie  lived  and  studied  in  the 
early  years  of  the  present  century,  when  village-tenures 
were  only  just  discovered,  and  when  everybody's  mind  was 
rilled  with  the  one  idea,  that  the  only  possible  form  of 
land-holding  was  by  a  landlord  who  let  his  lands  to  tenants 
at  a  stated  rent.  The  early  forms  of  property  had  not  been 

VOL.  I.  B 


2  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  i. 

considered.  No  Haxthausen,  Von  Maurer,  De  Laveleye, 
H.  S.  Maine,  or  Seebohm,  had  yet  arisen  to  set  men  think- 
ing and  comparing  and  making  use  of  the  materials  that 
were  to  be  found  in  different  countries.  Sanskrit  and 
Arabic  literature  and  law  were  only  beginning  to  be  ex- 
plored, and  no  one  had  found  out  anything  about  the  his- 
tory of  the  Aryan  conquerors  and  colonizers  of  India *,  still 
less  about  the  so-called  Dravidian  races  which  before  the 
Aryan  inroad  had  formed  organized  States  in  Central 
and  Southern  India,  or  about  the  Kolarian  tribes  whose 
remnants  are  still  found  in  that  part  of  Western  Bengal 
called  Chota  (properly  Chutiya)  Nagpur,  in  the  '  Santal 
Parganas,'  and  in  the  Vindhyan  Mountains  which  divide 
Upper  and  Central  India. 

Our  sources  of  information  have  immensely  multiplied 
since  those  days.  Not  only  have  we  works  whose  chief 
value  is  that  they  suggest  the  right  use  of  materials — tell 
us  how  to  extract  the  pure  metal  from  the  crude  ore  of 
tradition  and  semi-mythical  literature,  and  to  read  the 
meaning  of  ancient  forms  and  customs,  but  we  have  for 
nearly  every  district  in  India  valuable  materials  in  the  form 
of  '  Manuals  '  (for  the  Madras  districts)  and  the  volumes 
known  as  '  Settlement  Reports '  in  other  Provinces.  I  may 
explain  that  when  the  Land  Revenue  Settlement  operations 
of  a  district  (or  part  of  a  district)  are  concluded,  when 
rights  have  been  recorded,  and  the  interests  of  all  classes 
in  the  land  set  down  in  due  form,  and  when  the  assessment 
of  the  revenue  on  the  field,  the  '  village '  or  the  estate  (as 
the  case  may  be),  has  been  determined, — the  Settlement 
officer  gathers  up  the  results  of  his  work  in  a  printed 
volume  (in  English)  which  contains  the  history  of  the 
district  and  all  peculiarities  of  its  locale,  its  people  and  their 
land-tenures.  In  preparing  this  Manual  I  have  studied 
some  dozens  of  such  reports.  They  are  not  indeed  always 
easily  obtained,  nor  are  they  light  reading — especially  to 

1  I  doubt  whether  Holt  Macken-  States   of    modern    Rajputana,    or 

zie  had  known  Col.  Tod's  Study  of  whether  he  knew    of  Col.    Wilk's 

the  Aryan   (Rajput)   tribes   whose  Study  of  the  Hindu  State  organiza- 

last  permanent  home  was   in  the  tion  as  exemplified  in  Mysore. 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  3 

those  who  have  not  official  knowledge  and  experience 1 — but 
many  of  them  are  storehouses  of  valuable  information.  At 
the  beginning  of  the  century  no  such  aids  were  available, 
for  one  of  the  many  misfortunes  attaching  to  our  first  Settle- 
ments in  Bengal  and  Madras  (Permanent  Settlements  as 
they  are  called)  was  that  no  information  about  tenures  and 
agricultural  customs  was  recorded.  The  early  writers 
could  find  in  the  celebrated  '  Fifth  Report  on  the  affairs  of 
the  East  Indies,' presented  to  the  House  of  Commons  (1812, 
and  since  reprinted  in  Madras),  a  multitude  of  unarranged 
and  rather  confused  details  about  the  landholders  in 
Bengal  and  North  Madras  called  'Zamindars,'  but  that  is 
all.  And  without  enlarging  on  a  su-bject  which  must  be 
unintelligible  till  we  come  to  -our  chapter  on  land-tenures, 
I  will  only  say  that  the  tenure  of  the '  Zamindar  '  of  Bengal 
represents  a  late — if  not  the  latest — development  in  land- 
interest,  and  was  the  localized  outcome  of  a  dying  and 
corrupt  system  of  State  management.  The  study  of  it  threw 
no  light  on  the  real  customary  tenures  of  the  country. 

It  is  true  that  I  have  found  a  single  report  of  1796 
describing  the  real  natural  tenures  of  the  Benares  districts  : 
but  I  have  rarely  seen  it  quoted ;  and  all  our  early  authorities, 
who  are  responsible  for  the  dissemination  of  the  idea  that 
Indian  land-tenures  are  unintelligible,  appear  only  just 
to  have  heard  of  '  village '  tenures,  and  to  have  started 
with  the  idea,  derived  from  Bengal,  that  all  land  must 
have  sortie  landlord,  with  tenants  under  him. 

In  studying,  then,  the  land-tenures  of  India,  we  must  be 
prepared  for  difficulties,  and  expect  to  find  lacunce  which 
we  cannot  fill  up  or  only  supply  conjecturally  and  pro- 
visionally ;  but  it  would  be  exaggeration  to  go  on  saying 
that  a  fair  amount  of  clear  knowledge  on  the  subject  is 


1  There  are  also  volumes  of  re-  equally  valuable")  Elliott's  Report  on 
prints  of  special  reports  and  papers  Hoshangabad  (Central  Provinces), 
known  as  '  Selections  from  the  Ee-  Benett's  onGonda  (Oudh),  Ibbetsoix 
cords'  of  the  several  Governments.  on  Karnal  (Panjab\  Roe  on  Multan 
Among  the  notable  Settlement  Re-  (Panjab),  Logan  on  Malabar  ^ Ma- 
ports  I  may  instance  as  samples  dras), and Pedder's Bombay  Reports, 
(but  there  are  many  others  almost 

B  2 


4  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  i. 

unattainable1  with  moderate  study  and  a  fair  memory  for 
facts. 

And  as  to  the  systems  under  which  the  Land-Revenue  is 
assessed  and  afterwards  collected,  there  is  no  excuse  for 
regarding  their  study  as  of  excessive  difficulty,  when  there 
is  scarcely  a  province  that  has  not  its  Land-Revenue  and 
Tenancy  Acts  and  Regulations  besides  many  hand-books 
and  volumes  of  circular  orders,  and  special  Reports. 
In  the  aggregate,  no  doubt,  these  documents  form  an 
extensive  and  even  a  forbidding  literature ;  and  they  are 
often  written  so  as  to  be  puzzling  to  a  beginner,  or  a  non- 
official  reader.  A  guide  to  them  is  necessary,  and  it  is  the 
express  object  of  my  present  work  to  supply  the  need: 
whether  the  object  has  been  in  any  degree  satisfactorily 
attained,  it  will  be  for  the  reader  to  judge ;  but  I  may  ex- 
plain, that  I  have  endeavoured  to  give  only  the  essential 
features  of  the  Acts  and  orders,  confining  myself  to  what 
is  really  important  and  practical,  while  I  have  indicated  in 
footnotes  the  sources  whence  a  more  detailed  knowledge 
may  be  obtained. 

May  I  be  permitted  also  to  add  a  word  of  general 
explanation  as  to  my  method.  It  may  be  said  that  subjects 
are  treated  in  too  positive  or  even  dogmatic  a  manner. 
But  in  the  first  place,  space  is  limited,  and  room  could 
not  be  afforded  for  many  qualifying  and  apologetic  para- 
graphs and  for  repeated  drawbacks  on  the  statements 
made.  Moreover,  a  continued  hesitancy,  a  suggestion  of 
conflicting  possibilities  and  an  atmosphere  of  scepticism 
and  uncertainty,  is  apt  to  be  puzzling  to  a  beginner ;  and  it 
is  beginners  and  '  outsiders '  to  the  Revenue  official  circle 
that  have  been  kept  in  mind.  I  have  endeavoured  to  give 
my  authorities,  and  to  state  as  fact  only  what  is  fairly 
receivable  as  such :  if  any  one  thinks  the  facts  lead  to  other 

1  If   by  '  understanding  '    land-  the  more  modest  task  of  getting  an 

tenures  we  mean  possessing  a  com-  adequate  knowledge  of  the  facts  as 

plete  theory  of  origin  and  growth,  they  are,  or  as  they  have  become, 

perhaps  land-tenures  will  long  re-  then  I  see  no  reason  for  supposing 

main  '  not  understood.'     But  if  we  that  we  are  or  need  be  in  any  such 

mean  that  we  cannot   accomplish  position  of  difficulty. 


CHAP,  i.]  INTKODUCTOEY.  5 

conclusions  than  those  I  have  drawn,  he  will  have  no  great 
difficulty  in  working  out  another  view.  Possessed  in  the 
first  instance  of  a  definite  outline  of  the  subject,  even  if  it 
is  too  strongly  drawn  in  parts,  the  student  who  afterwards 
goes  into  detail  in  Indian  official  life,  will  fast  enough  dis- 
cover where  he  would  prefer  to  draw  the  lines  a  little  more 
faintly  or  uncertainly,  or  where  he  would  desire  to  give  a 
different  colour  to  the  phenomena  of  landholding  customs. 
The  text  will  always  afford  a  sufficient  indication  where 
there  is  room  for  an  interpretation  other  than  that  which 
it  adopts. 

With  these  few  prefatory  explanations  I  may  at  once 
proceed  to  the  direct  subject  of  the  chapter.  I  have  to  dis- 
cuss certain  general  topics  which  it  will  be  useful  to 
explain  by  way  of  preparation  for  the  study  which  we  are 
to  enter  on. 


§  i.     The  term  'India.' 

Sir  John  Strachey,  in  his  admirable  Lectures  on  India l — 
a  work  which  I  advise  every  student  to  read — has  already 
spoken  of  the  dangers  attaching  to  the  use  of  a  general 
term  like  'India.'  It  is  geographical  only.  In  no  other 
sense  is  there  any  one  country  which  can  properly  be  called 
'India.'  Within  the  confines  of  the  area  so  marked  on 
the  map,  we  have  a  series  of  provinces  inhabited  by  different 
races,  and  often  speaking  different  languages.  The  in- 
habitants of  the  Panjab  for  example — even  in  the  same 
province — are  so  different,  that  a  Peshawar  tribesman  in 
the  north  could  hardly  make  himself  understood  at  Delhi 
or  Hisar  in  the  south-east.  Religious  and  other  differences 
divide  the  populations,  and  racial  antipathies  are  not 
unknown :  Sikhs  have  no  love  for  Hindustanis,  and  a 
Bengali  Babu  2  at  Lahore  is  regarded  as  a  foreigner  almost 

1  '  India/  by  Sir  John  Strachey.  family,    then   a   native   gentleman 
London:    Kegan   Paul,  Trench   &  in  general.  It  is  now  commonly  em- 
Co.  (1888).    i  vol.  ployed  to  designate  a  pleader,  at- 

2  The  term  properly  means  a  ca-  torney,  or  office-clerk, 
det  or    younger    son    of   a    noble 


6  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  i. 

as  much  as  the  Englishman  is.  The  mere  fact  that  one 
portion  of  the  general  population  is  Hindu  and  the  other 
Muhammadan  is  in  itself  a  permanent  source  of  difference. 
And  there  is  little  internal  uniformity  among  those  who  are 
called  Hindus,  and  little  more  than  a  semblance  of  it  among 
the  Muhammadan  races,  despite  the  fact  of  a  common  creed 
and  a  common  form  of  worship. 

Those  who  have  read  Sir  A.  Lyall's  Asiatic  Studies 
know  how  protean  in  form  Hinduism  is  ;  local  deities  and 
deified  personages  are  readily  adopted,  thus  giving  a 
different  complexion  to  the  worship  of  each  locality:  in 
fact  there  is  nothing  common  to  Hindus  as  a  body,  except 
certain  social  ideals  and  rules.  Otherwise  the  Hindu  castes 
in  the  several  provinces,  have  very  little  connection.  The 
Sikh  religion,  again,  is  far  removed  from  the  Hindu  ideal ; 
and  the  great  bulk  of  the  peasant  population  of  the  Panjab 
that  is  returned  as  '  Hindu,'  is  so  only  in  the  sense  that  the 
people  are  not  Sikhs  and  are  not  Muhammadan.  They  have 
learned  a  certain  respect  for  Hindu  festivals  and  for  Brah- 
mans,  because  those  ubiquitous  caste-men  travel  everywhere 
and  skilfully  introduce  at  least  a  portion  of  their  ideas  ;  but 
the  Hindu  law  of  the  books  and  commentaries  is  unknown 
to  the  Jat  and  Gujar  and  Rajput  landholding  peasantry. 

Even  among  Muhammadans,  to  say  nothing  of  hostile 
sects  of  Shia  and  Sunni,  great  numbers  are  perfectly 
ignorant  converts,  knowing  nothing  beyond  the  simple 
formula  of  the  faith.  In  the  Panjab,  for  instance,  these 
people  follow  their  local  customs  of  inheritance ;  and  it  is 
perhaps  chiefly  the  action  of  the  law-courts  that  enforces  a 
certain  respect  for  the  regular  law  in  matters  of  marriage, 
divorce,  minority  and  bastardy,  otherwise  it  is  not  known 
or  respected  in  practice.  In  a  word,  the  various  castes  and 
races  in  the  different  provinces  diverge  from  one  another  as 
much  (or  more)  as  the  people  of  Scotland  do  from  those  of 
Naples,  or  the  peasantry  of  Normandy  from  the  moun- 
taineers of  the  Tyrol. 

Common  influences  there  are,  which  have  extended  far 
and  wide.  The  Muhammadan  conquest,  for  example,  intro- 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  7 

duced  the  use  of  Persian  or  Arabic  terms  regarding  land 
all  over  India,  and  with  the  terms,  many  practices  and 
principles  of  Revenue  management.  And  certain  land- 
customs  and  family  customs  derivable  from  early  Dravidian 
and  Aryan  traditions  among  Hindus,  as  well  as  official 
titles  derived  from  the  Rajput  State  System,  may  be 
traced  in  provinces  widely  separated.  But  while  we  shall 
take  note  of  such  wide-spread  influences,  and  make  the 
best  use  of  the  facts  they  disclose,  we  shall  not  be  misled 
into  supposing  that  all  Indian  peoples  are  more  or  less 
identical,  or  their  ideas  the  same.  Of  the  mistaken 
supposition  of  unity  throughout  '  India '  we  shall  soon  meet 
with  practical  examples.  I  shall  shortly  have  to  explain 
how  the  same  conditions  of  life  have  brought  about 
everywhere  the  aggregation  of  the  cultivating  classes  into 
groups,  which  we  call  '  villages,'  but  they  are  not  all  in  one 
form.  Yet  we  find  the  standard  histories  of  India  giving 
general  accounts  of  the  '  Indian  Village '  as  if  the  form 
described  was  prevalent  everywhere  and  one  general 
description  sufficed  for  all.  Another  instance  of  confusion 
is  perhaps  more  due  to  the  use  of  a  common  name  than  to 
any  assumption  of  unity  among  the  provinces.  I  allude 
to  the  term  '  Zamindar.'  We  first  came  in  contact  with  a 
certain  class  of  landholder  in  Bengal  known  by  this  name, 
and  from  the  language  of  some  of  the  earlier  Regulations 
and  minutes,  it  would  seem  as  if  the  same  form  of  landholding 
must  exist  everywhere.  This  of  course  is  not  the  case. 
But  unfortunately  the  vernacular  term  (in  itself)  means 
'  holder '  of  '  land,'  and  so  it  easily  got  used  to  designate 
entirely  different  things.  It  is  applied  to  particular  forms  of 
landed  interest,  entirely  special  or  local,  it  is  also  used  in  the 
widest  sense  to  signify  the  landholding  class  generally.  If 
you  meet  a  peasant  in  Northern  India,  for  example,  and  ask 
him  who  he  is,  he  will  probably  reply,  '  I  am  a  poor  man — 
a  zamindar.'  He  does  not  mean  that  he  is  a  great  estate 
holder. 


8  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  I. 

§  2.    Some  common  geographical  terms  used  in  India. 

While  we  are  on  the  subject  of  India,  it  may  be  well  to 
explain  some  common  terms  used  to  denote  different  parts 
of  the  country  which  have  often  distinctive  features,  though 
they  do  not  coincide  with  provinces  or  express  divisions 
recognized  for  Government  purposes.  In  reading  these  re- 
marks, the  student  should  have  a  map  of  India  before  him. 

Northern  'Northern  India'  is  applied  to  the  part  of  the  country 
which  is  north  of  the  Vindhyan  Mountains,  and  north-west 

Southern  of  Benares  or  thereabout.  '  Southern  India'  applies  to  the 
province  or  Presidency  of  Madras,  including  part  of  the 

Central  State  of  Hyderabad.  '  Central  India '  will  not  be  confused 
with  the  '  Central  Provinces';  the  former  is  an  area  really 

Central  '  <* 

Provinces,  central,  and  consists  mostly  of  Native  States ;  the  latter  is 
a  British  province,  having  its  capital  in  Nagpur,  and  lies 
between  the  Tapti  and  Narbada  rivers  on  the  north-west, 
and  the  Wardha  and  Godavari  on  the  south-east. 

The  The  '  Dakhan,'  commonly  written   Dekkan  or    Deccan, 

T)  *i  k  h  Rn 

is  a  convenient  term  which  is  employed  to  signify  the  part 

of  India  south  of  the  Narbada  river  and  inland  of  the 

Ghats  or  range  of  hills  that  run  down  the  western  as  well 

as  the  eastern  side  of  the  Peninsula  ;  but  it  is  not  employed 

to  include  the  whole  of  the  Peninsula,  and  may  be  said  to 

terminate  southwards  about  the  line  of  the  Mysore  State, 

and  to  include  Hyderabad.     Its  southern  limit  is  however 

The  east     rather  indefinite.     The  eastern  and  western  coasts  of  the 

coasts  and  Peninsula  are  less  commonly  spoken  of  as  the  Coromandel 

their  hill    an(j  Malabar  coasts  respectively.     Alone:  each,  at  a  greater 

^ 

or  less  distance  from  the  sea-shore,  runs  a  line  of  hills 
much  more  continuous  on  the  west  side  than  it  is  on  the 
east.  On  the  west  side  also  the  country  between  the  crest  of 
the  hills  (or  '  Ghat '  as  they  are  called)  and  the  sea-shore  is 
more  distinct  in  character  than  it  is  on  the  east.  The  sea- 
board, for  instance,  below  Bombay  to  the  Kistna  river,  is 
called  the  Konkan  (Concan),  and  southward  of  that  come 
the  interesting  and  specialized  districts  of  Kannada  (Canara 
or  Kanara)  and  Malabar. 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  9 

I  may  mention  that  '  Ghat,'  besides  meaning  the  hillrange  Ghat, 
itself,  is  the  common  Indian  term  for  any  pass,  gorge  or 
passage  leading  into  the  hills,  especially  in  Central,  Eastern, 
and  Southern  India.  Thus  the  visitor  who  has  taken  the 
beautiful  drive  up  to  Ootacamund — the  favourite  summer 
resort  of  the  Southern  presidency — will  remember  that  he 
heard  the  people  talk  of  '  going  up  the  Ghat 1 ' :  so  in 
all  these  countries  the  districts  on  the  uplands  are  said  to 
be  '  above  Ghat '  or  '  balaghat,'  while  those  at  the  foot  are 
said  to  be  '  below  Ghat '  or  '  payin-ghat.' 

We  shall  hear  much  in  the  sequel  of  native  chiefs  whose 
freehold  land  is  spoken  of  as  held  on  the  '  Ghatwali ' 
tenure,  because  they  held  the  land  free  of  revenue  or  on 
privileged  terms,  on  condition  of  maintaining  a  force  to 
keep  the  passes  into  the  hills  clear  of  robbers  and  prevent 
raids  on  to  the  low-lying  lands. 

'  Hindustan '  is  a  term  which  is  properly  applied  to  that '  Hindus- 
northern-central    region   that    lies   above    the   Vindhyan 
Mountains   and  about   the  great  plain   or  valley   of  the 
Ganges  river  as  far  west  as  the  Jamna. 

The  'Panjab' — the  land  of  the  five  (panj,  P.)  rivers  or 'Pan jab.' 
waters  (ab,P.)  properly  means  the  area  bounded  on  the  north- 
west by  the  Sindh  Sagar  or  Indus  river2  and  contained 
between  the  Rivers  Jihlam,  Chinab,  Ravi,  Bias  and  Sutlej 
(Satlaj). 

The  tracts  of  land  between  these  rivers  are  called  '  Doabs  '  •  Doab.' 
(between  'two-'' waters'),  each  distinguished  by  a  special 
addition :  but  '  the  Doab '  par  excellence  is  the  great  tract 
in  the  North- Western  Provinces  between  the  Ganges  and  the 
Jamn&r  vers. 


1  The    word    means    '  Gate '    or  hills,  and  doubtless  elsewhere  in- 

'  pass.'    In  the  case  of  Ootacamund  land  where  the  people  have  never 

there  is  a  long  natural  cleft  or  gully  seen  the  sea,  it  means  the  big  river 

in  the  hills  along  the  side  of  which  of  the  locality.     Thus  in  the  Simla 

the  carriage  road  zigzags  upwards  hills  the  people  will  tell  you  that 

first  on  to  one  plateau  and  then  on  such  and  such  a  stream  (nadi  or 

to  the  higher  one.  nala)  runs  into  the  '  Sagar,'  or  great 

*  The   word   S£gar  is   shown  in  River — Sutlej    in    those     parts— at 

the      dictionaries      as       meaning  such  and  such  a  point, 
'ocean,'  but  in  the  Panjab  and  its 


IO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  i. 

&  3.  Remarks  about  the  Provinces. 

3     \~f 

In  Chapter  II  a  list  is  given  of  all  the  provinces  or 
administrative  divisions  of  British  India.  A  few  remarks 
may  be  here  made  as  to  the  meaning  of  the  names  and 
what  territories  they  include. 

The  Commencing  with  the  north,  I  have  already  explained 

anja  .  ^e  ^erm  <  panja}3 ' — but  nave  to  add  that  the  Panjab  as  a 
province  extends  beyond  the  Indus  to  the  north-west,  and 
includes  also  the  country  beyond  the  Sutlej  up  to  the  Jamna, 
where  the  '  North- Western  Provinces '  begin.  Biluchistan, 
coloured  as  British  territory  on  modern  maps,  is  a  separate 
political  Chief  Commissionership,  and  is  not  part  either  of 
Sindh  or  of  the  Panjab. 

North-  The  '  North- Western  Provinces  '  consist  (i)  of  the  tract 

Western     known  as  <  Rohilkhand,'  because  it  was  the  site  where  the 
Provinces. 

Rohillas  or  Rohelas,  a  tribe  of  adventurers  from  Afghanistan, 

established  a  cruel  and  oppressive  rule  till  they  were  dis- 
lodged at  the  end  of  last  century.  (2)  '  The  Doab '  (as 
already  stated)  comprises  all  the  districts  between  the 
Ganges  and  the  Jamna ;  (3)  and  the  districts  of  Bandd, 
Hamirpur,  Jhdnsi,  Lalitpur  and  Jalaun  are  in  Bundelkhand 
— the  country  which  was  formerly  the  site  of  the  conquest  of 
an  Aryan  tribe  called  Bundela l.  (4)  There  remain  the  dis- 
tricts east  of  Oudh ;  and  the  group  of  permanently  settled 
districts  adjoining  the  Bengal  frontier  which,  speaking 
generally,  form  the  old'  Benares  Province,'  acquired  in  1775. 
The  provinces  as  a  whole  are  called  '  North- Western,'  be- 
cause at  first  they  formed  part  of  the  Bengal  Presidency, 
and  were  '  north-west '  of  Bengal  and  Bihar. 

Bengal.  The  term  '  Bengal '  is  now  generally  used  to  mean  the 
entire  territory  under  the  Lieutenant- Governor  of  Bengal. 
It  includes  (i)  'Bihar,'  i. e.  the  districts  north  of  the  hills 
about  Hazaribagh  (the  Rajmahal  hills),  as  far  east  as  the 
Mahanadi  River.  (2)  Chota  (or  Chutiya)  Nagpur,  between 
Bihar  and  Orissa,  occupying  the  western  part  of  the  pro- 
vince. (3)  Orissa  along  the  south-east  coast,  from  near  the 

1  Its  name  is  still  found  in  books       pronounced  like  the  English  word 
as  '  Bundlecund,'  apparently  to  be      bundle  ! 


CHAP.  i.J  INTRODUCTORY.  1 1 

Subarnarekha  River  to  the  frontier  of  Madras  1.  (4)  The 
'  Santal  parganas '  district  (often  written  Sonthal,  and  also 
called  in  some  bcoks  '  Santalia')  is  a  hilly  tract  of  frontier 
country  lying  to  the  south-west  of  the  Ganges  and  extend- 
ing from  the  river  to  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  boundary.  (5) 
'  Bengal  Proper '  is  the  rest  of  the  Province.  But  it  is 
usual  further  to  divide  it  into  Bengal  (or  Central  Bengal), 
and  Eastern  Bengal ;  for  the  latter  country  is  in  many  ways 
distinct:  it  includes  the  districts  of  Chittagong,  Tipperah 
(Tipra),  Noacolly  (Nawakhali),  and  as  far  north  as  Maim- 
ansingh  and  Rangpur,  while  along  the  mouths  of  the  Hughli 
the  country  is  known  as  the  '  Sundarband/  and  consists  of 
an  extent  of  swampy '  Delta '  country,  intersected  by  tidal 
creeks,  and  covered  with  dense  jungle  and  forest,  except  on 
the  higher  lands  where  cultivation  is  possible. 

'Assam'  has  been  separated  from  Bengal  since  1874,  and  'Assam.' 
though  '  Assam  Proper '  or  the  '  Valley  districts '  refers  to 
the  districts  (beginning  with  Goalpara)  which  lie  along  the 
valley  of  the  Tista  river,  the  province  as  a  whole  includes 
the  group  of  hills  to  the  south  of  the  river,  viz.  the  Garos, 
Khasia,  Jaintiya,  &c.,  and  the  districts  of  Sylhet  and 
Cachar. 

The   '  Central   Provinces '  include  the  old   '  Sagar  and  <  Central 
Narbada  (Saugor  and  Nerbudda)  territories  in  the  north  and    rovinces- 
north-west  as  well  as  the  Nimar  district,  the  Nagpur  districts 
(escheated,  on  the  death  without  heirs  of  the  Bhonsla  king), 
the  '  Chhatisgarh  plain,'  and  Sambalpur.     These  various 
parts  will  at  once  be  understood  by  a  glance  at  the  map, 
and  further  details  about  their  history  will  be  found  in 
Chapter  II  and  in  the  chapters  of  the  sequel  specially  re- 
lating to  the  Central  Provinces. 

None  of  the  other  presidencies  or  provinces  call  for  any 
general  explanation.  Purely  local  details  will  be  mentioned 
in  introducing  the  special  chapters  relating  to  the  various 
provinces. 

1  That  is  the  present   extent   of  of  the    coast   between   the   Subar- 
Orissa.  The '  Orissa '  of  1765 — when  narekha  river  and  the  Hughli  (now 
the    E.    I.    Company    received    the  nearly  conterminous  with  the  Mid- 
grant  of  'Bengal,  Bihar  and  Orissa'  napore  district, 
—referred  only  to  the  small  portion 


12 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  i. 


The 

seasons. 


Two 

principal 

harvests. 


§  4.  Certain  features  connected  with  land. — Seasons  and 

harvests. 

It  may  be  convenient  to  remark  that  everywhere  they 
recognize  three  main  divisions  of  the  seasons — the  cold 
season,  the  hot  season,  and  the  '  rains.' 

But  of  course  there  are  great  local  differences.  In  some 
parts,  as  in  the  south,  the  cold  season  is  only  marked  by 
a  slight  diminution  of  temperature,  and  that  for  a  short 
time.  In  the  Panjab,  on  the  other  hand,  the  climate  is  tem- 
perate from  November  to  March,  and  quite  cold  in  December 
and  January,  often  with  sharp  frosts  ;  while  an  intense  heat 
reigns  from  May  to  September  or  October. 

On  the  southern  part  of  the  east  coast,  the  N.E.  monsoon 
brings  rain  in  November  or  later,  but  in  other  parts  of  India 
there  is  no  rain  at  this  time ;  what  rain  falls  in  the  cool 
season  falls  in  December  or  January  and  is  due  to  other 
causes. 

The  general  rainy  season  is  due  to  the  S.W.  monsoon, 
which  brings  rain  from  the  end  of  May  to  September,  vary- 
ing of  course  in  the  direction  of  beginning  earlier  or  later, 
lasting  a  longer  or  shorter  time,  in  different  parts.  In  some 
parts  the  rainy  season  is  a  matter  of  occasional  downpours 
between  June  and  September ;  in  others  there  is  a  steady 
wet  season  from  the  end  of  May  often  to  half  through 
October.  Again,  there  are  almost  rainless  regions,  where  the 
'  rainy  season  '  does  not  mean  much,  and  where  cultivation 
is  only  possible  by  the  aid  of  river-overflow,  or  canals 
taken  shorter  or  longer  distances  inland  and  wells  sunk 
where  the  subsoil  is  still  moist  by  percolation  from  the 
river. 

The  general  division  of  the  year  into  a  dry  season  (part 
of  it  colder  than  the  rest)  and  a  rainy  season,  has  commonly 
resulted  in  the  people  of  a  large  part  of  India  recognizing 
two  main  harvests,  one  called  '  rabi' '  (A.) :  or  by  Hindi 
names  as  Hari,  &c.,  and  the  other  '  Kharif '  (Sawani,  &c.). 


CHAP,  i.]  INTEODUCTORY.  1 3 

These  terms  will  be  remembered  because  they  constantly 
occur,  and  regulate  many  matters  connected  with  land- 
administration. 

The '  rabi ?1  (or  spring)  harvest,  in  Northern  and  Northern- 
Central  India,  consists  mainly  of  wheat,  barley,  and  a  pulse 
called  by  the  English  '  Gram '  (Cicer  arietinum).  It  is 
often  the  principal  harvest,  sown  about  October2  and 
reaped  in  April  to  May.  The  Kharif  (or  autumn)  harvest 
(sown  as  soon  as  the  rains  set  in)  ripens  in  October  and 
November  or  earlier,  according  to  the  staple  grown.  Sugar- 
cane, which  is  an  important  item  of  this  harvest,  does  not 
ripen  till  later,  and  is  frequently  cut  gradually,  and  is  not 
off  the  ground  all  the  winter. 

'  The  Kharif '  is  the  time  •  when  the  millets  and  maize 
grow,  and  also  fodder  for  the  cattle.  In  Bengal  the  great 
rice  harvest  is  the  Kharif3. 

All  these  dates  and  details  vary  from  place  to  place,  but 
as  a  general  indication  they  will  be  useful. 


§  5.     The  Agricultural  and  the  '  Fasli '  Year. 

When  Akbar  began  his  reign,  he  desired  to  adopt  an 
universal  official  year,  which  should  correspond  to  the 
harvest  seasons  better  than  the  Hijri  year  (with  its 
changing  lunar  months)  or  the  Hindu  Samvat  era.  He 
began  with  the  loth  Sept.  1555  (A.D.),  and  arbitrarily 
called  it '  Fasli  963,'  being  the  Hijri  year  of  his  ascending 
the  throne.  This  era  (which  can  be  found  by  deducting 
592,  or  593  according  to  the  month,  from  the  year  A.D.)  was 
used  for  all  .Revenue  accounts.  The  '  Fasli '  in  use  in  the 


1  Having  once  indicated  the  cor-  general  cultivation  of  rice  is  by  no 
rect  spelling  of '  rabi,'  we  will  here-  means  widely  extended,  and  is  con- 
after  use  'rabi'   (without  accents)  fined  to  Eastern  and  Central  Bengal, 
for  simplicity  of  printing.  to  Lower  Burma,  and  to  the  moister 

2  The  land  having  been  ploughed  parts  of  Madras  and  Bombay.    Rice 
and  prepared  towards  the  close  of  is  locally   cultivated  elsewhere,  of 
the  rains.  course,  but  is  regarded  as  a  luxury 

3  People  have  an  idea  that  the  In-  rather  than  as  a  staple  food. 
dian  populations  live  on  rice.     The 


14  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  i. 

Dakhan  was  begun  by  Shah  Jahan  in  A.D.  1636.  and  is 
somewhat  different. 

The  '  agricultural  year,'  which  is  defined  in  Tenant  and 
Land-Revenue  Acts,  is  fixed  for  the  convenience  of  date  in 
enhancing  rents  and  putting  an  end  to  tenancies.  The 
year  begins  on  some  day  between  the  i5th  April  and  ist 
July,  as  the  provincial  climate  may  render  convenient.  It 
is  not  used  as  a  date  or  era. 


Canals. 

'  Inunda- 
tion ' 
canals. 


Private 
canals. 


§  6.    Irrigation. 

Irrigation.  The  details  of  irrigation  also  affect  many  questions 
regarding  land-revenue  management,  and,  as  we  shall  see, 
originate  some  customs  of  land-tenure. 

Canal  irrigation  is  of  two  kinds ;  regular  canals  which 
flow  perennially,  and  those  called  'inundation'  canals, 
which  only  flow  when  the  rivers  are  in  full  flood,  being 
swelled  by  the  rains  of  the  '  Monsoon '  season,  or  by  the 
melting  of  snows  in  the  Himalaya^  or  both,  as  the  case 
may  be. 

Some  canals  are  small  cuts  made  by  private  enterprise 
and  managed  according  to  local  custom,  as  regards  the  dis- 
tribution of  water  and  the  supply  of  labour,  or  the  cost 
of  labour  for  keeping  the  channels  clear  of  silt.  These 
are  mostly  inundation  canals,  and  have  no  regularly  con- 
structed masonry  head-works  at  the  source. 

In  some  places  on  the  north-west  frontier,  and  I  dare- 
say the  same  is  true  elsewhere,  there  are  curious  customs 
depending  on  the  use  of  water  in  streams  descending 
from  the  barren  hills  which  only  fill  when  a  rainfall 
occurs.  The  successive  rights  to  take  the  water,  and 
the  time  during  which  it  is  to  run  on  to  each  lot,  as 
well  as  the  dams  to  be  maintained  and  the  height  above 
which  they  must  not  be  piled  up,  are  all  regulated  by 
custom. 

Irrigation  from  wells  is  a  feature  of  Northern  and 
Northern-Central  India. 


Hill 
torrents. 


Wells. 


CHAP.  I.] 


INTRODUCTORY. 


In  the  Panjab,  water  is  raised  by  the  Persian  wheel1 
all  over  the  plain  country  as  far  to  the  south-east  as  the 
Sutlej,  where  (for  what  reason  I  cannot  say)  it  gives  way  to 
other  methods  of  which  two  are  found  more  or  less  all  over 
India.  One  consists  in  raising  water  in  a  large  leather 
bag  which  is  pulled  over  a  wheel  by  means  of  a  long  rope 
drawn  by  bullocks :  in  the  other  the  water  is  lifted  in  an 
earthen  pot  or  a  leather  bucket  fixed  at  one  end  of  a  long 
lever-pole,  the  other  being  weighted  so  as  to  let  the  empty 
vessel  descend  readily. 

Modifications  of  the  'well'  are  to  be  found  in  various 
parts,  as  where  a  small  reservoir  is  constructed  by  the  side 
of  a  river  or  channel,  and  some  form  of  wheel  or  lift  is  em- 
ployed to  raise  the  water  ('  Dhenkudi '  of  Bombay,  and  the 
small  wheel  on  canals,  '  Jhalar'  and  'raoti'  of  the  Panjab 
and  Sindh). 

In  the  Panjab  we  shall  find  that  the  area  watered  (or  Customs 
protected,  for  the  whole  is  not  watered  at  once)  by  a  well,  ^h60*** 
and  the  number  of  wells  in  a  village,  is  often  a  matter '  wells.' 
intimately  connected  with  land  customs  and  sharing  among 
co-proprietors.     A  person  has  a  fraction  of  a  well — a  six- 
teenth or  half  perhaps  — or  his  land  is  otherwise  estimated, 
and  he  has  a  share  in  the  water,  represented  by  so  many 
'  turns '  (varhi)  at  working  the  well  in  the  course  of  a  week 
or  other  stated  time. 

In  the  Panjab  also,  and  perhaps  in  other  dry  districts 
also,  the  term  'kuh'  or  well  is  constantly  used,  not 
merely  of  the  actual  water-shaft,  but  to  mean  the  entire 
area  of  land  cultivated  under  or  in  connection  with,  the 
well. 

Tank  irrigation2  is  a  great  feature  in  Ajmer,  in  parts  of  Tank. 


1  This  is  a  skeleton  wheel  fixed 
over  the  mouth  of  the  well  and 
carrying  a  long  belt  or  ladder  of 
rope  to  which  a  seriss  of  earthen 
pots  are  attached.  As  they  succes- 
sively dip  into  the  water  they  fill 
and  remain  full  till  they  come  to 
the  top,  when  the  movement  of 


the  belt  inverts  them  and  turns 
the  contents  into  a  wooden 
trough.  The  wheel  is  fitted 
with  stout  pegs  or  teeth  which 
work  into  one  upright  wheel  or 
drum  moved  round  by  oxen. 

2  The    Ajmer    chapter    contains 
some  rather  curious  details. 


1 6  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  I. 

Bombay,  and  in  Madras.  A  '  tank '  does  not  mean  a  rectan- 
gular masonry-lined  reservoir: — that  sort  of  tank  is  no 
doubt  common,  but  mostly  for  bathing  or  in  connection 
with  a  sacred  place  or  temple.  The  irrigation  tank  is 
in  fact  a  suitable  soil-depression,  storing  up  the  rain  and 
drainage  water,  and  varying  in  size  from  a  pond  filling 
the  upper  part  of  a  small  valley,  to  a  vast  lake  covering 
hundreds  of  acres.  The  tank  is  closed  in  by  an  embank- 
ment of  earth  and  masonry,  or  both.  In  some  cases 
this  is  an  enormous  work,  and  the  bursting  of  it  is  the  cause 
of  great  destruction  to  agriculture.  The  '  tank '  is  always 
so  situated  that  the  rain  water  reaches  it  by  flowing  down 
all  the  water-courses,  hill-sides,  &c.  of  the  neighbouring 
hills — it  is  in  fact  the  catchment  area  of  the  high  land. 
An  escape  is  afforded  in  case  the  water  threatens  to  over- 
top the  embankment.  In  some  cases  the  tank  represents 
a  lake  which  is  never  dry:  in  others,  the  whole  of  the 
water  is  run  off  or  dries  up  early  in  the  season,  and  the 
bed,  enriched  with  slime,  and  moistened  by  the  previous 
soaking  of  the  water,  is  ploughed  up  and  cultivated. 

§  7.  Orthography  of  Vernacular  Names. 

The  mention  of  Indian  provinces  and  some  of  their 
general  features  has  already  led  me  to  introduce  local 
terms,  and  this  again  suggests  the  question  of  the  method 
of  writing  the  native  names  of  places,  and  the  words 
indicating  tenures,  offices,  and  persons,  and  how  far 
tlie  use  of  such  terms  untranslated  is  permissible.  Two 
methods  of  writing  are  possible — one  is  to  endeavour  to  re- 
present the  word  as  pronounced,  by  writing  it  phonetically 
or  with  such  English  letters  and  syllables  as  the  writer  thinks 
will  convey  the  desired  sound.  The  other  is  to  trans- 
literate the  real  word  into  Roman  letters.  Unfortunately 
for  the  first  method,  English  vowels  (at  any  rate)  have  no 
uniform  value  or  sound  maintained  under  all  circumstances  : 
hence  it  is  impossible  to  be  sure  what  sound  is  meant  to  be 
represented.  Especially  in  the  case  of  '  out-of-the-way ' 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  1 7 

words.  It  is  only  a  limited  number  of  words  that  can  be 
phonetically  written  with  fair  certainty.  The  method 
therefore  neither  gives  the  true  word,  nor  does  it  give  the 
real  pronunciation,  because  hardly  two  people  would  read 
the  combination  of  letters  in  the  same  way.  I  have 
adopted  then,  perforce,  the  other  plan,  wherever  possible. 
I  give  the  vernacular  word  transliterated  into  the  Roman 
character1.  At  any  rate  this  represents  the  true  word, 
though  it  does  not  indicate  the  pronunciation. 

But  this  latter  is  of  little  consequence,  because  the  value 
of  the  vernacular  vowels  being  fixed  and  uniform,  the 
student  has  only  to  master  a  very  few  rules  or  principles 
in  order  to  pronounce  quite  accurately  enough  to  be 
intelligible.  And  I  wish  at-  once  to  give  the  necessary 
instructions  applicable  to  the  reading  of  the  vernacular 
terms  throughout  the  book.  Speaking  generally,  the  words 
are  read  as  if  they  were  Italian — or  with  the  '  continental ' 
sound  to  the  vowels.  The  short  vowels  are  printed  plain, 
the  long  (or  broad  sound)  vowels  have  an  accent.  Thus  :— 

Uniformly  sounded  as 

a  —  a     =     must  —  mast 

i   —  i     =     pit      —  peat 

u  —  u     =     pull    —  pool 

Of  the  other  vowels  '  e '  is  always  like  the  French  e  in 
'  te'te,'  so  that  the  Hindi  word  '  pet '  ( =  stomach)  is  pro- 
nounced like  the  English  word  'pate,'  and  not  like  the 
word  '  pet,'  and  an  accent  is  not  ordinarily  required.  In 
a  few  instances,  I  have  put  an  accent  on  the  (6)  so  as 
to  remind  the  reader.  And  in  Southern  Indian  names 
I  have  always  added  the  accent,  because  there  they  use 
a  short  8  sound  as  well  as  the  long  6. 

t  O '  also  needs  no  accent ;  it  is  always  long  as  in '  depot,' 
not  as  in '  pot.'  Thus  we  speak  of  Gond  tribes — Goand,  not 
short  as  in  '  pond.' 


1  In  order  to  indicate  the  origin  is  Persian  ;  Pj.  means  Punjabi ;  A 

of  the  terms,  a  capital  letter  is  often  Arabic,  S.  Sanskrit,  and  H.  a  Hindi 

added:     thus   P.   means  the  word  dialect. 

VOL.  I.  C 


1 8  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  i. 

Of  the  diphthongs,  '  ai '  is  always  pronounced  like  the 
English  '  eye  '  (not  like  'jay ').  '  Au '  is  as  in  '  bough '  (not 
as  in  '  awe '). 

As  regards  the  accented  and  plain  vowels,  short  '  a ' 
has  the  sound  of  '  a '  in  '  organ,'  never  of  '  a '  in  '  pan.' 
As  this  vowel  naturally  inheres  in  every  Sanskrit  or  Hindi 
consonant,  it  is  constantly  occurring,  and  attention  to 
this  one  rule  will  almost  secure  a  tolerable  enunciation  of 
words.  ' Parasu-Rama/  e.g.,  must  be  read  like  the  English 
syllables  purr-us-soo-Rama,  and  not  as  if  it  were  the 
English  '  parasol '  or  '  rammer.' 

The  accented  '  a  '  is  always  broad.  '  Allahabad'  has  all 
the  '  a's,'  except  the  first,  as  in  the  French  '  gateau '  or 
Italian  '  lago/ 

The  '  i '  is  as  in  the  English  '  pit,'  and  the  accented  '  i ' 
as  our '  ee,'  or  'ea '  in '  cheat' ;  thus,  Pitika(Pity-kah),Pilibhft 
(Pee-lee-bheet). 

The  '  u '  is  always  as  in  '  push'  or  'put,'  never  as  in  'jug,' 
'  pug'  (which  latter  sounds  would  be  supplied  by  short  '  a,' 
without  any  accent,  as  above  described). 

The  accented  '  u '  is  always  as  our  '  oo '  and  never  the 
'  you  '  sound  peculiar  to  English.  Thus  read  '  Telugu '  as 
Teloogoo,  not  as  '  Tell-you-gou,'  and  '  puram  'as  in  '  poor,' 
not  'pure.' 

Of  consonants  little  need  be  said.  The  ordinary  reader 
need  not  attempt  the  niceties  of  sound  ;  but  I  may  mention 
a  general  distinction  in  t's  and  d's  (which  are  very  common 
letters),  viz.  that  some  are  dental  (pronounced  with  a  touch 
of  the  tongue  against  the  teeth),  and  others  palatal  (touch 
against  the  palate).  The  latter  are  distinguished  by  a  dot 
under  the  letter. 

These  dots  will  however  not  concern  the  ordinary 
student,  and  are  retained  for  the  use  of  those  who  are  going 
to  learn  the  vernacular  dialects  regularly. 

'  Th '  is  not  sounded  in  any  Indian  dialect  as  a  sibilant 
(i.e.  like  '  thin '  or  '  that ').  It  is  simply  a  hard  '  t '  with  a 
slight  aspirate  after  it. 

The  gutturals  'kh'  and  'gh '  of  Arabic  and  Persian  words 


CHAP.  I.] 


INTRODUCTORY. 


are  indicated  by  drawing  a  line  under  the  two  letters,  thus — 
'kh'  and  'gh'  (pronounced  like  '  loch'  in  Scotch). 

The  Arabic  consonant  'ain  is  a  sound  the  student  need 
not  trouble  himself  to  try  and  pronounce ;  it  is  hardly 
noticed  except  in  writing,  and  is  represented  by  the 
apostrophe  (or  by  a')  at  the  end  of  a  word.  Thus  'jama'  ' 
=  a  total  sum;  ra'iyat=a  subject,  a  cultivating  tenant, 
'  mu'af '  = pardoned. 

As  there  are  two  letters 'k'  in  the  Perso- Arabic  alphabet, 
one  distinguished  by  the  long  '  tail '  and  the  other  by  two 
diacritical  points,  in  the  native  character, — I  use  '  k '  for 
the  former,  and  '  q  '  (without  any  conventional  '  u '  added) 
for  the  latter. 

The  letter  '  y '  is  always  a  consonant,  and  is  never  used 
as  a  vowel  in  transliterating. 

When  an  '  n '  is  intended  to  be  merely  a  nasal  inton- 
ation, not  a  distinct  letter,  it  is  written  with  a  dot  '  n ' 
and  then  it  is  hardly  sounded  :  e.  g.  ganw  =  a  village,  which 
is  pronounced  like  '  gow '  with  a  nasal  intonation. 

'  G  '  is  ahvays  hard,  never  as  in  '  gin,'  which  would  be  the 
'  j  '  sound.  I  have  only  to  add  that  these  instructions  suffice 
for  all  words  in  Sanskrit,  Arabic,  Persian,  Hindi,  Hindustani, 
Bengali,  Marathi,  &c.,  i.e.  for  Northern,  Eastern,  Western 
and  Central  India,  and  to  a  great  extent  in  Madras  also. 
But  in  this  latter  Presidency  there  are  several  separate 
languages — Tamil,  Telugu,  Canarese  and  Malayalam  ;  there 
are  also  many  names  which  are  virtually  Anglicized,  and 
I  have  not  knowledge  enough — if  any  change  were  de- 
sirable— to  restore  a  strict  transliteration.  In  Burma  also 
the  language  is  wholly  different,  with  a  variety  of 
additional  vowel-sounds,  and  a  transliteration  system  has 
not  yet  been  fixed.  In  writing  about  that  province  I 
could,  therefore,  only  adopt  the  common  spelling ;  but  the 
native  words  I  have  used  are  very  few,  and  by  giving 
accented  vowels  the  value  above  assigned,  no  great  error 
will  be  perceptible. 


C  2 


2O  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  i. 


§  8.    Retention  of  Anglicized  Names. 

Where  a  name  of  a  river  or  place  has  become  thoroughly 
English,  I  have  retained  the  familiar  form,  indicating  (if  it 
is  known)  the  real  vernacular  word  in  brackets.  It  would 
be  affectation  to  ignore  the  common  '  Calcutta '  (Kalkatta 
or  Kalighat  ?),  '  Cawnpore  '  (Kahanpur  *),  Oudh  (Awadh  2), 
Lucknow  (Lakhnau),  Sutlej  River  (Satlaj),  Sylhet  (Srihatta 
or  Silhatt),  Chittagong  (Ch^ttagraon)  Lahore  (Ldhaur),  &c. 
The  names  of  Burmese  towns — Rangoon,  Prome,  Moulmein, 
Mandalay,  again,  are  virtually  English  words  ; — they  have 
hardly  any  recognizable  connection  with  the  local  ver- 
nacular names,  and  I  have  retained  them  as  they  are. 

In  conclusion,  I  may  say  that  if  the  student  will  only 
remember  to  give  the  'continental'  sound  to  his  vowels, 
giving  the  accented  vowels  their  broad  or  full  sound,  he  will 
be  able  before  he  has  finished  a  chapter,  to  read  all  the 
Indian  names  without  hesitation,  and  quite  correctly  enough 
to  be  intelligible.  Indian  students  will,  on  the  other  hand, 
have  the  real  words,  so  that  they  can  look  them  up  in 
dictionaries  and  glossaries 3. 

§  9.    Employment  of  Vernacular  terms. 

A  few  remarks  have  also  to  be  made  about  the  use  of 
vernacular  terms — other  than  the  names  of  places.  A  great 
number  of  vernacular  revenue  terms  have  not  only  come 
into  use  in  the  common  speech  of  the  people,  but 
have  been  adopted  into  official  language — many  of  them 

1  The  name  is  derived  from  Kahn  has  been  the  endeavour  to  trace  the 
or  Kahan,  one  of  the  names  of  the  real  form  of  vernacular  words  fanci- 
god  Krishna  (city  of  Kahn),   and  fully  spelt  (and  rendered  absolutely 
not  the  Persian  Khan,  as  sometimes  unintelligible)  by  the  writers  of  Ke- 
said.  ports  and  text-books,  especially  the 

2  But  the  word  should   be   pro-  earlier  ones.     I  have  had  to  conjec- 
nounced   '  Owd,'    not   '  Ood,'   as   I  ture  of  half-a-dozen  possible  sounds 
have  heard  done  (i.e.  as  in  proud —  which  was  right,  and  search  and 
not  prude}.  search  again  in  dictionaries  till  I 

3  I  can  assure  the  reader  that  not  found  it.     Even  so,    I   fear   there 
the   least  part   of   the  very  great  may  be  several  mistakes. 

labour  of  getting  up  these  volumes 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTOEY.  2 1 

being  Persian  terms,  survivals  from  the  Revenue  System  of 
the  Muhammadan  Empire.  How  far  may  we  use  the 
original  words  in  a  book  of  this  kind,  and  how  far  should 
we  use  translations?  No  doubt  the  plain  rule  is,  when 
writing  English,  to  use  English  words.  But  in  matters  of 
land-revenue  and  land-tenure  there  are  necessarily  many 
of  the  local  and  general  terms  which  have  no  exact  English 
equivalent;  they  represent  institutions,  offices,  customs 
and  forms  of  proceeding  which  do  not  belong  to  anything 
English  or  in  England.  Sooner  or  later  the  reader  will  find 
it  necessary  to  know  familiarly  a  few  of  the  common  land- 
terms,  and  when  he  has  mastered  the  not  very  onerous 
task,  he  will  find  the  vernacular  words  both  shorter  and 
more  expressive  than  any  attempted  English  substitutes. 
I  cannot  pretend  to  any  system  in  determining  when  to 
use  an  English  and  when  an  Indian  term  ;  I  can  only  trust 
to  the  method  adopted  proving  practically  convenient. 

I  have  everywhere  used  the  English  word  '  village '  as  Tillage, 
the  commonly  accepted  equivalent  for  the  group  of  lands 
which  is  called  in  Revenue  or  official  language  '  Mauza '  or 
'Dm'  (P.),  or  in  Hindi  dialects  ganw,  grama,  gaum,  &c. 
But  the  reader  will  at  once  understand  that  by  '  village ' 
we  do  not  mean  a  small  collection  of  houses  with  a  green, 
a  few  shops,  and  a  church-spire  rising  above  the  '  imme- 
morial elms ' ;  we  mean  always  a  group  of  landholdings 
aggregated  in  one  place ;  there  is  generally  one,  or  more 
than  one,  group  of  dwellings  situated  somewhere  in  the  area, 
and  the  '  village '  has  a  common  tank,  graveyard  and  cattle- 
stand,  and  probably  an  area  of  scrub  jungle  and  grazing 
ground  attached  to  it. 

Again,  I  may  well  use  the  English  term  Headman  to  'Head- 
indicate  the  person  who  in  some  forms  of  village  tenure  is  man> 
an  essential  part  of  the  community, — an  hereditary  officer 
of  some  consideration.     Even  where  such  a  person  is  not 
essential  to  the  social    constitution    of  the    village,    the 
Government    has    generally   appointed    or    recognized    a 
headman  in  some  form  or  other,  because  it  is  more  con- 
venient to  deal  with  one  man  and  make  him  the  medium 


22  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  I. 

of  communication  and  the  representative.  At  the  same 
time,  while  the  English  does  well  enough  to  replace  the 
great  variety  of  local  names  that  exist1,  it  does 
not  distinguish  between  one  form  and  another,  as  the 

'  Lambar-  vernacular  does.  The  term  '  lambardar,'  for  example,  for 
the  headman,  in  the  North  Indian  and  Central  Provinces 
villages,  at  once  indicates  that  we  are  speaking  of  a  village 
of  the  joint  type  of  which  we  shall  afterwards  hear,  while 

'Patel.'  -'Mandal'  or  '  Patel'  at  once  suggests  the  other  type  of 
village  prevailing  in  Bengal  and  in  Southern  India. 

'  Patwari.'  Another  very  common  Indian  revenue  term  is  Patwdri, 
meaning  the  person  who  keeps  the  village  accounts,  and, 
above  all,  looks  after  the  maps  and  records  of  rights,  and 
registers  changes  in  land  proprietorship  and  in  tenancies. 
Some  books  call  him  '  village  accountant,'  others  '  village 
registrar,'  but  neither  term  is  satisfactory.  Synonymous 
with  Pativdri  (in  Northern  India  and  the  Central  Pro- 

'Karnam.' vinces)  is  the  name  'Karnam'  in   the  South,  and  '  Kul- 

'  Kul-        karni '  in  the  West. 

I  am  tempted  to  illustrate  my  point  by  one  or  two  more 
examples,  because  they  will  serve  at  the  outset  to  explain 
the  most  frequently  used  terms,  which  will  occur  at  every 
page  almost  of  our  reading. 

'  Raiyat.'  The  word  '  ryot/  as  it  is  incorrectly  written,  is  familiar  as 
a  word  to  English  readers,  and  they  mostly  suppose  it  to 
mean  'tenant.'  So  it  does  to  a  certain  extent;  but  it 
marks  also  that  it  is  'tenant'  of  a  sort  which  does  not 
necessarily  arise  out  of  any  contract  between  a  landlord  and 
a  cultivator. 

I  write   it  '  raiyat '  to  save  trouble,  though  in  strict 
accuracy  it  is  '  ra'iyat '  (A.),  meaning '  subject,  protected,'  &c. 
In  Bengal  it  has  always  been  the  custom  to  call  the . 
village  cultivators  under  the  persons  constituted  landlords 

1  The  village  headman  was 'Patel'  headman  is  not  a  natural  part  of 
all  over  Central  and  Western  India,  the  system.  He  is  only  one  among 
'  Mandal '  in  Bengal,  and  in  the  the  heads  of  families  selected  to  re- 
North  '  Muqaddam ' ;  but  there  are  present  them  with  the  Government, 
many  other  local  names.  In  the  and  primarily  to  pay  in  the  revenue 
joint-villages  of  Northern  India  the  due  by  the  body. 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  23 

in  1793,  as  'raiyats';  and  we  shall  see  the  term  continued 
in  the  latest  Tenancy  law  of  Bengal.  Some  of  these  are 
modern  contract-tenants,  but  a  great  many  are  really  the 
descendants  of  the  original  clearers  and  settlers,  who  would 
have  been  regarded  as  owners  of  their  holdings,  but  for 
subsequent  historical  circumstances  and  changes. 

But  perhaps  the  commonest  use  of  the  term  is  to  signify 
the  landholder  who  does  not  claim — or  at  any  rate  has  long 
lost  any  tangible  right  to — the  ownership  of  anything  be- 
yond his  own  field  or  fields.  Such  landowners  exist  all 
over  Bombay,  Madras,  and  indeed  in  other  parts,  where- 
ever  what  we  shall  presently  describe  as  the  'landlord 
village'  has  not  come  into  sight,  owing  to  the  growth  of 
a  landlord  class.  Technically,  the  position  of  such  a  land- 
holder may  be  differently  defined  in  different  parts.  The 
Bombay  Revenue  Code  calls  him  'occupant,'  and  defines 
his  rights.  There  is  no  Code  in  Madras  and  no  definition, 
but  judicial  decisions  have  recognized  the  occupant  who 
pays  revenue  as  de  facto  proprietor  of  his  holding.  Hence 
it  is  very  convenient  to  have  a  term  like  '  raiyat '  to  indi- 
cate the  members  of  village  communities  of  a  certain  type  ; 
and  especially  because  in  its  compound  form  we  can  talk  of 
a  Raiyat-w&ri  village,  and  of  the  Settlement  being  Raiyat-  'Raiyat 
war — meaning  that  each  occupant  is  separately  assessed  ^ivat- 
for  his  own  field  without  responsibility  for  anything  else,  war.' 
as  opposed  to  the  Bengal  '  Zamindari '  system,  where  one 
landlord  engages  for  the  revenue  of  a  considerable — some- 
times a  very  large — area,  including  many  villages  ;  or  to  the 
1  village '  system  where  a  smaller  estate — very  often  a  single 
village — is  settled  for,  and  assessed  at  a  lump  sum,  the  body 
of  co-sharers  of  the  village  or  estate  being  in  theory  jointly 
and  severally  liable  for  the  whole,  and  arranging  among 
themselves,  according  to  their  own  custom  and  constitution, 
how  much  of  the  total  each  has  to  contribute. 

Another  convenient  term  is  'jama','  and  its  derivative  'Jama.' 
'jamabandi.' 

'Jama'  is  Arabic  for  'total,'  and  means  the  entire  revenue- 
assessment  (exclusive  of  certain  road,  education  and  other 


24  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  r. 

cesses  separately  levied  under  special  laws).  To  say  that 
the  'jama'  of  village  A.  is  Rs.  300 '  means  that  the  Govern- 
ment Land  Revenue  demand  on  the  village  as  a  whole,  is 
Rs.  300  each  year.  Or  in  a '  raiyatwdri '  settlement  it  would 
be — the  'jama '  of  the  single  field  or  survey  number,  'No.  703 
is  1 6  Rs.  8  as.' 

'  Jama-  '  Jamabandi '  is  the  account  '  fixing '  or  definitely  record- 

bandi.'  jng  fiandi)  the  Revenue  demand  (Jama).  In  rwiyatwdri 
provinces  it  has  this  meaning  quite  intact.  Every  year 
an  account  is  made  out  showing  what  fields  each  raiyat 
has  held,  and  what  revenue  (jama')  he  has  accordingly 
become  liable  for.  Under  other  systems  the  term  has 
naturally  become  modified  in  meaning.  In  the  North- West 
and  Central  Provinces,  for  example,  it  has  come  to  mean  the 
list  of  the  tenants  and  their  rents.  In  the  Panjab  it  has 
come  to  mean  a  complete  record  of  right,  a  list  showing  con- 
cisely every  holder  of  land,  whether  co-sharing  proprietor 
or  tenant  cultivating  (under  a  co-sharer  or  under  the  whole 
body  jointly),  and  the  payment,  whether  revenue  or  rent, 
due  from  each. 

I  do  not  think  that  terms  like  these  gain  anything  by 
attempted  translations  or  equivalents,  and  I  have  described 
the  meaning  at  some  length,  with  the  double  object  of 
justifying  my  retaining  the  original  words,  and  also,  at 
the  same  time,  familiarizing  the  reader  with  the  words.  If 
he  will  make  himself  at  home  with  the  terms  (headman) 
'  lambardar '  and  '  patel ' ;  with  '  raiyat,'  '  jama' '  and  '  jama- 
bandi,'  he  will  have  taken  a  useful  step  forward. 

10.  Connection  of  the  Land-Revenue  Administration 
^vith  other  branches. 

One  other  topic  demands  perhaps  a  few  words  of  ex- 
planation :  why  is  it  that  the  systems  of  Land-Revenue 
Administration  are  of  so  much  importance  in  India,  that 
everybody  who  aims  at  understanding  the  Administration 
generally,  must  understand  this  first  1 

The  present  book  had  its  origin  in  a  desire  to  bring  a  class 


CHAP.  I.] 


INTRODUCTORY. 


of  public  officers — those  who  have  the  care  of  the  State 
Forests  in  India — into  closer  contact  with  the  civil  admin- 
istration ;  and  it  was  felt  that  to  let  them  understand  the 
land  system  was  the  best  way  to  begin. 

But  for  every  other  class  of  public  officer,  and  for  the 
economist  who  interests  himself  in  the  welfare  of  India,  the 
comprehension  of  the  broad  features  of  land-revenue  ad- 
ministration is  hardly  less  necessary,  if  the  reasons  are  less 
direct  or  less  easily  stated 1. 

The  State  derives  its  principal  revenue  from  the  land :  it 
has  done  so  at  all  times,  and  the  people  are  accustomed  to  pay 
it :  it  is  with  them  the  very  nature  of  things.  The  collection, 
when  once  the  assessment  is  arranged  for  a  term  of  years, 
is  effected  without  inquisitorial  proceedings  and  without 
trouble  or  extortion.  The  population  is  so  largely  agricul- 
tural, and  the  different  classes  so  wedded  to  custom,  that 
the  speculative  administrator  who  should  conceive  the  idea 
of  getting  rid  of  the  land-revenue  would  soon  find  himself 
in  a  position  of  difficulty  which  language  could  hardly  do 
justice  to.  The  '  land-tax '  in  England  is  only  one  item,  and 
not  a  very  large  one,  among  a  host  of  other  taxes ;  it  falls 
on  a  small  class.  In  India  the  land-revenue  is  a  totally 
different  thing.  With  the  necessity  for  fairly  adjusting  the 
amount  of  revenue  which  each  class  of  land  has  to  pay, 
comes  the  necessity  of  thoroughly  understanding  the 
agricultural  conditions  of  the  country,  the  caste  of  the 
people  as  it  affects  their  cultivating  capacity,  the  modes  of 
holding  land,  the  interests  each  class  has  in  the  land,  and 


1  There  are,  indeed,  in  the  case 
of  forest  officers,  special  reasons  for 
requiring  the  study.  Besides  re- 
garding a  '  forest '  as  an  organic 
whole — an  arrangement  of  nature 
destined  to  fulfil  certain  objects — 
a  forest  may  be  looked  on  as  a  piece 
of  property  of  a  particular  kind  ; 
and  when  it  is  so  regarded  we  find 
it  subject  to  peculiar  requirements 
for  its  protection.  Eights  of  various 
kinds  are  claimed  and  exercised  in 
a  manner  which  does  not  happen 


in  other  properties,  and  hence  the 
delimitation  of  forest  boundaries 
and  the  definition  of  vague  rights 
and  interests  are  matters  of  peculiar 
importance.  In  attempting  either, 
the  forest  officer  is  sure  to  be  brought 
into  contact  with  Land  Revenue 
maps,  records  and  officials  of  the 
neighbouring  lands,  and  he  must 
understand  them  all — at  least  in  a 
general  way — to  deal  with  them 
efficiently. 


26  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  i. 

on  what  classes,  and  to  what  extent  on  each  respectively, 
the  revenue  burden  is  to  fall.  Considering  what  a  large 
portion  of  the  total  population  gets  its  living  wholly  or  in 
part  from  the  land,  it  is  obvious  that  the  determination  of 
landed  rights  and  the  record  of  everything  which  concerns 
the  agricultural  and  social  habits  of  the  people  is  an 
immense  business ;  consequently  a  knowledge  of  the 
land  administration  and  of  the  records  it  requires  and  the 
procedure  it  employs,  is,  in  fact,  a  knowledge  of  the  largest 
class  of  the  population  and  of  the  conditions  under  which 
it  lives. 

And  as  the  collection  of  the  land-revenue,  and  the 
management  of  all  the  affairs  that  are  connected  with 
the  maintenance  of  the  land-holders  in  prosperity,  demand 
a  subdivision  of  the  entire  country  into  districts  and  minor 
official  charges,  this  subdivision  and  the  hierarchy  of  officers 
which  it  entails,  naturally  becomes  the  basis  of  the  entire 
administrative  system.  Considerations  connected  with 
it  find  their  way  into  every  department,  the  Post-office, 
the  Irrigation  department,  the  Public  Works  and  many 
others.  Nor  is  the  territory  organized  and  officers  ap- 
pointed to  the  charge  of  each  local  area,  merely  with  a 
view  to  collecting  fixed  sums  of  revenue  at  fixed  dates. 
The  administration  has  to  take  a  sort  of  paternal  or 
'lord  of  the  manor'  interest  in  the  whole  range  of 
agricultural  conditions.  It  is  on  this  account  that  the 
Government  is  sometimes  represented  as  the  '  universal 
landlord.'  The  term,  it  is  true,  is  used  with  some  reference 
to  the  fact  that  the  Government  has  the  right  over  all 
waste  and  unoccupied  land  (as  will  be  explained  in  the 
sequel),  and  that  to  secure  its  revenue  it  holds  in  a  sort  of 
hypothecation  the  ultimate  right  over  every  acre.  But 
there  is  more  than  that.  In  order  that  the  revenue  may 
not  be  reduced  below  what  a  prosperous  country  should 
yield,  the  State  officers — among  whom  the  District  officer 
or  Collector  vested  with  magisterial  powers,  is  the  most 
prominent — have  continually  to  watch  the  state  of  the 
country.  They  have  to  take  note  of  the  approach  of  famine, 


CHAP,  i.]  INTRODUCTORY.  27 

and  by  suspending  or  even  remitting  the  revenue  in  due 
time,  prevent  any  undue  strain  being  laid  on  the  people ; 
they  have  to  watch  the  state  of  the  crops,  the  failure  of  rain, 
the  occurrence  of  floods,  locusts  and  blight,  the  spread  of 
cattle-disease,  all  of  which  may  affect  the  revenue-paying 
capacity  of  the  land.  They  have  to  repress  crime  and  other 
sources  of  social  disturbance,  which  demoralize  and  tend 
to  pauperize  the  people;  to  consider  how  estates  may 
•  be  improved  and  protected  against  famine,  by  studying 
the  requirements  of  the  district  in  respect  of  communica- 
tions which  improve  the  market,  of  canals  which  render 
the  waste  cultivable,  of  drainage  and  embankment  works 
and  other  improvements.  Local  Acts  empower  the  Col- 
lector to  distribute  advances  from  the  Treasury  to  enable 
the  agriculturist  to  buy  stock  and  to  sink  wells  and 
undertake  individual  and  local  improvements ;  and  this 
duty  requires  intimate  knowledge  of  the  land. 

Even  education  is  not  unconnected  with  the  land  system. 
Village  schools  and  the  dissemination  of  agricultural  know- 
ledge are  matters  which  indirectly — or  perhaps  I  should 
say  directly — affect  the  welfare  of  the  villages,  and  thus 
affect  their  power  to  bear  up  against  calamity  and  pay  with 
ease  instead  of  with  pressure  the  demands  of  the  State. 

Every  officer  of  every  department  will  in  some  way  or 
at  some  time  be  brought  into  communication  with  the 
Collector,  his  records  and  his  subordinate  officials. 

The  Police-officer  has  to  deal  with  the  village  headmen 
and  rural  notables,  who,  as  land-holders,  have  by  law 
certain  duties  laid  on  them  in  connection  with  the  re- 
pression and  discovery  of  crime.  The  details  of  offences, 
and  especially  cattle  thefts,  demand  a  knowledge  of  local 
land  customs  and  agricultural  habits  to  make  them  intel- 
ligible. The  Canal  Officer  can  neither  assess  water-rates  nor 
distribute  the  water  without  some  acquaintance  with  the 
land  system.  Even  the  Commandant  of  a  regiment  is 
thrown  into  contact  with  the  local  Revenue  officer,  the 
rural  deputy  of  the  Collector,  for  the  supplies  and  the  carts 
and  camels  he  needs  on  the  march.  In  fact,  I  cannot  think 


28  LAND   SYSTEMS    OP   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  i. 

of  any  public  servant  who  will  not  be  the  better  for  a 
general  idea  of  the  Land  System,  while  for  many  such 
knowledge  is  absolutely  indispensable. 

And  it  also  follows,  almost  without  saying,  that  any  one 
who  aims  at  understanding  India,  its  people  and  its  require- 
ments, and  who  would  gauge  at  their  real  value  the  outcry 
of  half-educated  newspaper  writers  and  students  of  our  col- 
leges at  the  great  capitals,  and  who  would  understand  where 
there  is  really  a  reform  to  be  wisely  introduced,  and  where 
there  is  mere  clamour  and  the  expression  of  a  natural  dis- 
content and  aspiration  that  does  not  know  really  what  it 
wants,  or  what  is  best  for  it, — it  follows  that  for  him,  at  least 
a  general  idea  of  the  land-system  and  of  the  land-tenures 
cannot  fail  to  be  of  primary  value  and  importance. 

I  think  I  have  now  discussed  all  the  purely  preliminary 
questions  that  arise  ;  so,  after  devoting  a  chapter  to  a  brief 
history  of  the  Provinces  into  which  British  India  is  divided 
— describing  how  they  came  to  be,  and  on  what  legal  basis 
they  are  constituted — we  may  proceed  to  a  general  account 
of  the  land-tenures  and  landholdiug  customs  of  the 
several  provinces,  especially  noting  the  factors  which  went 
to  their  making  and  shaping :  after  this  will  follow  an 
equally  general  account  of  the  different  systems  under 
which  the  Land-Kevenue  is  assessed  and  collected,  and  the 
administration  carried  on. 

These  chapters  are  especially  designed  for  the  home  reader 
and  the  non-official  student,  while  I  hope  they  will  serve 
as  a  useful  and  introductory  study  to  all  classes. 

I  only  add  that,  as  in  the  course  of  our  study  we  re- 
peatedly mention  '  Acts '  of  the  Legislature  of  India  and  of 
the  Local  Government's  '  Eegulations,'  and  Acts  of  Parlia- 
ment relating  to  India,  I  have  thought  that  it  would  tend 
to  completeness  to  interpolate  a  short  chapter  on  the 
Indian  Legislatures  and  their  powers.  Thus  the  first 
or  '  General '  volume,  looks  at  the  subject  as  a  whole, 
and  is  intended  to  prepare  the  way  for  the  volumes 
which  follow  and  which  deal  in  more  detail  with  the 
separate  provinces  seriatim.  It  will  be  observed  that 


CHAP,  i.]  1NTEODUCTOEY.  29 

each  provincial  account  is  divided  into  chapters,  the  first 
being  introductory  and  calling  attention  to  any  special 
historical  or  local  features  that  affect  the  administration ; 
the  next  describes  the  process  of '  Settlement/  i.e.  assess- 
ing the  Land  Eevenue ;  the  next  deals  with  land-tenures 
and  customs ;  and  the  last  with  the  classes  of  re  venue- officers 
and  the  powers  they  exercise,  and  with  the  principal  heads 
of  business  which  they  daily  transact  in  camp  or  in  the 
Collector's  office1  connected  with  the  collection  of  the 
revenue,  the  realization  of  arrears,  the  hearing  of  petitions 
and  cases  relating  to  revenue  business,  and  to  the  affairs 
of  the  estates  generally  as  far  as  those  are  of  public 
concern. 

1  In  India  a  public  office  in  the      erry,'   an   Anglicized  form  of  the 
provinces  is  always  called  '  Kutch-       Hindi  '  Kachhahri.' 


CHAPTEE  II. 

OE    THE    PEOVINCES    UNDER  THE    GOVERNMENT    OF   INDIA, 
AND    HOW   THEY   WERE    CREATED. 

§  i.     Introductory. 

BKITISH  INDIA  is  divided  into  Provinces,  each  under  a 
separate  local  government,  and  each  having  its  own  special 
laws  relating  to  Land-Revenue.  It  will  be  well,  therefore, 
to  understand  how  these  provinces  came  into  separate 
existence  for  the  purposes  of  administrative  government. 
The  limits  of  my  work,  however,  preclude  me  from  entering 
on  anything  like  a  historical  sketch  of  the  progress  of 
those  great  and  unforeseen  events  which  led  to  so  vast 
a  territory  being  brought  under  British  rule:  for  such 
information  the  standard  Histories  of  India  must  be  con- 
sulted. I  must  plunge  at  once  in  medias  res,  only  pausing 
briefly  to  remind  the  reader  that  the  history  of  the  British 
rule  in  India  is  the  history  of  a  trading  Company,  which 
in  the  course  of  events  was  entrusted  with  the  government 
of  the  country  until  1858,  when  its  delegated  powers  being 
resumed,  the  Crown  undertook  the  direct  administration 
by  its  own  officers. 

§  2.     The  Presidencies. 

So  long  as  the  East  India  Company1  was,  as  a  body, 
chiefly  concerned  with  trade,  the  charters  granted  to  it 

1  The  title  '  East  India  Company '  (A.D.  1833).  Section  in  says  that 
originated  with  the  Act  of  Parlia-  the  Company  may  be  described  as 
ment  3  and  4  Wm.  IV,  cap.  85  the  '  East  India  Company.'  At  first 


CHAP.  IF.] 


ORIGIN    OF    THE    PEOVINCES. 


by  the  Crown  (from  the  first  memorable  grant  of  December 
3ist,  A.D.  1600,  onwards)  related,  as  might  be  expected, 
chiefly  to  trading  interests. 

The  first  settlements — at  Surat  (A.D.  1613),  on  the 
Coromandel  Coast,  at  Fort  St.  George  (A.D.  1640),  and  at 
Fort  William  in  Bengal  (A.D.  1698) — were  mere  'factories' 
for  trading  purposes l.  These  factories  then  became  '  settle- 
ments,' which  were  governed  internally  each  by  a '  President 
and  Board.'  In  the  course  of  time,  out-stations  or  dependent 
factories  grew  up  under  the  shelter  of  the  parent,  and  then 
the  original  factory  was  spoken  of  as  the  '  Presidency  town,' 
or  centre  of  the  territory  where  the  President  resided.  In 
this  way,  what  we  now  call  'the  three  Presidencies2,' 
Bengal,  Madras,  and  Bombay,  came  into  existence. 

In  1773  the  government  of  the  Presidency  of  Fort 
William  was  entrusted  to  a  Governor  and  Council  of  four 
members.  The  style  of  the  '  Governor '  was  changed  to 
'  Governor-General,'  and  as  such  he  had  a  certain  control 
over  the  other  two  Presidencies,  particularly  as  regards 
the  declaration  of  war  and  concluding  peace.  This  was 
provided  by  the  Act  (13  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  63)  known  as  the 
'Regulating  Act.'  It  was  not  till  twenty  years  after 
(33  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  52)  that  the  government  of  Bombay  and 
Madras,  respectively,  was  formally  vested  in  a  Governor 
with  three  Councillors3. 


the  Company  was  called  'the  Go- 
vernor and  Company  of  Merchants 
trading  to  the  East  Indies.'  Then  a 
rival  Company  was  formed,  called 
c  the  English  Company  trading  to 
the  East  Indies.'  These  two  Com- 
panies were  afterwards  united,  and, 
by  the  Act  of  Queen  Anne  (6  Anne, 
cap.  17,  Sec.  13),  the  style  became 
'  the  United  Company  of  Merchants 
of  England  trading  to  the  East 
Indies.'  Last  of  all,  the  Act  of 
William  IV,  first  quoted,  legalized 
the  formal  use  of  the  designation 
ever  since  in  use.  It  is,  however, 
frequently  used  in  the  titles  of 
Statutes  prior  to  this,  e.  g.  9  Anne, 
cap.  7  ;  10  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  47  ;  13 
Geo.  Ill,  cap.  63. 


1  And,    indeed,   they    were    not 
'  possessions,'  but  the  traders  were 
the  tenants  of  the  Mughal  Emperor. 
The  first  actual  possession  was  the 
Island  of  Bombay,  ceded  by  Portu- 
gal, in  1661,  to  Charles  II,  as  part 
of  the  marriage  dowry  of  the  Infanta. 
This  island  was  granted  to  the  Com- 
pany in  1669. 

2  The  use  of  this  term  has  never, 
even  in  Acts  of  Parliament,  been 
precise  :  sometimes  it  is  meant  to 
signify   the  form    of    government, 
sometimes  the  place  which  was  the 
seat  of  that  government ;   at  other 
times  it  meant  the  territories  under 
such  government. 

3  The  term  '  Governor  or  President,' 
however,  begins   to   appear   before 


32  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 

These  territorial  divisions  of  India,  called  Presidencies, 
could  not  be  authoritatively  defined  from  the  first;  they 
gradually  grew  up  under  the  effect  of  circumstances. 

Territories  that  were  conquered  or  ceded  to  the  Company 
were,  naturally  enough,  in  the  first  instance  attached  to 
the  Presidency  whose  forces  had  subdued  them,  or  whose 
Government  had  negotiated  their  cession.  Thus,  for 
instance,  Bengal,  Bihar,  and  (old)  Orissa,  granted  in  1765, 
went  to  Fort  William;  the  territory  acquired  from  the 
Nawab  of  the  Carnatic  (1801),  the  Ceded  districts  (1800) 
and  the  acquisitions  from  Mysore  (Maisur)  1792-99,  went 
to  Fort  St.  George  ;  and  the  Bombay  territories,  taken  in 
1803-1818  from  the  Maratha  King  or  Peshwa,  to  Bombay ; 
and  so  on. 

No  one  could  foresee  what  course  events  would  take  ; 
and  when  it  is  recollected  under  what  very  different  cir- 
cumstances, at  what  different  dates,  and  under  what 
unexpected  conditions,  province  after  province  was  added 
to  the  government  of  the  Company,  it  is  not  surprising 
that  the  Legislature  should  not,  ab  initio,  have  hit  upon 
a  convenient  and  uniform  procedure,  which  would  enable 
all  acquisitions  of  territory  to  be  added  on  to  one  or  other 
of  the  existing  centres  of  Government  in  a  systematic 

that ;  e.  g.  in  Section'sg  of  the  Eegu-  pany  was  never  sovereign,  its  power 
lating  Act  itself;  and  in  26  Geo.  Ill,  was  always  derivative.  In  1813 
cap.  57.  (50  Geo.  Ill,  c.  155)  an  express  re- 
It  would  be  beyond  the  scope  of  serration  is  made  of  the  'undoubted 
this  work  to  go  into  any  detail  about  sovereignty  of  the  Crown  over  the 
the  powers  of  the  E.  I.  C. :  it  may  be  territorial  acquisitions  of  the  Corn- 
useful  to  state  so  much,  that  the  Act  pany ' ;  and  the  Statutes  from  1833 
of  1773  was  the  first  in  which  the  onwards  speak  of  the  Company  as 
new  position  of  the  Company  as  trustee  for  the  Crown  as  regards  its 
territorial  potentate  seems  to  have  possessions,  its  rights  and  its  powers, 
been  fully  realized.  After  this,  See  also  Field,  §  348,  p.  632,  where 
further  statutes  were  usually  passed  the  learned  author  discusses  the 
about  every  twenty  years,  when  the  question  at  what  time  the  Company 
charters  came  up  for  reconsider-  can  be  held  to  have  begun  to  act  as 
ation,  with  the  general  result,  as  a  Government  (by  delegation  for 
Mr.  J.  S.  Cotton  puts  it,  'of  tighten-  the  Crown).  For  a  long  time  the 
ing  the  authority  of  Parliament  and  Company,  even  after  it  had  acquired 
of  transforming  the  Company  itself  territory,  neither  desired  nor  exer- 
from  a  trading  corporation  into  an  cised  sovereign  rights.  But  the 
administrative  machine' (Statement  treaties  of  1801,  1803,  and  1805 
of  Moral  and  Material  Progress,  Parl.  clearly  show  that  by  that  time  such 
Blue-Book,  1882-3,  P-  3)-  The  Com-  rights  were  exercised. 


CHAP.  II.]  OEIGIN   OF   THE    PEOVINOES.  33 

manner.  The  student  will  not  therefore  be  surprised  to 
find  that  the  legislative  provisions  for  the  formation  and 
government  of  the  provinces  of  India  are  not  contained 
in  one  law,  but  were  developed  gradually  by  successive 
Acts,  each  of  which  corrected  the  errors,  or  enlarged  the 
provisions,  of  the  former  ones. 

§  3.    Method  of  dealing  with  new  Territories. 

Until  quite  a  late  date  (as  will  be  seen  hereafter)  no 
Statute  gave  any  power  to  provide  for  any  new  territory, 
otherwise  than  by  attaching  it  to  one  or  other  of  the  three 
historical  Presidencies.  But  as  a  matter  of  fact,  large 
areas  of  country,  when  conquered  or  ceded  to  the  British 
by  treaty,  were  not  definitely  attached  to  any  Presidency ; 
at  any  rate,  it  was  doubtful  whether  they  were  intended 
to  be  so  or  not.  This  was  especially  the  case  with  the 
Bengal  Presidency ;  it  became  in  fact  difficult  to  say  with 
precision  what  were  the  exact  limits  of  that  Presidency, 
or  whether  such  and  such  a  district  was  in  it  or  not ;  and 
this  afterwards  gave  rise  to  questions  as  to  whether  par- 
ticular laws  were  in  force  or  not. 

The  Act  39  and  40  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  79  (A.D.  1800),  was 
the  first  distinctly  to  empower *  the  Court  of  Directors  in 
England,  to  determine  what  places  should  be  subject  to 
either  Presidency,  and  set  the  example  by  declaring  the 
districts  forming  the  province  of  Benares  (ceded  in  1775)  to 
be  formally  '  annexed  '  to  the  Bengal  Presidency. 

§  4.     List  of  Provinces. 

At  this  point,  and  before  describing  the  further  legis- 
lative enactments  relating  to  the  constitution  of  provinces, 
it  will  be  well  to  give  a  list  of  the  existing  provinces  in 
British  India,  and  to  describe  how  they  were  constituted  : 
then  we  shall  be  in  a  better  position  to  understand  the 
legal  enactments  which  settle  their  territorial  constitution 
and  government. 

1  There  are  Acts  of  1773  and  1793  but  the  Act  of  1800  is  the  first  which 
which  make  allusion  to  the  subject,  directly  deals  with  it. 

VOL.  I.  D 


34 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  n. 


Calcutta 

(Fort 

William). 

•^ 

Madras 
(Fort  St. 
George}. 
Bombay 
(Bombay 
Castle). 
N.W.  Pro- 
vinces. 
Allahabad, 


Lahore. 
Nagpur. 
Ajmer. 
Shillong. 


Bangalore 
(local 
capital 
Merkara). 
Rangoon. 
Port  Blair. 
The  Resi- 
dency, Hy- 
derdbad. 


The  student  will  clearly  understand — 

I.  That  originally  there  were   certain  centres  of  trade 
managed  by  a  President  and  Council,  and  that  in  the  first 
instance  such  territories  as  were  acquired,  were  attached 
to  one  or  other  of  these  three  centres  called  '  Presidencies.' 
And   it   appears  to  have  been  supposed  that  they  would 
embrace  all  the  British  territories  in  India.     But  this  after- 
wards proved  impossible. 

II.  That   the   Presidencies   of  Bengal,  of   Madras    and 
Bombay,  do  not  cover  the  whole  of  British  India,  and  that 
the  following  list  summarizes  the  whole.     The  capitals  or 
head-quarters  are  noted  in  the  margin. 

(1)  Presidency   of    Bengal.      (Lieutenant-Governor  and 
Council.)     This  at  first  included  '  Benares  province '  (1775- 
1800)  and  the  'North-Western  Provinces'  (1801-3). 

(2)  Presidency  of  Madras.     (Governor  and  Council.) 

(3)  Presidency   of    Bombay.      (Governor  and   Council.) 
(Aden  belongs  to  this  Presidency.) 

(4)  The  North-Western  Provinces  and  Oudh.    The  former 
was  separated  from  Bengal  in  1 834.     Oudh  was  annexed  in 
1856,  and  placed  under  a  Chief  Commissioner.    In  1877  the 
Provinces  were  amalgamated,  so  that  the  official  title  of 
the  head  of  the   administration   is  '  Lieutenant-Governor 
and    Chief   Commissioner.'      A    Legislative    Council    was 
formed  in  1886. 

(5)  The  Panjab.     (Lieutenant-Governor,  no  Council.) 

(6)  The  Central  Provinces.     (Chief  Commissioner.) 

(7)  Ajmer  and  Merwara.     (Chief  Commissioner.) 

(8)  Assam.    (Chief  Commissioner ;  separated  from  Bengal 
in  1874.) 

(9)  Coorg.     (Chief  Commissioner.) 

(10)  Burma.     (Chief  Commissioner.     Lower  Burma  ac- 
quired 1824-1852,  Upper  Burma,  1885.) 

(n)  The  Andaman  Islands.     (Chief  Commissioner.) 
(12)  The  Hyderabad  (Haidarabad)  assigned  districts  or 
Berar,  governed  by  the  Viceroy  (through  the  Resident  of 
Hyderabad).     This  constitutes  a  special  territory  as  will  be 
explained. 


CHAP,  ii.]  ORIGIN   OF    THE    PEOYINCES.  35 

§  5.  Notice  of  their  Acquisition. 

Taking  these  provinces  in  the  order  stated,  we  will  now 
give  the  essential  particulars  regarding  each,  seriatim. 

And  this  seems  the  place  to  introduce  and  explain  a 
general  map  of  India,  which  shows  at  a  glance  when  the 
various  territories  were  acquired.  The  States  which  are 
still  more  or  less  independent — that  is,  managing  their  own 
affairs  under  a  native  administration,  but  acknowledging 
the  suzerainty  of  the  British  Crown — are  left  uncoloured  in 
the  map. 

I  will  only  explain  that  the  number  of  colours  being 
limited,  I  could  only  adopt  one  for  each  period  of  years, 
not  one  for  every  separate  war  or  treaty  by  which  territory 
was  acquired.  Thus  in  Madras  in  1800-1  territory  was 
acquired  by  assignments  which  had  nothing  whatever  to 
do  with  the  acquisition  of  the  '  Ceded  Districts '  of  the 
North- West  Provinces  (1801),  though  the  colour  is  the 
same.  On  the  other  hand,  in  1 803,  the  Maratha  treaty  gave 
us  territory  in  various  parts  of  India — viz.  near  Delhi,  in 
Bombay,  and  in  Orissa L. 

§  6.  Bengal  and  the  North-West  Provinces. 

The  Presidency  of  Bengal  was  the  one  which  first  necessi- 
tated legal  steps  with  a  view  to  providing  for  the  distribu- 
tion of  territory.  Madras  never  received  any  territory  that 
was  not  naturally  and  conveniently  attached  to  it.  Bom- 
bay was  also  compact,  and  though  Sindh  (annexed  by  war 
in  1843)  was  added  to  it  as  an  outlying  province,  it  was  a 
natural  addition,  as  in  1843  the  Panjab  was  foreign  terri- 

1  It   is  curious  to   observe   from  thought  to  secure  the  sea-board  and 

this  map,  first,  that  territory  was  to  prevent  the  hostile  action  of  cer- 

not  eagerly — but   most  reluctantly  tain  States.     I  do  not  mean  to  de- 

— acquired.     Certain    powers    that  fend  every  acquisition  of  territory 

continued  to  resist,  e.  g.  Mysore,  were  in  detail,  but  a  study  of  such  a  map 

not  deprived  of  their  provinces  at  will  certainly  exculpate  the  rulers 

once — but  at  first  of  only  such  dis-  of    past    days    from    many    vague 

tricts  as  were  absolutely  needed  for  charges   of    wantonness.      A   large 

security.     It  will  also  be  seen  that  area,  it  will  be  observed,  has  come 

the    annexations    were    not    hap-  to  us  by  escheat  on  failure  of  heirs, 
hazard,   but    arranged    with    fore- 

D  2, 


36  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  II. 

tory  and  Sindh  was  nearer  to  Bombay  than  to  any  other 
centre1. 

It  was  otherwise  with  Bengal.  The  addition  of  Benares 
in  1775  by  itself  would  not  have  been  a  difficulty,  and  even 
the  annexation  of  the  modern  Orissa  (Cuttack  (Katak) 
Balasur  and  Puri)  in  1803  was  not  inconvenient  from  an 
administrative  point  of  view.  But  the  first  Burmese  war, 
in  1824,  gave  Assam,  Arrakan,  and  Tennasserim  ;  and  the 
additions  in  1801-3  to  the  North- West2,  would  have  ex- 
tended the  Presidency  beyond  all  reasonable  limits. 

The  subject  of  territorial  division  was  accordingly  again 

3  and  4      dealt  with  in  the  year  1833  (3  and  4  Will.  IV,  cap.  85). 

cap.  85,  '    This  Act  proposed  to  divide  the  Presidency  into  two  parts, 

sec.  38.       ^0  be  called  '  the  Presidency  of  Fort  William  in  Bengal,' 

and  the  '  Presidency  of  Agra  V 

It  was  to  be  determined  locally  what  territories  should 
be  allotted  to  each. 

§  7.  The  first  Lieutenant-Governorship  (North-West 
Provinces}. 

Though  a  '  Governor  of  Agra'  was  actually  appointed4, 
the  scheme  was  early  abandoned,  and  instead  of  forming  a 
new  Presidency,  the  '  North-West  Provinces '  were  separated 
from  the  rest  of  Bengal  and  placed  under  a  Lieutenant- 
Governor.  This  was  ordered  in  1836,  and  was  legalized  by 
the  5  and  6  Will.  IV,  cap.  52  (1835),  which  suspended  the 

1  Aden,   the  military  station  at  the  Maratha  War  (which  began  in 
the  entrance  to  the  Red  Sea,   was  1803) :    these    were    Etawa,    Main- 
placed  under  the  Governor  of  Bom-  puri,  Aligarh,  Bulandshahr,  Meerut 
bay  for  the  same  reason.  (Mirath) ,  Muzaffarnagar,   Saharan- 

2  These    large    additions    in  the  pur,  Agra,  Muttra  (Mathura),  and 
north-west    (besides    the     Benares  Delhi  (the  latter  including  the  dis- 
territory    above    alluded    to)    con-  tricts    on    the   right   bank    of  the 
sisted  of  the  districts  ceded  in  1801  Jamn&,  now  in  the  Panjab)  ;  also 
by  the  Nawab  of  Oudh,  and  com-  Banda  and  parts  of  Bundelkhand. 
prised  the  country  now  known  as  3  This  attempt  to  attach  the  his- 
the   districts  of  Allahabad,  Fatih-  toric  reminiscences  involved  in  the 
pur,  Cawnpore  (Kahnpur),  part  of  term  'Presidency'  to  Agra,  which 
'Azimgarh,  Gorakhpur,  Bareli,  Mu-  had    never  known   the   system  of 
radabad,     Bijnaur,     Badaon,     and  '  President  and  Board,'  is  curious. 
Shahjahanpur.    Soon  after,  a  subor-  *  See  Notification  (in  the  Politi- 
dinate   of  the   Nawab's  ceded   Fa-  cal  Department)  of  the  1 4th  Novem- 
rukhabad ;     and     not    long     after  ber,  1834. 

followed  the  districts  conquered  in 


CHAP,  ii.]  ORIGIN    OF   THE    PROVINCES.  37 

previous  enactment  ordering  the  creation  of  two  presiden- 
cies, and  rendered  valid  the  appointment  of  the  Lieutenant- 
Governor.  Bengal  was  thus  partly  relieved  and  reduced 
to  more  reasonable  dimensions. 

§  8.  The  Government  of  Bengal. 

But  still  there  was  another  difficulty.  There  was  no 
separate  Governor  or  Lieutenant-Go vernor  for  Bengal. 
The  Governor-General  of  India  was  ex-offi-cio  Governor  of 
Bengal ;  that  is  to  say,  he  had  to  do  the  work  of  a  local 
Governor  in  addition  to  his  functions  as  Go  vernor- General 
with  supreme  control  over  all  Governments.  It  is  true 
that  the  Governor-General  was  empowered  to  appoint  a 
Deputy-Governor  of  Bengal,  but  that  did  not  relieve  him  of 
the  direct  responsibility.  Accordingly,  the  Statute  16  and 
17  Viet.,  cap.  95  (1853),  authorized  the  appointment  of  a 
separate  Governor  of  Bengal,  or  (until  such  an  officer  should 
be  appointed)  a  Lieutenant-Governor.  This  Act  also  looks 
back  on  the  arrangements  made  for  the  North- West  Pro- 
vinces (just  described),  and  again  confirms  them,  going  on 
to  say  that  the  Lieutenant-Governorship  of  Bengal  was  to 
consist  of  such  part  of  the  territories  of  the  Presidency  as 
for  the  time  being  was  not  under  the  new  Lieutenant- 
Governorship  of  the  North- West  Provinces. 

A  Lieutenant-Governor  of  Bengal  was  accordingly  ap- 
pointed under  this  Act1. 

&  o.  Unattached  Provinces. 

0     -/ 

With  this  relief,  the  management  of  Assam,  though  the 
province  was  early  exempted  from  the  Regulation  Law  of 
Bengal,  presented  no  difficulty;  and  even  the  Burma  dis- 
tricts did  not  call  for  any  special  measures  till  several 
years  later. 

1  See  Resolution,   Home  Depart-  Governor  of  Bengal  extends  to  all 

ment,    No.   415,  dated  28th  April,  matters   relating  to  civil  adminis- 

1854.     And  by  order  of  the  Govern-  tration  heretofore  under  the  author- 

ment  of  India,  a6th  January,  1855,  ity  of  the  Governor  of  Bengal.' 
'  the  authority  of  the  Lieutenant- 


38  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH  INDIA.       [CHAP.  IT. 

So  far  then  as  the  territory  actually  attached  to  the 
Bengal  Presidency  is  concerned,  the  matter  was  settled. 
But  before  long  other  territories  also  were  acquired,  and 
they  were  so  large  and  important,  that  some  further  pro- 
vision for  their  government  was  needed;  for  on  annexa- 
tion they  were  not  formally  attached  to  either  of  the 
existing  Presidencies.  Such  were  the  'Saugor  and  Ner- 
budda'  (Sagar  and  Narbada)  territories  (ceded  after  the 
Maratha  War  of  1817-18),  Coorg  (Kodagu)  1834,  Nagpur 
(1854),  the  Panjab  (1849),  and  Pegu  (1852).  How  were 
these  to  be  provided  for1  ? 

It  is  probable  that  at  first  the  case  was  not  thoroughly 
understood  ;  at  all  events,  the  only  additional  provision 
made  by  the  law  of  1853,  was  a  general  power  to  create 
one  other  Presidency  besides  those  existing,  and  if  it  was 
not  desired  to  make  a  '  Presidency '  then  to  appoint  a 
Lieutenant-Governor  of  the  territories  to  be  provided  for. 

But  a  glance  at  the  list  of  provinces  or  districts  just 
given  as  'unattached,'  and  a  thought  as  to  their  geo- 
graphical position,  will  show  that  this  provision  was  not 
sufficient ;  the  '  unattached '  provinces  were  too  far  apart 
to  make  it  possible  to  provide  for  them  by  uniting  them 
under  one  new  '  Presidency.' 

What  are  now  called  'The  Central  Provinces '  were  mainly 
formed  by  the  cession  of  the  '  Saugor  and  Nerbudda ' 
(Sagar  and  Narbada)  territories  in  1817-18  and  by  the 
escheat  of  the  territory  of  the  Bhonsla  family  (one  of  the 
members  of  the  Maratha  Confederacy)  in  1 854 ;  and  they 
were  far  removed  from  the  older  territories.  The  second 
Burmese  war  added  the  rest  of  Lower  Burma,  across  the 
Bay  of  Bengal.  The  important  acquisition  of  the  Panjab 
was  in  the  extreme  north-west  of  India. 

None  of  these  provinces — either  from  their  geographical 
position  or  owing  to  the  requirements  of  their  administra- 
tion, or  both — could  be  attached  to  either  of  the  Presiden- 
cies ;  nor  would  the  Lieutenant-Governorship  of  the  North- 

1  Sindh,  annexed  in  1843,  nad  was  n°t  annexed  till  afterwards 
been  attached  to  Bombay.  Oudh  (1856). 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN    OF    THE    PEOVINCES. 


39 


West  Provinces  bear  extension  so  as  to  include  any  of 
them. 

The  Act  of  1853,  above  alluded  to,  by  which  the  Lieu- 
tenant-Governorship of  Bengal  was  constituted,  had  em- 
powered the  Government  to  create  one  other  '  Presidency ' 
besides  those  existing,  or,  if  that  was  not  desired,  then  to 
appoint  a  Lieutenant- Governor  for  the  territories  in  question. 
This  provision  was  held  to  authorize  the  appointment  of 
a  Lieutenant-Governor  for  the  Panjab,  but  it  was  insuffi- 
cient to  meet  the  other  cases. 

In  the  year  1854  the  deficiency  was  supplied.  By  the 
17  and  18  Viet.,  cap.  77,  provision  was  made  for  the 
government  of  such  territories  or  parts  of  territories  as 
'  it  might  not  be  advisable  to  include  in  any  Presidency 
or  Lieutenant -Governorship.'  Section  3  empowers  the 
Governor-General  by  proclamation  (under  Home  sanction) 
to  take  such  territories  under  his  '  immediate  authority 
and  management,'  or  otherwise  to  provide  for  the  adminis- 
tration of  them.  Under  this  Act  the  '  Local  Administra- 
tions '  under  Chief  Commissioners,  as  they  now  exist,  were 
constituted.  As  they  are  under  the  '  direct  orders  '  of  the 
Governor-General,  the  Government  of  India  is  itself  the 
Local  Government1,  and  the  Chief  Commissioner  consti- 
tutes a  '  Local  Administration '  as  administering  the  orders 
of  the  Local  Government. 

It  would  of  course  be  inconvenient  if  the  Governor- 
General  had  to  exercise  directly,  in  every  one  of  these 
provinces,  all  the  powers  of  a  Local  Government ;  and  there- 
fore, in  1867,  an  Indian  Act  (XXXII)  was  passed  to  enable 
him  to  relieve  himself  of  such  detailed  work,  by  delegating 
certain  of  his  powers  as  the  '  Local  Government '  to  the 
Chief  Commissioners  then  existing,  which  were  those  of 
Oudh,  the  Central  Provinces,  and  Pritish  Burma.  Since 
then,  this  process  has  been  further  simplified  by  inserting 
in  Section  2,  clause  10  of  Act  I  of  1868  ('The  General 


1  The  provinces  under  Lieuten- 
ant-Governors are  called  '  Local 
Governments,'  because  such  pro- 
vinces, though  subordinate  to  the 


Government  of  India,  are  not  im- 
mediately under  the  orders  of  the 
Governor-General. 


4O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  11. 

Clauses  Act '),  a  definition  of  the  term  '  Local  Government.' 
In  all  Acts  passed  after  1868,  when  anything  is  provided 
to  be  done  by  a  Local  Government,  that  includes  the  Chief 
Commissioner  of  any  province ;  in  fact,  the  delegation  of 
the  Governor-General's  power  as  a  Local  Government  is  in 
all  such  cases  implied  by,  or  contained  in,  the  legal  mean- 
ing of  the  term  Local  Government 1.  Of  course  the  term 
has  this  wider  meaning  only  when  the  context,  or  some 
express  provision,  does  not  control  or  limit  it. 

The  powers  of  the  Governor-General  were  further  en- 
larged by  the  46th  section  of  the  24  and  25  Viet.,  cap,  67 
('  The  Indian  Councils  Act,  1861 ').  which  gives  him  power 
to  constitute  new  provinces  and  to  appoint  Lieutenant- 
Go  vernors  for  them.  The  Act  also  makes  provision  for 
fixing  the  limits  of  every  '  Presidency  division,  province  or 
territory  in  India '  for  the  purposes  of  the  Act ;  and  for 
altering  those  limits. 

In  1865  the  28th  Viet.,  cap.  17,  provided  the  power  to 
apportion  or  re-apportion  the  different  territories  among 
the  existing  Governorships  and  Lieutenant-Governorships. 

There  are  also  provisions  of  the  Indian  Legislature 
regarding  minor  divisions  of  territory,  i.  e.  creating  new 
districts  and  altering  the  existing  boundaries  of  districts, 
of  which  it  is  not  here  necessary  to  speak. 

§  10.  Notes  on  the  Provinces — Bengal — Madras. 

I  may  now  add  a  few  particulars  regarding  the  different 
provinces  as  constituted  under  the  laws  above  enumerated. 
The  growth  of  Bengal  has  been  already  indicated.  Madras 
calls  for  no  explanation ;  the  table  at  the  end  of  the  chapter 
gives  the  facts. 

1  The  'General   Clauses  Act'  of  shall  include  a  Chief  Commissioner. ' 

1868 defines  the  term 'Local  Govern-  In  Assam,  where  it  was  not  con- 

ment '  to  mean,  '  the  person  author-  venient  that  this  should  take  effect, 

ized  by  law  to  administer  executive  Acts  VIII  and  XII  of   1874  were 

government  in  the  part  of  British  specially   enacted    to  regulate    the 

India  in  which  the  Act  containing  powers  of  the  Chief  Commissioner, 
such  expression  shall  operate,  and 


CHAP.  II.]  OEIGIN    OF   THE    PROVINCES.  41 

§  ii.  Bombay. 

The  earliest  acquisitions,  leaving  aside  Bombay  itself, 
were  Surat,  Bharoch,  and  Kaira,  which  were  acquired  partly 
from  the  Nawab  of  Surat  in  1 800,  partly  from  the  Gaikwar 
of  Baroda  (one  of  the  Marath^,  confederacy)  between  1 802— 
1805.  Ahmadabad  was  also  acquired  from  the  Gaikwar 
between  1802  and  1817. 

The  Maratha  war  of  1803  was  the  cause  of  some  of  these 
cessions.  The  rest  of  the  districts  were  variously  acquired, 
but  the  bulk  of  them  were  annexed  after  the  last  war  in 
1818.  In  1822  a  treaty  with  the  Nizam  of  Haidarabad 
resulted  in  several  exchanges  and  cessions  with  a  view  to 
simplifying  boundaries  and  jurisdictions.  The  Bombay 
presidency  still  remains  much  interspersed  with  native 
states,  and,  as  might  be  expected,  occasional  lapses  for 
want  of  heirs,  and  some  confiscations,  have  occurred.  Thus 
the  Satara  district  was  acquired  on  the  deposition  of  the 
Raja  in  1837  ;  and  the  part  of  Belgam  that  was  not  ceded 
in  1818  was  acquired  from  the  Raj£  of  Kolapur  in  1827. 

A  treaty  with  Sindhia  of  December  12th,  1860  (also  for 
the  purpose  of  adjusting  boundaries),  resulted  in  several 
exchanges  of  small  tracts  in  Poona  and  elsewhere. 

In  1 862,  the  North  Kanara  district,  which  was  previously 
under  Madras,  was  transferred  to  Bombay. 

§  12.  The  North -West  Provinces  and  Oudh. 

I  have  already  been  obliged  to  include  much  of  what  has 
to  be  said  of  this  province  in  my  account  of  Bengal.  It 
will  only  be  necessary  here  to  repeat  that  the  province 
consists  of  the  Benares  districts  which  came  under  the 
Permanent  Settlement — viz.  Benares  (Banaras),  Ballia, 
Jaunpur,  Ghdzipur,  and  part  of  Mirzapur ;  the  '  Ceded 
districts'  of  1801,  already  enumerated  in  a  footnote;  and 
certain  districts  called  the  '  Conquered  territories,'  acquired 
by  treaty  from  the  Marathas  in  1803.  These  were  Agra, 
Muttra  (Mathura),  Aligarh,  Bulandshahr,  Meerut  (Mirath), 
Muzaffarnagar,  and  Saharanpur,  as  well  as  the  Bundelkhand 


42  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  IT. 

districts  of  Banda  and  Hamirpur.  The  remaining  districts 
of  this  last  local  group,  viz.  Jhansi,  Jalaun,  and  Lalitpur, 
were  acquired  by  lapse,  forfeiture,  and  treaty  after  1840. 

The  Maratha  treaty  of  1 803  also  ceded  certain  territory 
on  the  right  bank  of  the  Jamnd  river  known  as  '  the  Delhi 
territory.'  In  1858  it  was  transferred  to  the  Panjab, 
because  at  the  time  the  mutiny  at  Delhi  made  it  impossible 
to  communicate  with  it  from  the  North- West  Provinces. 
Further  particulars  will  be  given  in  the  next  paragraph. 

The  only  other  addition  to  the  North- West  Provinces 
was  the  hill  and  sub-montane  tract  taken  after  the  Nepal 
war  of  1815  (Dehra-dun,  Jaunsar-Bawar,  Kumaon  and 
British  Garhwal.) 

The  North-West  Provinces,  as  already  explained,  are  under 
a  Lieutenant-Governor,  whose  capital  was  moved  to  Allah- 
abad shortly  after  1860.  The  Province  is  under  a  High 
Court  and  a  Board  of  Revenue. 

OUDH  was  annexed  in  1856,  and  placed  under  a  Chief 
Commissioner.  In  1877  it  was  amalgamated  with  the 
North- West  Provinces,  so  far,  that  the  Lieutenant-Governor 
became  also  the  Chief  Commissioner,  and  is  the  chief  con- 
trolling Revenue  authority l.  The  Board  of  Revenue  does 
not  control  Oudh,  nor  has  the  High  Court  jurisdiction :  the 
Judicial  Commissioner  is  still  the  highest  local  Court. 

§  13.  The  Panjdb. 

The  first  acquisition  of  territory,  which  now  forms  part 
of  the  Panjab,  resulted  from  Lord  Lake's  Maratha  campaign 
and  the  treaty  of  Sarji-Anjangam  (Dec.  30,  1803).  This 
was  the  country  on  the  right  bank  of  the  Jamna,  and  is 
comprised  in  the  present  districts  of  Delhi  (Dihli),  Gurgaon, 
Rohtak,  Karnal,  Hisar,  and  the  Sirsa  tahsil  of  Firozpur. 

1  The  official  particulars  are  to  be  the  Lieutenant-Governor  would  ex- 
found  in  the  Resolution,  Home  De-  ercise  as  such.  The  assimilation 
partment  (Government  of  India)  is  chiefly  effected  by  repealing  some 
No.  45,  Jan.  17,  1877.  In  order  to  of  the  provisions  (in  various  Acts) 
facilitate  the  action  of  Government,  which  require  the  Governor-Gene- 
Act  XIV  of  1878  was  passed  to  as-  ral's  sanction  to  the  Chief  Com- 
similatethepowers  of  the  Chief  Com-  missioner's  proceedings, 
missioner  of  Oudh  to  those  which 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN    OF   THE    PROVINCES. 


43 


The  country  was  at  first  under  the  general  political  con- 
trol of  the  North-West  Provinces.  It  was  then  our  policy 
to  make  the  Jamnd  the  frontier,  and  to  provide  for  the 
districts  beyond  by  granting  them  to  great  chiefs  who 
were  to  receive  the  revenue,  and  be  responsible  for  the 
administration.  The  plan  failed ;  and  after  some  years 
under  the  North -West  Provinces  government,  the  events  of 
the  Mutiny  (as  already  stated)  compelled  the  transfer  of 
the  districts  (1858)  to  the  Panjab1. 

The  next  important  occurrence  was  the  Protection  treaty 
of  1809  with  the  chiefs  on  this  side  (i.  e.  the  side  nearest 
the  British  capital)  of  the  Sutlej.  The  chiefs  became 
alarmed  by  the  incursions  of  Ranjit  Singh,  who  indeed  in 
1806  advanced  as  far  as  the  British  cantonment  at  Karnal. 

The  greater  chiefs  have  since  been  confirmed  as  feudatory 
princes  (Faridkot,  Patiala,  Jind,  Nabha,  and  the  minor 
states  of  Maldr-Kotla  and  Kalsia),  the  others  became 


1  One  of  the  above-named  districts 
— Karnal — as  it  now  is,  does  not 
wholly  consist  of  territory  taken  in 
1803 ;  other  neighbouring  lands 
lapsed  to  the  Government,  and  there 
were  several  changes.  First,  there 
were  two  districts,  Karnal  and 
Thanesar,  and  then,  on  the  abolition 
of  the  latter,  there  was  a  remodel- 
ling of  the  district  of  Karnal. 

The  districts  named  in  the  text  are 
commonly  called  the  '  Delhi  terri- 
tory,' and  were  equally  commonly, 
but  erroneously,  supposed  to  be  the 
territory  spoken  of  in  the  Regula- 
tions of  1803-5  which  provided  for  the 
administration  of  the  '  Conquered 
districts.'  The  territory  therein  de- 
clared exempt  from  the  Regulations 
was  only  the  country  round  the  city  of 
Delhi,  including  the  'taiyul'  villages 
— lands  the  income  of  which  went 
to  the  privy  purse  of  the  titular 
king  of  Delhi,  and  certain  other 
tracts,  the  revenues  of  which  were  assigned 
for  the  expenses  of  the  Court.  Certainly 
Karnal  as  it  then  was,  and  Hisar, 
Rohtak,  &c.,  though  called  the  Delhi 
territory,  were  never  assigned  for  the 
support  of  the  king  of  Delhi.  The 
fact  is  that  the  Regulations  ignored 
the  country  on  the  right  bank  of 
the  Jamna.  Reg.  VIII  of  1805  pro- 


fesses to  provide  for  the  whole  of  the 
conquered  territories :  but  by  the 
direction  to  form  them  into  districts, 
and  then  specifying  the  law  applic- 
able to  those  districts,  the  country  we 
are  speaking  of  is  virtually  excluded, 
because  geographically  it  never  was 
or  could  be  included  in  any  of  the  five 
districts  prescribed  by  the  Regula- 
tion. Legally  then  the  Regulation 
law  generally  applied,  but  practically 
there  was  no  one  to  administer  it, 
as  most  of  the  territory  had  been 
granted  to  native  chiefs  under  poli- 
tical control  only.  Karnal  was  (for 
example)  granted  to  the  Mandal 
family,  who  still  hold  the  pargana 
of  Karnal.  As  a  whole,  the  plan 
failed,  and  some  of  the  chiefs  re- 
signed their  grants.  Gradually 
these  districts  came  under  British 
Government,  and  the  grantees 
(such  of  them  as  remained)  became 
great  private  estate  holders  under 
the  Government.  In  1832,  Reg.  V 
was  passed  to  declare  the  laws  in 
force,  and  British  officers  made  the 
Revenue  Settlements.  This  Regula- 
tion was  repealed  in  1858  (Act 
XXXVIII),  and  since  then  the  dis- 
tricts have  been  under  the  Panjab, 
and  of  course  subject  to  the  ordinary 
Panjab  law. 


44  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  IT. 

'jagirdars'  or  smaller  chiefs  to  whom  the  revenue  of  the 
territory  was  granted.  Some  of  the  states  have  since  lapsed 
from  failure  of  heirs,  e.g.  part  of  Jind  in  1834,  Kaithal 
(now  part  of  Karnal  district)  in  1843,  and  Thanesar  in 
I85O1.  In  1845  the  Ladwa  state  was  forfeited  for 
rebellion,  and  now  forms  part  of  Karnal  district. 

In  this  part  of  the  country  there  have  naturally  been 
minor  exchanges  of  villages  and  adjustments  of  boundary 
which  it  is  not  necessary  to  detail. 

Things  so  remained  till  Ranjit  Singh's  death,  and  some 
years  afterwards,  when  the  Darbar  (or  Sikh  Court)  was 
foolishly  moved  to  interfere  on  the  other  side  of  the  Sutlej  ; 
this  led  to  the  first  Sikh  war,  and  the  annexation  of  the 
cis-Sutlej  districts,  Firozpur,  Ludiana,  Ambdla2,  as  well 
as  (for  security)  the  districts  of  Jalandhar,  Hushyarpur, 
and  Kangra,  which  were  trans-Sutlej,  or  between  the  Sutlej 
and  the  Bias  Rivers.  A  British  Resident  was  appointed  to 
aid  the  Darbar  in  administering  the  Panjab  to  the  north- 
west of  the  Bias  River;  but  a  second  Sikh  war  broke 
out,  and,  in  1 849,  Lord  Dalhousie  (very  reluctantly)  annexed 
the  whole. 

The  province  was  not  attached  to  any  presidency, 
but  simply  annexed  to  the  British  dominion ;  hence 

1  Thanesar  was   at   first  formed  or  great  over-lord  of  the  whole, 

into   a  separate    district,   but  was  2  Ambala  was    only  partly   an- 

afterwards    divided   between    Am-  nexed :    most  of  it  is  made  up  of 

bala  and  Karnal  districts.  territory  which  lapsed  to  Govern- 

The  history  of  the  Sikhs  is  a  very  ment  by  failure  of  heirs.      A  cer- 

interesting    one,  but  I  cannot,  of  tain  number  of  the  cis-Sutlej  chiefs 

course,  go  into  it.     By  the  Treaty  of  intrigued  with  the  Sikhs  before  the 

1809,  the  states  cis-Sutlej  were  pro-  war.      Ladwa   was   confiscated    on 

tected  from  being  swallowed  up  by  this  account,  and  on  the  conclusion 

the  power  of  Ranjit  Singh.    At  first,  of  the  war.  safety  was  secured  by 

the  reader  will  remember,  a  number  acknowledging    sovereign     powers 

of  Sikh  chiefs,  with  their  followers,  only  to  the  greater  (and  thoroughly 

each  conquering  and  holding  what  loyal  i    chiefs,    Patiala,    Jind,    and 

territory  he  could  (as  his  taluqa  or  Nabha.  of  the  Phulkian  misl,  while 

state),  formed  a  number  of  groups  sovereign  powers  were  withdrawn 

called '  misl,'  confederated  together,  from  the  petty  territories.     It  was 

till  Raja  Mahan  Singh  of  the  Sukr-  obviously  impossible  long  to  tolerate, 

chakya  misl  began  to  take  the  lead  among  the  British  districts,  a  series 

and  reduce  the  others  to  subjection.  of  semi-independent  kingdoms,  each 

The  plan  was  consummated  by  the  the  size  of  half  a  county,  and  at  bitter 

force  and  genius  of  his  son  Ranjit  enmity  one  with  the  other. 
Singh,  who  became  the  '  Maharaja ' 


CHAP,  ii.]  ORIGIN    OF   THE    PEOVINCES.  45 

the  Regulations  did  not  apply.  A  despatch  (dated  3ist 
March,  1849)  from  the  Governor-General,  gave  direc- 
tions as  to  the  form  and  method  of  administration,  and 
appointed  a  '  Board  of  Administration '  consisting  of  three 
members.  By  the  Government  of  India,  Notif.  No.  660, 
dated  4th  February,  1853,  a  single  Chief  Commissioner  was 
substituted.  (Differences  of  opinion  arose  in  the  Board, 
and,  as  might  be  expected,  it  was  found  that  the  responsible 
executive  functions  in  a  province  must  be  in  a  single  hand.) 
The  Chief  Commissioner  was  assisted  by  a  Financial  Com- 
missioner and  a  Judicial  Commissioner  as  the  chief  Revenue 
and  Judicial  authorities  under  Government.  Lastly,  by 
Notification  No.  i,  dated  ist  January,  1 859  (under  the  16  and 
17  Viet.,  cap.  95)  the  Governor-General  'proclaimed  that  a 
separate  Lieutenant-Governorship  for  the  territories  on  the 
extreme  northern  frontier  of  Her  Majesty's  Indian  Empire 
shall  be  established,  and  that  the  Panjab  and  the  tracts 
commonly  called  the  trans-Sutlej  States,  the  cis-Sutlej 
States,  and  the  Delhi  territory,  shall  be  the  jurisdiction  of 
the  Lieutenant-Governor.'  These  limits  are  maintained  to 
the  present  day.  As  they  include  more  than  the  Panjab 
proper,  the  official  style  is  'Lieutenant-Governor  of  the 
Panjab  and  its  dependencies/  The  Chief  Court  (virtually 
a  High  Court,  but  not  by  Royal  Charter)  has  become  the  chief 
judicial  controlling  authority  (Act  IV  of  1866),  and  there 
are  now  two  Financial  Commissioners  for  Revenue  control. 

§  14.    The  Central  Provinces. 

It  will  be  observed  that  there  are  certain  groups  which 
will  facilitate  the  remembrance  of  the  main  parts — (i) 
Nimdr;  (2)  the  districts  adjoining  the  Tapti  and  Narbada 
rivers  in  the  North ;  (3)  the  Central  districts ;  (4)  Sambalpur ; 
and  (5)  the  small  tract  in  the  south  on  the  Godavari 
river. 

(i)  The  first  portions  of  Nimar  were  acquired  after  the 
Maratha  war  from  Sindhia  in  1818.  But  the  rest  of  the 
district  was  made  over  to  our  management,  the  northern 


46  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  n. 

part   in   1820-25,  the   southern   (adjoining  the  Tapti)  in 
1844.     The  sovereignty  of  both  was  ceded  in  1860. 

(2)  Of  the  Northern  districts,  Baitul,  Seoni,  Jabalpur1, 
and  Mandla  were  ceded  after  the  war,  in  1818,  so  was  most 
of  Narsinghpur,  and  Hoshangabad.     A  few  parganas   of 
Narsinghpur  north  of  the  Tapti  were  first  made  over  to 
British  management  (1820-5)  and  ceded  in  1860,  and  the 
southern  part  of  Hoshangabad  (Harda-Handia)  was  made 
over  in  1844,  and   ceded   in    1860.      The   two    northern 
districts,  Sagar  and  Damoh,  were  acquired  piecemeal ;  por- 
tions of  both  were  acquired  in    1818  from  the   Bhonsla 
Marathas  of  Nagpur,  and  from  the  Peshwa  ;  and  the  rest, 
having  been  made  over  for  management  in  1820-5,  was 
ceded  in   [86o2.      One  pargana  (Shahgarh)  in  Sagar  was 
forfeited  for  rebellion  in  1 857. 

(3)  The  central  districts,  escheated  for  want  of  heirs  in 
1854.     The  same  was  the  case  with  Sambalpur  (4)  in  1849. 

Lastly,  the  tract  now  called  the  Sironcha  tahsil  of  the 
Chanda  district,  along  the  Godavari,  was  ceded  by  the 
Nizam  (in  exchange  for  other  lands)  in  1860. 

By  Resolution  (Foreign  Department,  No.  9  of  2nd  No- 
vember, 1861)  the  Chief  Commissionership  of  the  Central 
Provinces  was  constituted.  The  notification  contains  a 
long  history  of  the  administration  of  these  provinces.  It 
recites  that  Nagpur  had  been  under  a  Commissioner  as 
Agent  for  the  Governor-General.  The  Sagar  and  Narbada 
districts  had  at  various  times  been  transferred  from  one 
Government  to  another.  They  were  originally  under  the 
Supreme  Government  ;  subsequently  they  were  placed 
under  the  Lieutenant-Governor  of  the  North- West  Pro- 
vinces. Again,  in  1842,  the  general  control  of  them  was 
vested  in  a  Commissioner  and  Governor-General's  Agent, 
in  direct  communication  with  the  Supreme  Government, 
while  the  supervision  of  fiscal  and  judicial  affairs  re- 

1  The     north-east     pargana      of  were     further    altered     by    some 
Jabalpur   formed  a   separate   state  transfers  from  British  territory  in 
(Bijragogarh),  which  was  forfeited  Bundelkhand,  but  that  was  an  ad- 
for  mutiny  in  1857.  ministrative  transfer  not  a  territo- 

2  Both  Sagar  and  Damoh  districts  rial  acquisition. 


CHAP,  ii.]  OEIGIN    OF   THE    PEOVINCES.  47 

inained  with  the  Sudder  Board  and  Sudder  Court 
of  the  North-West  Provinces  respectively.  After  this, 
the  general  jurisdiction  was  again  transferred  to  the 
Lieutenant-Governor  of  the  North- West  Provinces,  and 
so  remained  till  the  notification  issued  in  1861.  Nimar 
had  been  managed  chiefly  as  an  '  assigned  district '  till  its 
cession  as  a  whole  in  1860.  Sambalpur  was  added  to  the 
Central  Provinces  in  1862,  Nimar  in  1864,  and  a  small 
estate  called  Bijragogarh  in  1865.  The  fact  that  some 
tracts  in  Nagpur  were  ceded  in  1817  does  not  place  Nagpur 
first  in  the  list  of  acquisitions.  The  province  as  a  whole 
had  been  managed  since  the  defeatrof  Appa  Sahib  in  1817, 
on  behalf  of  the  minor  Bhonsla  Raja  (Raghuji  III).  He 
succeeded  to  the  estates  in  1830,  but  died  without  heirs  in 
1853,  and  the  province  lapsed  to  the  British  Government. 

§  15.    Ajmer  and  Merwdra. 

Ajmer  was  ceded  by  treaty  in  1818  and  Merwara  also, 
but  the  latter  district  was  in  so  disturbed  a  state  that  it 
had  to  be  restored  to  order  by  military  occupation.  Such 
details  as  are  necessary  will  best  find  a  place  in  the  chapter 
specially  devoted  to  an  account  of  this  province.  The  whole 
was  constituted  a  Chief  Commissionership  under  the  autho- 
rity of  the  17  and  18  Viet.,  cap.  77,  sec.  3  J.  The  Governor- 
General's  Agent  for  the  Rajputana  States  is  ex  officio  Chief 
Commissioner. 

Previously  the  province  had  been  under  the  North- 
West  Provinces  Government,  and  it  was  owing  to  that 
fact  that  the  first  regular  settlement  was  made  on  the 
system  of  village  settlements  prevalent  in  those  provinces. 

§  1 6.    Assam. 

This  province  was  separated  from  Bengal  and  placed 
under  a  Chief  Commissioner  under  the  provisions  of  the 
Act  of  1854  (17  and  18  Viet.,  cap.  77).  As  it  was  not  de- 
sirable to  give  the  Chief  Commissioner,  as  such,  all  the 

1  Notification  (Foreign  Department),  No.  1007,  dated  26th  May,  1871. 


48  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BEITISH    INDIA         [CHAP.  H. 

powers  which  had  been  exercised  by  the  Government  of 
Bengal,  special  acts  were  passed  dealing  with  the  subject  of 
powers.  The  detail  of  this  will  be  more  appropriately  given 
in  the  chapter  devoted  to  Assam. 

Assam  includes  the  Assam  valley  districts,  acquired  in 
1824,  the  Hill  districts  (Garo  Hills,  Khasi  and  Jaintya  Hills, 
&c.),  and  the  older  districts  of  Goalpard,  Sylhet  (properly 
Silhatt  or  Srihatta),  and  Kachar l. 

§  17.   Coorg. 

The  little  province  of  Coorg  (Kodagu)  was  annexed  in 
1834  owing  to  the  continued  misgovernment  of  its  Raja2. 
It  is  a  hill  country  along  the  top  of  the  Western  Ghat 
range ;  only  a  tract  to  the  north  and  a  strip  to  the  east  is 
'  below  Ghat.'  Its  people  and  its  tenures  were  peculiar,  so 
that  its  administration  was  provided  for  separately.  The 
Resident  of  Mysore  is  the  Chief  Commissioner. 

It  is  a  scheduled  district  under  Act  XIV  of  1874,  and  is 
governed  by  such  of  the  General  Acts  as  have  been  declared 
in  force,  and  by  Regulations  under  the  33  Viet.,  cap.  3. 

§  1 8.    Burma. 

British  Burma  was  constituted  a  Chief  Commissionership 
on  its  present  footing  in  i8623.  As  in  the  case  of  the 
Central  Provinces,  the  Resolution  gives  a  history  of  the 
previous  administration.  It  recites  that  there  had  been 
three  separate  Commissioners  of  Arracan,  Pegu,  and  Tenas- 
serim  respectively :  the  first  had  been  under  the  Government 
of  Bengal  (annexation  after  the  war  of  1824) ;  Pegu  (second 
Burmese  war,  1852)  had  been  directly  under  the  Govern- 
ment of  India. 

After  the  third  Burmese  war  (1885-6)  the  provinces  of 
Upper  Burma  and  the  Shan  States  were  annexed,  and  formed 
into  seventeen  districts,  the  States  being  under  political  con- 

1  Notification,  No.  379,  dated  7th  3  Resolution,  Foreign  Depart- 

February,  1874  (Gazette  of  India,  Part  ment  (General),  No.  212,  dated  3ist 

II,  p.  53).  January,  1862. 

8  Proclamation  issued  May,  1834. 


CHAP,  ii.]  ORIGIN   OF    THE    PROVINCES.  49 

trol  only1.  The  Chief  Commissioner  has  jurisdiction  over 
the  whole,  but  the  Upper  Burma  territories  are  governed  by- 
several  separate  Regulations  under  the  33  Viet.,  cap.  3. 


§  19.   The  Andaman  Islands. 

The  small  settlement  at  Port  Blair  has  importance  chiefly 
as  a  penal  settlement  for  convicts  ;  the  government  is  by 
a  Chief  Commissioner  at  Port  Blair. 


§  20.    Berdr. 

Berar  (the  Hyderabad  Assigned  Districts)  is  governed  by 
British  officers  in  virtue  of  the  treaties  of  1853  and  i86o2. 
By  the  first  treaty  Berar  and  some  other  territories  were 
assigned  for  the  payment  of  interest  on  the  debt  due  to  the 
East  India  Company  for  the  support  of  the  Hyderabad 
Contingent  force,  and  for  some  other  purposes.  The  assign- 
ment was  subject  to  an  annual  account  of  receipts  and 
expenses.  By  the  treaty  of  1860  the  debt  was  declared 
cancelled  ;  certain  of  the  territories  assigned  under  the  first 
treaty  were  restored,  and  Berar  alone  retained  (within  the 
general  limits  it  now  occupies,  but  including  certain  taluqas 
inside  the  boundaries  which  were  before  exempt  from  man- 
agement). No  account  is  now  rendered  to  the  Nizdm,  but 
the  British  Government  pays  to  him  any  surplus  it  may 
have  in  hand  after  meeting  the  cost  of  administration,  the 
cost  of  the  troops  of  the  Contingent,  and  certain  allowances 
and  pensions  specified  in  the  treaty. 

No  laws  are  in  force  as  such ;  but  the  Governor-General 
makes  rules  on  certain  subjects  and  also  directs  such  Acts 
as  are  suitable,  to  be  followed.  They  are  then  '  in  force,' 

1  Proclamation,  3rd  March,  1886  '  to   the   exclusive   management  of 
(British  Surma   Gazette,   6th   March,  the  British  Resident  for  the  time 
1886,  Part  I,  p.  89).  being   at   Hyderabad   and   to  such 

2  Article  6  of  the  treaty  of  1853  officers  acting  under  his  orders,  as 
and  article  6  of  the  treaty  of  26th  may  from  time  to  time  be  appointed 
December,  1860  (Aitchison's  Treaties,  by  the  Government  of  India  to  the 
vol.  v.  pp.  214-224").     By  the  treaty  charge  of  those  districts.' 

of  1853  the  districts  are  assigned 

VOL.  I.  E 


5O         THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 

not  as  Acts  of  the  Legislature,  but  as  expressions  of  the  will 
of  the  Governor-General l. 

§  21.    The  term  'Non-Regulation'  Province. 

There  remains  one  more  topic  of  the  administrative  sys- 
tem to  be  noticed.  We  still  hear  of  '  Regulation '  Provinces 
and  '  N  on- Regulation '  Provinces ;  and  these  terms  should  be 
explained,  if  it  is  only  for  the  sake  of  history,  as  it  must  be 
admitted  that  the  terms,  having  lost  their  former  force,  are 
going  out  of  use. 

Starting  with  the  idea  of  the  '  Presidencies '  as  the  centres 
of  government,  we  have  already  seen  that  each  Presidency 
under  its  Governor  and  Council  was  empowered  to  enact 
a  code  of  '  Regulations '  for  its  government,  in  the  days 
before  1 834,  when  a  General  Legislative  Council  was  formed. 
When  therefore  any  territory  was  added  by  conquest  or 
treaty  to  a  presidency — as  it  was  first  supposed  would  be 
the  ordinary  course — such  territory  or  province  came  under 
the  existing  '  Regulations ' ;  and  further,  the  course  of  its 
official  appointments  was  governed  by  an  Act  of  Parlia- 
ment. But  when,  as  we  have  seen,  provinces  were  acquired 
which  were  not,  and  could  not  be,  annexed  to  any  of  the 
three  Presidencies,  their  official  staff  could  be  provided  as 
the  Governor- General  pleased,  and  was  not  governed  by 
any  Statute  ;  and  what  was  perhaps  of  greater  importance 
still,  the  existing  Regulations  of  the  Bengal,  Madras,  or 
Bombay  Codes  did  not  apply  proprio  vigore.  Such 
provinces  were  then  called  '  Non-Regulation  Provinces.' 
Besides  the  whole  provinces  never  '  regulationized,'  there 

1  There  have  been  proposals  from  especially  when  the  term  of  settle- 
time  to  time  to  restore  the  territory  ment  expired.  It  should  also  be 
to  the  rule  of  the  Nizam.  But  it  is  fairly  borne  in  mind  that  the  Nizam 
believed  that  these  have  now  re-  is  not  the  indigenous  or  natural 
ceived  their  final  quietus.  It  would  ruler  any  more  than  the  British 
certainly  be  extremely  hard  on  the  crown.  The  country  was  conquered 
population,  which  has  grown  well  by  the  Mughal  emperors,  and  the 
to  do  if  not  rich  and  contented,  Nizam, who  was  originally  their  local 
under  British  rule,  for  nearly  half  deputy,  established  his  independ- 
a  century,  if  a  change  was  now  ence  in  the  last  days  of  the  collapse 
made.  Treaty  obligations  to  respect  of  the  empire,  and  owes  his  con- 
the  moderation  of  our  Revenue  tinuance  in  his  existing  territory 
Settlement  might  be  made  on  paper,  entirely  to  the  moderation  of  the 
but  they  could  not  be  enforced,  British  rulers  of  the  time. 


CHAP.  II.]  ORIGIN    OF   THE    PROVINCES.  51 

were  also  parts  of  the  older  presidencies  "which  it  was 
desirable  to  exempt  from  the  ordinary  law.  The  '  Non- 
Regulation  Provinces,'  in  fact,  soon  came  to  comprise  the 
larger  portion  of  the  total  number  of  districts  in  British 
India 1. 

Of  the  two  features  which  distinguished  the  Non-Regula- 
tion districts,  one  relating  to  the  difference  of  the  laws  in 
force  cannot  be  fully  explained  till  we  have  further  studied 
the  legislative  powers  of  the  Indian  Government  in  the  next 
chapter.  I  must  therefore  defer  my  remarks  for  the  present, 
only  saying  that  the  difference  in  law  has  now  almost  dis- 
appeared as  regards  the  bulk  of  the  districts  ;  but  as  regards 
a  few  which  are  really  backward,  or  exceptional  tracts  of 
country  requiring  a  simpler  and  more  '  paternal '  form  of 
government,  the  old  distinction  has  given  way  to  a  new 
and  real  one. 

The  second  feature  of  the  original  distinction  survives 
still,  but  only  in  the  titles  and  salaries  of  certain  officials, 
and  also  in  the  fact  that  in  Regulation  Provinces  certain 
posts  are,  by  law,  reserved  to  be  held  by  members  of  the 
Covenanted  Civil  Services  2.  Under  the  Act  of  33  Geo.  III. 
(1793),  it  was  provided  that  offices  under  Government 
should  be  filled  by  Covenanted  Civil  Servants  of  the  Presi- 
dency to  which  the  vacant  office  belonged.  Consequently 
districts  not  attached  to  any  Presidency  were  not  bound  by 
this  rule,  and  the  Governor- General  could  provide  for  their 
administration  as  he  pleased. 

1  Colonel  Chesney  (Indian  Polity,  began  in  1834),  applied  equally  to 
and  edition,  p.  193)  gives  a  list  these  territories,  provided  the  pro- 
showing  that  there  are  in  Non-  vince  formed  part  of  British  India 
Regulation  to  97  Regulation  dis-  when  the  Act  was  passed.  Thus, 
tricts.  Readers  must  beware  of  any  general  Act  passed  after  1849 
certain  inaccuracies  in  this  other-  would  apply  to  the  Punjab,  and  one 
wise  excellent  book,  as  regards  the  passed  after  1856  to  Oudh. 
legal  position  of  the  Non-Regulation  2  The  question  what  appoint- 
Provinces.  The  author  is  mistaken  ments  in  India,  generally,  must  be 
in  supposing  that  the  Non-Regu-  held  by  Covenanted  Civil  Servants 
lation  Provinces  were  excluded  from  and  what  must  be  so  held  in  the 
the  operation  of  Legislative  enactments  Judicial  and  Revenue  Branches  in 
till  1861.  They  were  exempt  from  Regulation  Provinces,  is  now  deter- 
the  Regulations,  but  all  Acts  applying  mined  by  the  Act  of  Parliament, 
generally  to  British  India,  passed  24  and  25  Viet.,  cap.  54. 
by  the  Legislative  Council  (which 


5  2  THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.      [CHAP.  n. 

It  was  both  natural  and  advisable  in  such  cases  that 
military  and  political  officers  (who  had  been,  in  many  cases, 
engaged  in  the  affairs  of  a  province  before  its  annexation) 
should  be  appointed  to  the  task  of  first  organizing  and  con- 
ducting the  new  administration.  Besides  this,  as  time  went 
on,  an  increasing  staff  of  native  and  European  and  Eurasian 
'  uncovenanted '  officers  came  into  existence.  It  consisted 
of  qualified  persons  appointed  in  India  or  otherwise,  but 
who  had  not  signed  a  covenant  under  the  old  forms  with  the 
Court  of  Directors,  or  passed  through  Haileybury  College,  or 
been  selected  by  competitive  examination  under  the  later 
rules  (since  1856). 

Such  officers  could  of  course  be  also  employed.  At  the 
same  time  there  was  nothing  to  prevent  civilians  of  the 
Covenanted  Services  being  also  appointed  as  their  services 
became  available:  consequently  the  Commission  in  those 
provinces  is  always  a  mixed  one l. 

In  the  '  Non-Regulation  '  districts  also  the  district  officer 
(called  '  Deputy  Commissioner ' ?)  originally  had  civil  as 
well  as  criminal  and  revenue  powers,  and  this  is  still  main- 
tained in  a  few  cases,  though  the  later  tendency  has  been  to 
confine  the  district  officer  to  his  revenue  and  executive 
duty  ;  he  however  has  in  all  provinces  criminal  powers  as 
magistrate,  because  that  is  necessary,  though  of  course  he 
does  not  take  any  large  share  in  the  disposal  of  ordinary 
Criminal  Court  cases.  As  magistrate  he  hears  appeals  and 
superintends  the  administration,  and  in  some  provinces  is 
invested  with  special  powers  enabling  him  to  deal  directly 
with  heavy  cases  (all  offences  not  punishable  with  death) 
without  committing  them  for  trial  to  the  Sessions  Court. 

1  And  local  rules  exist  as  to  what  2  This  special  title  of  the  district 

appointments     should     ordinarily  officer  is  about  the   most  tangible 

be  open  to  or  be  held  by  each  class,  'outward  and  visible  sign'  that  a 

— Military  in  Civil  employ,  Civilian  district    is   '  Non-Regulation '    that 

and  Uncovenanted — with  a  view  to  I  am  aware  of. 
giving  a  fair  proportion  to  each. 


CHAP,  ii.]  ORIGIN   OF   THE    PEOVINCES.  53 

§  22.    List  of  Districts  in  India. 

The  following  provincial  lists  will  prove  useful  to  the 
student,  who  will  in  the  course  of  this  book  find  continual 
reference  to  the  '  Districts  '  and  '  Divisions '  (aggregates  of 
three  or  more  districts  under  a  Commissioner). 

The  table  shows  the  form  of  government,  whether  a 
'  local  government '  (i.  e.  under  a  Governor  or  Lieutenant- 
Governor),  or  a  '  local  administration  '  (under  a  Chief  Com- 
missioner) l,  and  also  the  groups  of  districts  under  '  Divi- 
sions ' — a  plan  which,  as  we  shall  see,  interposes  a  certain 
intermediate  superintendence  and  control  over  the  districts 
before  coming  to  the  chief  revenue  and  executive  control 
vested  in  the  Financial  Commissioners  or  Boards  of  Revenue, 
and  in  the  head  of  the  Government.  I  have  also  given  the 
chief  facts  regarding  the  acquisition  of  the  districts,  and 
the  date  of  their  passing  under  British  rule  2.  The  date  of 
the  Land-Revenue  Settlements  is  also  given  as  far  as 
possible. 

1  See  pp.  39-40.  quired    by    treaty,    exchange    and 

8  This    is    stated   generally  :    in  other  arrangement  for  simplifying 

some  cases  the  district  was  acquired  boundaries,  which  it  is  impossible 

piecemeal,  and  small  portions  ac-  to  include  in  a  general  table. 


54         THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 


<    . 


O    o  TJ 

s  1  a 


3    133-U 


o  .5  _i  «• 
-S'E  S  01 


W 


11 


§£ 
S-s 


PH 


il 


. 

"3  a-0" 
H  3  5  0 


EH 
O 


EH 

i— i 
Q 


EH 
02 


-ds^« 


•UOTSIAI(J  •UOISIATQ 

Xouapisajj 


•UOTSTAt(J 


iJ 

ill 


CC      ^J 

03    fl 


o  jj 

~T"S 


- 
m 


Name  of  P 
vince,  with 
of  Governm 
and  chie 
Revenue  Co 


M  8-B 


O 


- 

|| 

^ 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN    OY    THE    PROVINCES. 


55 


The  '  Nodbad  '  estates  are 
temporarily  settled  :  set- 
tlement expires  in  1892. 

These  two  districts  together 
formed  the  old  Tirhut  dis- 
trict. 

The  Daman-i-Koh  exempt 
from  the  Regulations  (and 
Permanent  Settlement) 
since  1780  and  forms  a 
Government  estate  settled 
under  Act  XXXVII  of 
1855,  and  now  under  Reg. 
Ill  of  1872. 

: 

^                                                    ^ 

i  I 

>> 

'    T3 

-t> 

d 

-«  o  ®      ^>  -e 
a  0,53      a  " 

ia 

h  .  .  . 

§  1  "i  .  S  s 

<3  o> 

c3  J»     -    "    - 

e  _  t»,  a  a  r- 

•»•>•••»•>»•*• 

"        "       -       "    &    >! 

Noacolly 
khali). 
Tipperah 


•UOISIAI(J 


be  jo 
IS 


•uotsrAi(j 


•UOISIAT(J 


•UOISIAT(J 


56          THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 


of  2    o 

o 

$  5  •£  T3 

1 

J5   S   05  3 
O   o   *  S 

e£  «  S 

i 

00 

<3  «  S  ^? 

c 

M 

•S 

I'i  s 

•2    • 

3 

®  0 

^  S  »  g 

•«l 

^^5  S 

1*8 

ills 

IM 

O    *$   S 

T"      Tm 

Date  of 
Land  Reve 
Settlemen 


!* 


g  il  1 

M  P<  m  a: 


J  l 

O  o 


n    03  >3  ^5 

«  ^  ^5  ^ 


o  S  S  .S  § 

CTj-e-2 
g<i  S-s 


'UOISIAT(J 
BSSIJQ 


Acquisition, 
er  territorial 
nation. 


Date 
and  f 
d 


I  §0  1  I 


CHAP.  II.] 


OEIGIJST   OF   THE    PROVINCES. 


57 


These  were  the  five  '  Sir- 
kars  '  or  districts.  Gantur 
did  not  immediately  pass 
with  the  others  but  fell  in 
in  1788.  The  others  were 
all  managed  politically 
under  tribute  till  1823. 
In  these  districts  the  Per- 
manent Settlement  chiefly 
took  effect. 
The  '  Settlement  '  dates  of 

course  refer  to  the  tracts 
under  Raiyatw&ri  Settle- 

•9J 

fe  ^ 

o 

fl    of 
M 

£S 

cl^ 

11 

<cj 
.  ^  T5 

als-S'Sa    lo-S-s-g-gA 

Isllil  §s|ri^ 

1tl^Afc*4f!        «2«2 
llfS'gf  2«|flS-g     1^ 
•S|S^l5g|.|J8«8 

flllW^gSJ*-*?! 

i  M^oig^ii.-?i 

*^»^$l'il^s,|p5 

,2  .S  5      &Ha      *     "S^'3 
73^,    N'i^_i2®:329"S-S-s 

TO     [>  ^^   "^   H^     —    rvl   _rt     ™   ^-*     O     Q>     Cj     ^ 

tricts  of  '  Rajamundry,' 
'  Masulipatam,'  and  'Gun- 
toor.'  The  change  was 

1 

•^  — 

— 

_i 

"V 

CH     CO 

O^(Y}      ^ 

i 

•3                      r^ 

ts» 

TJ- 

00    X  CO 
r-  pjoo 

M     H     M 

Settlem 
in  progr 

•  vo                         \O 

00                              00 

\o 

\o 

CO 

M 

^^_ 

—  N 

co 
oo" 

KJ 
<l 

"o  a  o 

V    ^    O 

: 

rf 

| 

•            ew     ' 

P       1-a 

1 

-1 

TJ 

=t-c  _i£ 
tn    03 

M 

.S'l  a 

I 

s 

2  *         ®  ° 

'd 

Is  'g 

£ 

<D    * 

fi 

omb 

^ 
p; 

^^          H5 

O 

PQ^i 

« 

H~ 

" 

1 

x 

^^ 

—  r  — 

• 

•8 

,j 

a 

3 

& 

^ 

^s 

1 

oi 

N 

'd 

0 

.2 

O 

^ 

^ 

— 

—  - 

\ 

33     T3 

| 

gg^ 

O 

^  Ifi  »J 

^3,"o 

s 

^ 

lO           -4^> 

^**  Q>  o  ^3 

g     ^    *3$   rC 

'£  r°-0  ,/ 

qj  HH    ®   52 

*lH 

Governor  in 

O    CO 

3«t 

M    ^O  <; 
—    Q^  ; 

r 

5  ei 
3 

Board  of 
Revenue. 

58           THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 


GJ     '      '     ®          rt    O    O 

X 
« 

_£§~'3>,§<Dqj"8 

S 

.^     fl  _  f^  ^2            p     C(  .li  ^^ 

i 

« 

^og^-S^cl" 

|ff!"!|lil 

a?  ]<2  75  fl 

§ 

03 

«M    §    C 

to       oo  o\  ,S       «       co      ®                o\^o  oo  c^  co  10  oo 

o  ®  S 

finsS 

00             CO  00      (£•        00          00           ^                     00000000000000 

II 

a 

Taluk,  Per- 
gana,  or  other 
sub-division 
of  District. 

f2                    '  >y           • 

"S'li    ^    ^Isi    1           11-    lls'S 

p,^  §    ."§-;«  &  ^^  >_•  §                     ^s  r3  '5       o  S  d  £< 
'^2'3Ei2>>>§'3^-^i:«                  '5'3T3'3^^!'§)M 

•«^  s  s^^--  ^.^^i           iaaE*^IS 

^^a3r5«*Hc^^^*^*l^L2                             »cdc5o3.^oSOP|SJ 

^                           ^  _                 —  <• 

43 
a 

i| 

s'i        « 

S| 

S                      ft^                      ^ 

sp 

§•               |b                 § 

'A 

^§                 |s                  S 

0                            $&                              M 

*°  %  i-~  g 

§    >•"*!£•> 

<S    OJ  'C3    CO  —H 

^  OS  C  'S  Q 

^c 

-^ 

^""^ 

Date  of  Acquisition, 
and  former  territorial 
designation. 

gS                  1||gS  °3|||  |_||| 

^1*       illi?l?Lllilf 

l^l      !'?u«|r«H| 

?^.S              1iliJfsl*|l'   -S'-i 

ill 

Kurnool  district  in 
1858-9. 

i^fl  i 

•SfS^l 

5§  ^ 

«g«  S^§o 

§1 

C    ?    £,3    « 

1  g-ll  1 

X|o     1 

^ 

CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN   OF   THE    PROVINCES. 


59 


a  ,«s' 

9  &      <s> 


1  ^ 


. 


vO 

co 

N   or 

Th 

1/5    VO    « 

j-g           ^|     , 

i 

i      1 

1 

1        1      1 

M    ^j       |        j        t      M           |             i                         1        | 

1/5 

r~ 

CO 

M      01 

CO 

I*-        1/5    M 

oC-*-3    TJ-  10^0    "^     CO     "^  ^t"       vO    r^- 

C~ 
CO 

co 

oo 

CO  CO 
CO  CO 

CO 
00 

CO      00  VO 
OO      CO  CO 

P^vOcoooP      r*     r*c^«        r-r- 

g^oooooog^co    coco       cooo 

— 

—  v^  — 



*—>^ 

Cjg                  fl 

M  ^                       M  ^^^, 

02        02 

O    -13      O 

ipet  and 
her  taluks. 

taluks. 

.+J 

1 

'jf-g 

i'! 

.  +5    « 

1'^iU' 

O    »rH      £    VP 

£3  'O    03  ."S 

ur. 
maner. 
indiwash. 
idamba- 

j        s'-3  •           ..a  »• 

>S                GO              -S    'S    ^>                  .      A              '£    'S    ri<5 

TS      -^       s  r3  I-H      --H  a    .  '«  c  -s 

03           tr^            M     ^    a)  V^H     03    n3    r^     ^     "  I~H 

-^     2   .r§~Mf»>'»^«2^(Boi 

-gv* 

tJ   0 

^ 

t>Ooo 

£££o! 

HO      -<|PHPHOPEHH<S<       fe  r<  '" 

^    

—  —  ' 

-  — 

,-^  •,-— 

-^^'                                   T        .•—       —  *_     *         ^ 

a 


"O 

1 

1 

>LH 

O 

§       || 

03      H  H 

1 

fl 
H 

^—  • 

«^N- 

^—  x 

•^.^^^^ 

^fff. 

*~ 

MJ 
-!^ 

.S  ««M 

bdrO  O 

^^ 

^ 

natic  in  parts,  in 
1750  and  1760,  con- 
firmed by  Empe- 
ror's Sanad  of  1  763)  . 

The  '  Carnatic  dis- 
tricts,' ceded  by  the 

Nawab  in  1801. 

J3  «C5" 
*sg  -3 
M  'O 
A        fl 

lsa 

^    r^       ^ 

43  i  ^ 

•e  -*r  G 

2    o    3 

(&  <y  be 

cj^Ti 

•rt    03    fi 
Pn  «« 

111 

-S  T3  ^ 

*  fl 

0   eS   ^ 

~-a> 

III 

o3 

^ 
1" 

a.a 
§s 
^i 

«<s 

^  fl 

—   - 

The  Dindigal  part  of 
this  district  (Palni, 
Dindigal  and  Pe- 
riyakulam  taluks) 
was  acquired  1792. 

60          THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  11. 


«H    O 

o.o  i^j 

-§:|S  S 


Taluk,  Pe 
na,  or  oth 
ub-divisio 
of  District 


*ljjj 

li^ll 


'' 


go 


H-3     O 
«4_,     ®     <D 


g^ 


rrt- 

>c*So  G  "3  R»  H 

45^  g  s«^3~S  =s 

pq  fi  H  «  ft  ^  - 


1 
"3  -a  .5 


ill  a 

- 


^•s 

—     CO 

3*3 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN   OP    THE    PROVINCE  S. 


61 


8  A            $H 

6 

c 

*i         el 

.S      =        r          r                      s 

§  S                 •"  o 

"*2 

°s  Sr1               c? 

o> 
d 

«  °°  up           o  °* 

®    ^      »-       ^               *• 

o  oo          to  .2 

£ 

12  "3  M            .. 

CD 

§  >s  .9      «  a  -g 

C 

O      . 

11-1      111 

!3  S  . 

•?  2  - 

r^      S     *3                           ®      S    T5 

,2  S) 

02                        W 

PH 

IO 

vo     H           i/)             o                              o 

:                  co 

co      o             r-              \o                                     r~- 

:                  co 

CO      CO                 CO                    CO                                                CO 

N       \Q      r-        o              •*             r- 

M      O\            vo                 ^                 ^                  CO 

r—    vo              *O                *O               vo                    10 

to      2,  vo       o          vo           ••*•  ' 

II                                III 

VO           r^        IO           r-                  IO                  IO 

1/3       "^                 ^*                    OO                    IO                        CO 

CO          ~      CO          CO                 CO                 CO 

CO      CO                 CO                    00                    CO                        CO 

o 

o 

as                aj 

SH                    C? 

!   1  I   . 

ill!  i 

CO       PQ    M       PH            <q            EH 

r-<                      Pu                                                      M 

*®             fS          ^                       ^ 
"a  J                    •§          '2           ^ 

%2     S3                           o             3               ^ 

d  S       -3         §         ^          •& 

M     ^5             <,               PH               CC                  CQ 

^                                                         ^ 

^                                                                                  ^^ 

•           •       •UOTSTAI(J 

•      :            :      >UOTSTAT(I       : 

^d    g»  v  -s      -s-     -9 

-Q  a      oo     g    .g            ^           -rf 

Vs  •  "  *  £       ^       -2 
•1  5  °°          a       o       « 

T3    O                   02                              PH 
|||                   |            5?      |     t 

g  §  ||    i    !!<*>  || 

M       ^          |  J     d          ^                  |  1    H          |  '-     Si 

CD            ^       oo       PH           'S^'^      ^       » 

rj                                                                          OO5 
^                          <X>0>rrt               ®                      pL).^"               ^^^ 

1   ^s  ^  .  if?  -^§ 

S  ^  ,i?           ^g  \S      So      S  M 
osg              0°°      Oco      2°° 

oo         o^co        Oco        ^^oo        ofloo 

^^               u  H     fe  H     ^  H 

HM                    NH                          h^                  fn                          W 

>! 

2    .                         c  p  o  ^ 
fl  JH                      -3    ,  $  <3 
<u  <•                      .,  <!  cb  "° 

"^    05                                      O      - 

°35  3                       fl  rr3  J2  Er 
20                          M  o       T?5 
.     CQ                                      <C    cj         <-> 

PH  ^                             >   S   oo    ^ 

ii»iii  , 
?iiuii 

o  .2  S  ^  a  ^  S 

"S  s  :s  2  a^ 

H                                            M  M 

p  g  fi  '73  ^  ^ 

62 


THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  ir. 


.S-gS® 


a 
o  crt 


I  .s  a  I  :§  J   -P  j§ 


'I 
CD 


'g  gg  g 


-is    OD=tH  ^-c  •  —  ft  In 


-2    0=5 
o   ON 

2  °° 

Pl   M 


rt 

.2  5 

"3  5  S 

fl'C  co 

32  "^ 


1111 


<H    S     C 

si  1 


•6-8881 


jo 


8UO     ] 
-UOJJ 

jo   Tioj^daoxa 


S-g 
°l 


-cs        ^p 


III 


aauoissiuioioQ  et{!j  aapnf^ 


.    fe  a 
•<  I  jj> 

' 


- 


o 


'SM  2"^ 

ON        9 

o  o  .2  d 


-    - 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN   OF   THE    PEOVINOES. 


NORTH-WESTERN  PROVINCES. 

£    o3    ^  "C    cS   ^    ^"                                      ° 
'rt  43   EL,  "*   S  r£3  '** 

i   1             ; 

03                                            02                  O 

:                   C    60 

jpl    1  •       N   ??  "^r 
?3§i     si       £j  i«s£l-i 

5&SS           SS               ,2®       so^     ^^°2 

•*-iOCO"*--^-(N    0)    <N    O    ••*• 

1       1      1       1      1      1       1      1             1 
CO    CO  rovo    r-  T)-  10  10  N    T(- 

cococooocooooooococo 

5,3  S                  o3  ®                     E"1  M 

R       D§                       —    ^                        -._  -     » 

:    :    :    :    :      *•  i  ^  .b  60   :    :    :    :    :    : 
:    :    :    :    :       a  ®  o  g  g    :    :    :    :    •    : 

_g  "^-^    03  _      

rt                         'cT 
^             ^                            ,d                        .3 

"S                       ft                                              M                                    EH  •§• 

^3                  c^                                    >3^           __;             ^  ^ 

s  I    S'  %          *       "§  1    1  s  §  .    |    'g  S  ^   ^  1  ^- 
|f.p|  |  &           "8         ^3  .rt-  ^  ^  §"?  g  5  .  I-IJ  a  3  ^  g 

§|s§a       ig     lTiPHll^|f11l1.| 

<D43o3^grH                     O               NOc^^Hc^cS    '^-ia    c^^^^^cSTZn^  '^ 

^                                                                —      V 

•    'UOISIAIQ     'UOTSTAT(J 

•UOISIAI(J                             'UOISIAI^ 

•~  —  _                                                                                                - 

fl  "^  2  s  d  ^            01  ^-9 
•g    r-^  O   3    J7            3  S   te  H                           'SaSU'BQ  pUB  T?UUI^J> 

^O^^fqM          gi  ^  o 

o  8^- 
•I  2  fef  o            ] 

l||      '   ' 

64          THE    LAND    SYSTEMS    OE    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  n. 


(BO)® 

^  su 


oo  '2  oo      oo      oo  oo  oo 


i 


M 


S 

ait 

^  i 
II 


•UOTSIAT(J 


Acquisition, 
er  territorial 
gnation. 


Date 
and  f 


£|hj 

i  g-ll  I 


CHAP.  II  ] 


OEIGIN   OF    THE   PEOVINCES. 


i     ^     05 

73    &o 

•^    03 

cs^'o  b 
.2       S 

"S 

00      J^j    53 

S  «  fl 

•s  s 

^   «M 

3 

48  i  §  -S 

o  as  a 

C    0 

.25  >i  K.  fl 

PH 

s 

6iD 

m'^ 

• 

•g  •—  '    03    >, 

hi 

<B    S    °^ 
<a  °0 

.-  ft 
00  "S 
00    o 

co  CL 

3HT3 

c-SX!  § 

o 

"S^ 

-  C 

j;. 

3 

•r 
- 
o 

I* 

ft  CS 

fc 

2-S 

'frl 

•-' 

CO  ^_,    0)  -g 
£.S«    C8 
o        ft 

Various  port 
rately  sett: 
tlement  of 

1 

ft 
x 

o 

Settlement 
new  Settler 
poned  till  i 

Expired  in  i 
Settlement 
till  1898. 

This  Divis: 
'  Scheduled 
under  Act 
1874.  But 

ft 
03  ft 

II 

CO 
M 

a 

X 

_!. 

O 
« 
43 

law,  excepi 
Jaunsar-Ba 

Settlement  e: 
has  been  ex 

twenty  yeai 
1904. 

Scheduled 
Under  spe 
Ordinary 
law  only 
force. 

3    cS    ® 

^3 

a 

«®    I 

1 

"S  <E' 

P    03  "S 

£ 

03    CD 

d     3 

03 

S  "ft 

,  —  ™»-^ 

-^-  --. 

•UOTSIAT(J 


•UOISTAT(J  UJ 


•UOISTA'  (J 


VOL.  I. 


66 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.      [CHAP.  n. 


>> 

" 


03  a1 
§| 

w>  5 


«u  3  a 

0  £  2 

3*J 

o'si 


w 


PWcc 


feOPQ 


•UOISTAJd          'UOISIAT(J 


'UOISIAT(J 


ro- 


rm 
nt 

rol. 


Name  of  P 
vince,  with  f 
of  Governm 
and  chief 
Revenue  Con 


«  *H   M» 

S§3.a§^ 

olllll 

CD    fn  _fl  "ti    fe  i^ 
rH    ^*  fn    ^  ~*^ 

E"1  §  .2  O      * 


CHAP.  II.]  ORIGIN   OF   THE    PROVINCES. 


. 


®tf£p2S:3<i>.S 
£  k<2  3  £  '?  S  IS 


«f « 

w>^^ 


1 3  a 
§|  $•> 

^  iB    ® 


S    C8.21 


o  .3 

-    g    cs 


68 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  n. 


i| 


-s, 


-      fl 

p 


fi*  = 


VI 

W 
O 

JZ1 


* 
EH 
O 


s-si 

So2 
I-J 


la 


00  t- 
VO  \O 

oo  co 


sl§« 

PL,  o  'S  -g 

rf&ii 


n 


•notsiAT(j 


quisi 
terri 
tion 


fo 
d 


Name  of  Pro- 
vince, with  form 
of  Government 
and  Chief 
Revenue  Control. 


s 

- 


CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN   OF    THE    PROVINCES. 


69 


EC* 
L- 

1  3  J  1  -e  1  ^      | 

^  *C       W  "3        ^ 

"fi  nS  2  j      3          o3§ 

ed  from 

Seoni. 

>*      >. 

-a       -u 

.S     Pi 

!i 

"S 

1 

.2 
o 

13 

Is 

twelve 

ilement 

For  thirty  yea: 

PI    t^5*"1  vO    ..    £<  J3         c«    ® 

.  2  *  ^  'S  .2  ^  *     ^  P. 
"        "      ;      s  SOQ-  |  q      c^     >,« 

3  g  P  d-a  8  h  •  S^ 

S-a-Js  S  5  aj'S^S'g 

I:           *•         r         "i:c^P^'~'Mi^^3^ 
-   -  be  o"3  N  3*  5  ®  £  -^  -« 
^«2;C"Sa)fe.S^^ 

^    C8    ^  ^    oj    >,£   ft^P  ^ 

trict  transferr 
Mandla  and 

Settled  for 
years. 
Settlement  for 

years  expired. 

Part  transfers 
Sambalpur. 

1 

S 

years  expired. 
Settlement,  w 

practically 

- 
£ 

"3 

ED 

2 
^ 

in  progress. 

^    g 

& 

i 

9} 

g 

<V 

O             r 

bo 

bO 

g, 

33             0 

O 

2 

O 

^  3  Js 

ft 

ft 

ft 

w 

q 

i—  i 

d 

i—  i 

r>       r—       1/5  1000                                         f 

co 

i 

I 

00 

VO            ThiOCOdio                                         vo-^ 

ul 

vO 

p« 

3  73 
60  >o3 


•UOISIAI(J 


r 

;- 

il 

•-  o>  o 

n3  T3    fs 

73  TS  co 

43 

.S 

73 

"o 

0 

Pi 

0) 

>5«     ^     § 

^^  •• 

ON 

{ 

1    r 

.S  * 

02  73 

^ 

1 

S 

1C 

1 

ft 

oo 

*3** 

PICO    ^ 

*•« 

^°3 

£ 

•g 

IM 

co 

•as         Pi 

.rl 

d 

^ 

1-9 

u 

_j 

rc? 

ft 

v)  73 

O 

S 

5)72       73  co 
*         .  ®   H 

l^^'S  a 

O     ' 

3 

i 

H 
O 

^a 

QO     ^ 
w     C> 

bo 

•C3 

o> 

||| 

A 

1 

•0  " 

WW 

h 

O 

70 


LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  n. 


REMARKS. 

S 

2  .2  S  o  35.0313  ..      aj      te"<s'S    °      a  al2+a 

illl-gol  sll  §11  1.*?      11 

1888. 

(Settlement  expired.) 

Sanction  of  Govern- 
ment of  India  not 
received. 

HI 

~ 

^ 

s     ^   * 

2 
c 

1—  1 

Date  of  Regular 
Land  Revenue 
Settlement 
(in  force). 

co  M   N       r-co  ^ 

0 
ON       °?    ON  CO       CO    •*  O\00 

CO    Th  Th  O\ 

VO  VO    IT)  I> 

oo  co  co  oo 

00  00  00         00  00  CO  CO           JJ.CO  CO         00  00  CO  CO 

;JI;I 

Name  of  present 
District. 

•                            c3    N 

i  «   -i-2 

-2          b          .J 
|           g         Jill 

I  ill  llil 

i'5I-cj  '^3 

•g  2  '3  >  a 

Hill 

fcM§-Sfi 

•aOISIAI(J    -aOTSTATd                -UOISIATd 

•UOISTAId 

-  • 

Date  of  Acquisition, 
and  former  territorial 
designation. 

O     O!     HI 

llil 

SH     eg     C3     V 

Name  of  Pro- 
vince, with  form 
of  Government 
and  chief 
Revenue  Control. 

^^"§     «^§"{*     c«SV<»        |V* 
531     S'Sl"     ^6c»     fe§g^2 

lit  qjl  fill  3Jii 

1^^ 
o3  -2   o3  T3 

.S  »  -^  o 

CHAP.  II.] 


ORIGIN    OF    THE    PROVINCES. 


e8   «   9   fl  ^4   fl  «g 
G    g    M.rt    cS    <B    ° 

^«                                  «fl     §>h(SS 

pi  sisa 

s 

«"£."§                           -§3p<'£!i:SC2ra 

s  l  !•«  ^  1 

ftl*l    |J& 

4  ^      I  8  P  *  <£ 

£>8  G-^3'5        ®  H 

G 

jjlj          jff  |5j|s 

J*'^..^! 

*H     S     S      Th   §)   fl     S 

llilllll 

C"1 

Revision 

OJgjG^                                                                             '^'fio'C^§r£< 

•^  os  '-3  "S                                      °      -M  M  S  "^  oj  _.  >1H 

o  ^^  'i              ^J^°'"^ii3'S 

^^                  p^                                                               J—  1                          s  ^ 

^                                          ^ 

^                                               _^ 

_  o5              . 
GO>         G    ® 

.S 

13  ti                                                       "^  re 

0   £         °  "S 

pvj 

ON                      ^H                                                                         '^    O    ® 

'S  be      'S  "-s 

2 

<S"            '&,  &                                        b  '«  &o 

*P  S     '>  & 

S< 

™             r^w                                        ft'?  S 

f?i  si 

x 

W      M                                                                                                  *      OJ     O, 

HW   G 

• 

P<  "2     co 


^  l.li 

03    C         ,§  ^    S    cS    g, 

.44 

^^ 


a       P  s  s  a 


•noisiAi(j 


•noisiATQ; 


treaty 
,  after 
r. 


6 


a 


Ceded  by 
(March  18 
first  Sikh  w 


vo"  g 


rt 
-03 


a  y    «  "^  • 

."2  'G  G  °°  3?  >rt      * 


®  S-t 


jlli||fi||frJJ|| 


s 


72 

LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA. 

[CHAP.  n. 

i 

a 

o  g>      T3°?                          S           ®i   ol                 ^               •*? 

is  :s    §«£•          1     d^i       i       § 
g  §•  "*                p£  §       * 

1  *      d°§                   48        1    .«             1     -d   j 

i..  •&!         s    4  «  .       aii 

r/)     OT             C3   ^j                                          ,-H                 ^^  Q}     to 

^^oo-d)                                          d  *"•)                 ^J^O- 
DQ                                                    cc  q  --3                           -H 

'S            cj    «  ^    r> 

a    Illll 

»            d    oj    2    m  M 

q>             -M  d  \' 

J_,                         CC     H       1      ® 

M 

•—  '   efl                                         *-«T3a>^                  _-        k> 

CS        O                                   yf.                                                                   -*J            »              '--      •—*     Hi                                              ^3                     ™ 

S  p2{           m    P                                     t^^S^"                                          ^12 

1     ||:      -|Ji.a      2  |3a 

^cofe*^                       ^Hdri^S'               •*»          O®-^ 

ti^iSSR1-1                   <*d     SS®^3            i^^5^5® 
®-2«£^_,                 3«.2cd.2           Sd^^S 

*  oo'    "o  «  O2  "II  « 
O\        ^  ^  B  m 

1".  1s  111 

6  •§      -'  1  S  S 

®    O              ^j    ft.  3     gj 

'S  ®  c^^  ^^                SS-gdS>          S®^1       o 
^  E<™  [2  ,2  i                a  -^     o-5^;^          wS^     dJ 

1^  |un 

Sb 

0)    fl 

•+j  ^^ 

"°  1  1 

co  d  ® 

ON  *    d 

i          «  5  2    C 
oo            £  a  S.   o° 

Q'O  S 

H  ^  t3 

<2         «S^   oo 

SCB 

«  S 

O)   -^         H 

fij 

^tn 

—  02 

M 

s||-§ 

s~^ 

; 

P^    Q    M  T" 

"S 

»•                                 _"d          =§ 
^              '1                           ^     •  a 

1 

Pi'** 

cS 

•S.1 

•    •tjj^.p^        ^        ft             3                  d"3W 

e, 

f 

g  9  §  II    •  i      S           S               *  W  A 

"     C5     Sr*,   S^  3                 ~                fl)                                                                       S                     ™ 

a  I  ^f  a     g     1         8           -1  M  •§ 

*rf    o3    c3  ^    c^             O              c^                       c3                            *^H      *c3       c3 

C                    ^S            5 
«                    t>           ^ 

5      .S 

o3                  k»         3 

rH  ft  ^  tf)  ^             ^5             W                       O                              ttd      ^      ^3 

0                 02          ^ 

P 

•aedoT^ssy                     ^    -aSu^  ^  m^ssy" 

uauoisstra 

|f  jl 

"TOBSSV                                                                                              j 

[q^peinj^woejia 

jo  aauoTssiuimoo          ^—  ^  .^^-^ 

.3 

O      W      C^                ^J              ^2      ^    S    -*^                IO    £|A    Oi    ?   x—  V 

c3  to       H    .  rtn  *o  o            co.     o  ®  *o 

10 

II. 

•ffl'C  a 

?               i_3          q        ^  ^    ^    r*"  SH    &<       oo    Q)    w  **^    CO 

3            CO 

|!| 

|          *     |      "S-Sf'-^l      ^'2      S?-<2 

^               d 

Sit 

S.      a^lo'«'3g<|go      ^^^d°»-S 
pq  ^o        eg  £^  so  ®  K  2  g.  2  5      ^Soo123—, 

<D             (JJ 

eg  173 

co  ^      &x)  is  *s       s  fl  "t**  §       ^  ^*  d  ®  tn  *S  r^  o 

d 

—   — 

•  *"*   ^            *C  ^     ?)   PH     £H     ^     eS  r^           *p5   ^  •<-"    ~     QJ  ^y  '£*     Jj^ 

i?        c 

—  .            O            *     ^3       QJ 
t~s 

£        <! 

ijl^j 

a  &  §^ 

^.d  |^cS 

^        o  c  H  'S 

"°*£  S°  » 

•  rH    HH 

3     S'S  S 

m                           ^  ^  **^ 

1  |l  a  f 

•^  p^ 

CHAP.  II.] 


OEIGFN    OP   THE   PEOVINCES. 


73 


3 


fl    0 


II 

(3  S 


c<» 


®  £  "I 

S  ,2  „        „         r,     f3 

-M  Q)  -4^   i 

0§  ~ 


-4-3      Q 

fl  ^ 

d) 

S  S 

•— '  .o 


-H  ^  d 
soo"g 

«  M  S 

-<1  o  ~ 

M  a 


«  S  2 


-    *  J 

3  «    53 

3     w'tt 


*  i***  ®       « 

C3    g    O)    o  '^ 

l-rt       *H       fH       X       t>~. 


§ 


31JS 


W  cq 
10 

rg  OO 

S   H 


£Tf 
w 

tfi  OO 


74 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  n. 


tf 
O 
O 
O 


11* 

g  2  S 

M 
H 

03    0  "8 

•"SJ 

ro   «3  .2 

05    fl    Q 

fe    03  »C3  •% 
^     ^H   W     OQ 

J* 

iJJJ.Si 

P.1*  £ 

CO  _2    bD.S    ®*  ®  .2 

§03 

Ss6i^§ 

LI 

Jjfl.1 

l§"^"6 

J       ^ 

1       4| 

•^              P>5 

M                                «  rQ 

t'8>3° 

03                rH 

M 

-g   oS 

"sis 

00 

Ifi 

-S    | 

O 

(D 

•g  K 

•g*  |  a 

^—  —  v~—  ' 

1  siaf 

^  ffi  S  fl 

.3 

il. 

S? 

'3  ^.S 

c 

•  rH 

•§ 

o  ^ 
^  *<-< 

Is 

Name  of  Pro- 
vince, with  form 
of  Government 
and  chief 
Eevenue  Control. 

If 

CHAP.  II.] 


OEIQIN   OF   THE    PROVINCES. 


75 


-8 -is 
^£c 

Ju 
§^ . 

a>  -pi 
$  ,4 


o3  .5 

o  ;+3 


13  2 


>»     '£ 


•  flil 

fe  fq  *   5 
fl       „  2  ^ 

—     CD     O     §9     ~ 

hCT   CJ  ,<^   ®    o 

^     CUD  5  rC  GO 

S      ®     O)     fe 

i|ll  L 

Q  i—-     M    OS    09 

IsJjffl 

ai-SEt§. 

==  ®  s  §^0 


.in    c  « -6  *  S  -S 


« 

<! 
pq 


.1  d 


.    5  2  »  "  g 
TS  S       w  <s  ja  '-"-. 

2  §^a  S-l  ?3 

n  c  "9  ®  •+*  ^  <aj 
a  s  .3  -ra  _  ®  ^2 


i    O    ti    ®  • 

!OWi 


o 
as 


f  Illl^UIKfl.1 

w    i"j||-a^li-slsi 


2  & 


«  §.2' 
bS 


g^jjia^p 


a  M 


*F.I. 


CHAPTER   III. 

OP   THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATURES,    AND   THE    LAWS   BY 
WHICH    INDIA    IS    GOVEENED. 


§  i.    Reason  for  describing  them. 

As  I  have  already  alluded  to  '  Acts '  and  '  Regulations '  of 
the  Indian  Legislature,  and  shall  have  occasion  continually 
to  refer  to  such  Acts  and  Regulations  in  the  sequel,  it  will 
be  desirable  to  give  a  brief  account  of  the  legislative  powers 
under  which  laws  have  been,  and  are,  enacted  for  the  Indian 
Empire. 

Just  as  in  the  last  chapter  we  learned  that  the  organiza- 
tion of  the  several  provinces  for  administrative  purposes 
was  only  accomplished  gradually  and  by  a  series  of  Acts  of 
Parliament,  so  the  Indian  Legislature  has  gradually  grown 
into  its  present  form  after  several  statutes  for  organizing  it 
have  been  made,  amended,  and  repealed.  The  tentative 
and  changeful  nature  of  the  arrangements  provided  are  due 
to  the  same  causes  in  both  instances. 

At  first  it  was  only  necessary  to  provide  for  the  internal 
affairs  of  the  Company's  factories,  to  determine  what  laws 
the  settlers  were  to  be  deemed  to  carry  with  them,  and  were 
to  be  bound  by,  in  their  new  home,  and  what  courts  were  to 
administer  justice  among  them.  Soon,  however,  the  sphere 
widened ;  whole  provinces  were  acquired  and  added  on  to 
the  original  settlements ;  and  then  came  the  necessity  of 
controlling,  not  only  the  European  settlers,  but  of  providing 
for  the  government  of  the  country  at  large. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATURE.  77 

Trading  charters  had  then  to  be  supplemented  by  Acts  of 
Parliament,  providing  for  the  direction  and  control  of  the 
East  India  Company  (now  that  it  was  a  governing  body), 
regulating  the  appointment  of  high  functionaries  and  sub- 
ordinate agents  in  India,  determining  the  constitution  of 
Courts  of  Justice,  and  giving  powers  of  local  legislation. 

The  first  Act,  as  already  intimated,  passed  for  this  purpose 
was  the  '  Regulating  '  Act  of  1772-3  (13  Geo.  Ill,  cap  63). 
This  had  to  be  amended  on  the  subject  of  framing  'Regu- 
lations' in  1780-1,  and  further  in  1784  and  1786  (26  Geo. 
Ill,  cap.  1 6).  The  subsequent  Acts  were  passed  at  intervals 
of  twenty  years  (when  the  charters  were  renewed),  thus  : — 

1792-3  (33  Geo-  HI,  cap.  52). 

1812-3  (53  Geo-  IH,  cap.'  155). 

1833  (3  and  4  Will.  IV,  cap.  85). 

1853  (16  and  17  Viet.,  cap.  95). 

§  2.    Home  Government  of  the  present  day. 

It  would  serve  no  useful  purpose,  even  if  I  had  space 
available,  to  describe  the  early  history  of  the  Government 
which,  in  former  days,  as  at  present,  was,  from  the  necessity 
of  the  case,  carried  on  partly  in  England  and  partly  in 
India. 

The  'Court  of  Directors'  of  the  Company,  afterwards 
supervised  by  the  '  Board  of  Control '  (which  acted  as  a 
check  on  the  part  of  the  Crown) 1,  passed  away  in  1 858. 
The  Home  Government  is  now  provided  for  by  the  Act  21 
and  22  Viet.,  cap.  106  (A.D.  1858),  known  as  the  '  Act  for  the 
better  government  of  India,'  amended  in  1869  (32  and  33 
Viet.,  cap.  97).  This  Statute  received  the  Royal  assent  on 
the  2nd  August,  1858,  and  came  into  force  thirty  days  later. 
In  the  proclamation  that  was  issued  throughout  India,  the 
Governor-General  is  for  the  first  time  styled  'Viceroy.' 
This  Act  transferred  the  government  of  the  Company's 
possessions  to  the  Crown,  and  provides  that  all  the  rights  of 
the  Company  are  to  be  exercised  by  the  Crown,  and  all 

1  This  was  constituted  by  '  Pitt's  Act'  of  1784  (24  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  25). 


78  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  in. 

revenues  to  be  received  for  and  in  the  name  of  the  Queen, 
and  to  be  applied  for  the  purposes  of  the  government  of 
India  alone,  subject  to  the  provisions  of  the  Act l. 

One  of  Her  Majesty's  Principal  Secretaries  of  State  is  to 
exercise  all  the  control  that  the  Court  of  Directors  of  the  old 
Company  did,  whether  alone  or  under  the  Board  of  Control. 

A  Council  of  fifteen  members,  styled  the  '  Council  of 
India2,'  is  also  established.  The  number  has  been  since 
reduced  to  ten  (1889),  by  enabling  the  Secretary  of  State 
not  to  fill  up  five  vacancies  out  of  the  fifteen.  The  Act 
fixes  the  salary  of  the  members  (payable  out  of  the  Indian 
revenue)  and  prohibits  them  from  sitting  or  voting  in  Par- 
liament. The  Council  is  under  the  direction  of  the  Secre- 
tary of  State,  and  its  duty  under  the  Act,  is  to  '  conduct 
the  business  transacted  in  the  United  Kingdom  in  relation 
to  the  government  of  India  and  the  correspondence  with 
India.' 

It  may  be,  and  is,  divided  into  Committees  for  different 
departments  of  business.  If  the  Council  differs  from  the 
Secretary  of  State,  the  opinion  of  the  Secretary  is  final,  ex- 
cept in  some  matters,  for  the  decision  of  which  the  law 
declares  a  majority  of  votes  necessary  3. 

§  3.    Legislative  power  in  England. 

The  Parliament  has  full  power  to  legislate  for  India 
whenever  it  thinks  fit.  Not  only  has  Parliament  this 
general  power,  but  the  local  Indian  Legislature  is  expressly 
barred  from  dealing  with  certain  subjects  which  it  was 
thought  wiser  to  reserve  for  the  Imperial  Parliament. 

I  may  here  mention  that  it  is  a  settled  rule  of  inter- 
pretation that  Acts  of  Parliament  applicable  to  'British 

1  In  1876  (39  Viet.,  cap.  10)  the  native  princes  and  chiefs  at  Delhi 

authority  of  the  Queen  was  further  on  ist  January,  1877. 

recognized    and    Her  Majesty  was  2  See  the  Act,  sects.  7  and  19. 

authorized  to  adopt  the  style  and  3  The    most    important    of   such 

title  of  Empress  of  India  which  she  cases  is  provided  by  section  41  of 

did   by  Proclamation,   a8th   April,  the  Act  itself.     No  grant  or  appro- 

1876.     The  assumption  of  the  title  priation  of  Indian  revenue  or  public 

'  Empress  of  India '  (Kaisar-i-Hind)  property  can  be  made  without  such 

was  celebrated   with    great    pomp  majority, 
before   an  immense  assemblage  of 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATDEE.  79 

India '  give  the  law  to  the  whole  of  those  territories,  not 
only  as  they  happen  to  be  at  the  time,  but  however  they 
may  be  constituted  thereafter.  No  matter  how  many  pro- 
vinces may  be  added  to  British  India  in  future,  Acts  of 
Parliament  now  in  force  and  applying  to  '  British  India ' 
would  equally  apply  to  the  new  provinces  added1.  The 
meaning  of  the  terms  '  British  India '  and  '  India '  (includ- 
ing territories  which  are  under  native  princes,  but  under 
'  the  suzerainty  of  Her  Majesty ')  is  more  formally  defined  in 
the  '  Interpretation  Act,'  53  and  53  Viet.,  cap.  63  (1889),  but 
sect.  1 8  makes  this  apply  only  to  Acts  passed  after  the 
Interpretation  Act. 

I  shall  not  here  notice  the  Acts  of  Parliament  applicable 
to  India,  as  that  would  be  beyond  the  direct  scope  of  my 
work  2. 

Such  being  the  powers  of  the  Secretary  of  State  for  India 
and  his  Council,  and  of  the  Imperial  Parliament,  we  may 
now  consider  the  powers  and  constitution  of  the  Government 
of  India. 

§  4.    The  Government  of  India. 

There  is  a  Viceroy3  and  Governor-General  with  the 
supreme  power  of  control  and  supervision  over  all  the 
Governors  and  Lieutenant-Governors  (who  are  the  'Local 
Governments ').  The  Governors  of  Madras  and  Bombay 
retain  some  special  powers  (such  as  that  of  direct  cor- 
respondence with  the  Home  Government)  not  enjoyed  by 
other  Local  Governments,  and  which  in  some  respects 
affect  their  relation  to  the  Government  of  India ;  but  this  it 
is  not  necessary  to  enter  upon. 

1  See  Sir  H.  (then  Mr.)  Maine's  because  it  was  not  till    1849  that 

remarks  in  the  Abstract  of  the  Pro-  the    Panjab    formed    part    of    the 

ceedings  of  the  Legislative  Council  territories  of  the  East  India  Com- 

of  sand  March,  1867  (Calcutta  Gazette,  pany. 

3oth   March,    1867).      Not   so   with  2  An  excellent  collection  of  '  Sta- 

Indian  Acts  : — if  applicable  to  the  tutes  relating  to  India'  (up  to  1881, 

'  whole  of  the  territories  of  the  East  and   Supplement)    is  published   at 

India   Company,'  that   means   the  the   Government  Central  Printing 

territories   as  they  existed   at  the  Office,  Calcutta,  by  the  Legislative 

time.     For  example,  an  Act  passed  Department. 

in  1 848  would  not  (unless  afterwards  3  So  first  styled  in  the  Queen's 

extended)    apply    to    the    Panjab,  Proclamation  of  1858. 


8o  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  nr. 

The  Governor-General  may  also  himself  become  the  Local 
Government  of  certain  provinces  by  taking  them  under  his 
direct  management  (under  the  Act  17  and  18  Viet.,  cap.  77) 
in  the  manner  described  in  the  last  chapter  1.  The  Central 
Provinces,  Oudh,  Assam,  and  Burma,  are  examples  of  this. 
In  such  cases  there  is  a  Chief  Commissioner  who  constitutes 
the  '  Local  Administration.' 

The  Governor- General  is  now  assisted  by  a  Council  of 
five  Ordinary  Members  2.  This  is  the  Executive  Council. 

§  5.    The  first  form  of  Indian  Legislature. 

The  first  Act  which  directly  provided  for  the  form  of 
government  in  India  is  the  13  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  63  (passed  in 
1773),  known  as  'The  Regulating  Act.'  It  provided  that 
the  Government  of  Bengal  should  consist  of  a  Governor- 
General  and  Council  (four  Councillors),  and  this  was  to  be 
the  Supreme  Government,  subject,  however,  to  control  of 
the  Home  authorities  3. 

Legislative  powers  were  given  under  this  Statute  to  the 
Governor-General  for  the  '  Settlement  of  Fort  William ' 
and  other  factories  and  places  subordinate  thereto. 

Madras  and  Bombay  had  not  yet  any  power  of  making 
Regulations.  To  the  former  of  these  Presidencies  powers 
were  given  by  an  Act  of  Parliament  in  1800  (which  ex- 
tended powers  similar  to  those  which  an  Act  of  1781, 
presently  to  be  mentioned,  had  given  to  Bengal). 

In  1807  Bombay  was  provided  for,  and  the  powers  of 
Madras  were  at  the  same  time  improved  and  placed  on  the 
same  footing. 

The  chief  feature  of  the  Regulating  Act  as  it  affected 
legislation,  was,  that  all  laws  required  to  be  registered  in 
the  Supreme  Court  of  Judicature  at  Calcutta,  in  order  to 
give  them  validity.  This  plan  did  not  answer  ;  and  it  was 
amended  by  an  Act  of  1781  4. 

1  See  Chapter  II,  p.  8.  4  The  causes  of  the  change  were 

2  24  and  25  Viet. ,  cap.  67  (Indian  the  antagonism  which  sprang  up 
Councils  Act),  sect.  3.  between   the   Supreme   Court   and 

3  Vide  the  Act,  sees.  7,  8,  and  9,  the    Council.      All    such    matters 
and  Tagore  Lectures  for  1872,  p.  44.  must  necessarily  be  here  omitted. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATURE.  8 1 

§  6.    The  Regulations. 

Under  this  amending  Act  of  1781,  a  large  body  of  Regu- 
lations  was  passed1.  The  Marquis  of  Cornwallis  revised 
and  codified  the  Regulations  in  1793,  and  on  the  ist  of 
May,  1793,  forty-eight  Regulations,  so  revised,  were  passed, 
of  which  the  forty -first  declares  the  purpose  of  forming  into 
a  regular  Code,  all  Regulations  that  might  be  enacted  for 
the  internal  government  of  the  British  territories  in  Bengal. 

That  these  Regulations  did  not  exactly  comply  with  the 
terms  of  the  Act  of  1773,  while  they  exceeded  the  limits  of 
the  powers  given  by  the  Act  of  1781,  there  can  be  no  doubt. 
However,  Parliament  in  1797  (37  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  142)  recog- 
nized them  as  in  fact  valid,  approved  of  the  formation  of  a 
Code  of  such  Regulations,  and  only  added  that  they  should 
be  registered  in  the  'Judicial  Department,'  and  that  the 
reasons  for  each  Regulation  should  be  prefixed  to  it 2.  The 
Code  thus  issued  in  1793  an<^  added  to  down  to  1833, 
forms  what  is  called  the  '  Code  of  Bengal  Regulations 3.' 
There  are  local  Codes  of  Regulations  also  for  Madras  and 
Bombay. 

§  7.    No  provision  for  Provinces  not  annexed  formally 
to  the  Bengal  Presidency. 

It  was  noted  in  the  last  chapter  that  the  force  of  the 
Regulations  was  in  1800  (39  and  40  Geo.  Ill,  cap.  79) 
extended  to  the  province  of  Benares  and  'all  other  fac- 
tories, districts,  and  places  which  now  are,  or  hereafter  shall 
be,  subordinate,  and  to  all  such  provinces  and  districts  as 
may  at  any  time  hereafter  be  annexed  to  the  Presidency  of 
Fort  William  in  Bengal.' 

The  student  who  desires  to  pursue  these  preambles  being,  in  fact,  '  ex- 
the  subject,  may  refer  to  the  Tagore  planatory  memoranda '  of  the  object 
Lectures,    1872    (Lecture    III),    and  and  purpose  of  the  law. 
the  standard  Histories.  3  Part  of  this  is  still  in  force.    The 
1  Tagore  Law  Lectures,  1872,  p.  80.  various  repealing  Acts  have  done 
"  This  is  the  reason  why  long,  away  with  all  obsolete  Regulations  ; 
and    sometimes    very    instructive,  others,  of  course,  have  been  specially 
preambles  are  to  be  found  prefixed  repealed  in  the  course  of  legisla- 
te some  of  the  earlier  Regulations,  tion. 

VOL.  I.  G 


82  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  in. 

In  the  course  of  the  preceding  chapter  I  have  noticed  the 
importance  of  this  provision,  and  also  the  fact  that  various 
new  acquisitions  of  territory,  though  annexed  in  general 
terms  to  the  British  dominions,  were  not  specifically  made 
subordinate,  or  annexed  to,  the  Presidency  of  Bengal.  Con- 
sequently, no  Regulations  applied  to  such  provinces,  nor 
was  there  any  direct  power  of  making  laws  for  them  till 
1834;  nor  was  all  difficulty  connected  with  the  subject 
completely  removed  till  1861. 

§  8.    The  second  Indian  Legislature. 

The  28th  August,  1833 — on  which  day  the  3  and  4  Will. 
IV,  cap.  85,  was  passed — brought  to  a  close  the  era  of  the 
Regulations.  By  the  43rd  section,  the  '  Governor- General 
in  Council '  was  to  make  Laws  and  Regulations  for  all 
persons,  for  all  courts  of  justice,  and  for  all  places  and 
things  within  British  territory  and  regarding  servants  of 
the  Company  in  allied  Native  States. 

The  Act  provided  also  certain  limits  to  the  power  of  the 
Indian  Legislature  with  regard  to  certain  subjects  of 
legislation. 

In  the  former  period,  the  legislative  power  had  been  to 
make  '  Rules,  Regulations,  and  Ordinances ; '  the  term 
'  Regulation '  was  consequently  adopted  as  most  properly 
describing  the  enactments  issued.  Under  the  3  and  4 
Will.  IV,  cap.  85,  the  power  was  given  to  make  laws  as 
well  as  Regulations ;  and  it  thenceforward  became  the 
custom  to  call  the  enactments  of  the  Governor- General 
in  Council  '  Acts.' 

There  is  but  little  specific  difference  in  the  nature  of  a 
Regulation  and  an  Act,  except  that  the  former  were  less 
concisely  and  technically  drafted,  and  were  usually  pre- 
ceded by  the  detailed  expositions  of  the  motives  and  pur- 
pose of  the  enactments  previously  alluded  to.  This,  in 
'  Acts,'  has  been  replaced,  by  the  brief  '  preamble 1.' 

1  There  are  also  some  differences  on  such  details.  The  introduction 
in  the  manner  of  interpretation  ;  to  '  Field's  Chronological  Index  ex- 
but  it  is  not  here  necessary  to  enter  plains  the  subject  clearly.  The 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATURE.  83 

From  1793  to  1833,  therefore,  we  have  'Regulations,' 
and  from  1834  down  to  the  present  day  we  have  '  Acts/ 

These  Acts  are  numbered  consecutively  through  the 
year,  and  follow  the  calendar,  not  the  official,  year.  This 
plan  has  ever  since  been  adhered  to,  notwithstanding  the 
modifications  which  have  affected  the  constitution  of  the 
Legislature  down  to  the  present  time. 

By  the  Act  of  1833,  the  Governments  of  Madras  and 
Bombay  were  deprived  of  the  power  of  legislation,  and  did 
not  regain  this  power  till  1861. 

The  Act  gave  the  Governor- General  a  Council  of  four 
members,  of  whom  one  was  to  be  conversant  with  legal 
subjects.  He  was  not  a  member  of  the  Executive  Council, 
and  only  sat  when  legislation  was  in  question.  Even  then 
he  was  not  necessarily  present ;  nor  need  he  concur  when 
an  Act  was  passed  l.  Under  this  Act,  however,  Commis- 
sioners were  appointed  in  India  to  consider  and  propose 
drafts  of  laws  a. 

§  9.    The  Indian  Legislature  in  its  third  stage. 

Our  present  system  is  nothing  more  than  a  development 
of  the  Legislature  of  the  3  and  4  Will.  IV,  cap.  85.  The 
first  important  change  was  made  by  the  Act  of  1853  (16  and 
17  Viet.,  cap.  15).  It  will  be  interesting  to  follow,  in  a  very 
general  manner,  the  changes  made  3. 

'  Statement  of  Objects  and  Reasons,'  appointed  to  advise  the  Crown,  on 

which  is  always  published  with  the  the  recommendations  of  the   Law 

proposed  law  while  it  is  yet  in  the  Commissioners  in  India, 

stage  of  a  '  Bill,'  does  away  with  3  Acts  passed  under  the  constitu- 

the  necessity  for  any  lengthy  pre-  tion  of  1834  are  technically  styled 

amble  to  the  Act  itself  when  passed.  Acts  of  the  Governor-General  of  India  in 

It  is,  however,  itself  probably  a  relic  Council;  those  under  the  system  of 

of  the  old  exposition  prefixed  to  the  1853  are  Acts  of  the  Legislative  Council 

Regulations.  of  India ;    those    made    since    the 

1  For  an  excellent  comparison  of  Indian  Councils'  Act  of  1861  are 
the  various  Legislatures  in  more  Acts  of  the  Council  of  the  Governor- 
detail,  see  Tagore  Law  Lectures,  1872,  General  of  India  assembled  for  the  pur- 
page  105  et  seq.  pose  of  making  Laws  and  Regulations. 

3  It  was  under  these  provisions  At  the   present  day  the   drafts   of 

that  Lord  Macaulay  came  out,  the  proposed  Acts  are  published  in  the 

result  of  the  Commissioners'  labours  Gazette  of  India,  for  the  purpose  of 

being  the  Indian  Penal  Code,  now  giving  notice  of  the  proposed  law 

so  famous.     By  the  Act  of  1853  a  and  of  invoking  criticism,  and  in 

Law  Commissioner  in  England  was  that  stage  the  draft  is  spoken  of  as 

G    '2, 


LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  in. 


By  this  Act  some  purely  legislative  members  were  added 
to  the  Council.  These  were  appointed,  one  by  each  Governor 
of  a  presidency  or  Lieutenant-Governor  of  a  province. 
The  Chief  Justice  of  Bengal  and  one  of  the  Judges,  were 
also  made  members. 

While,  however,  the  Council  was  thus  improved  in  two 
important  features — (a)  local  representation  of  provinces, 
and  (6)  special  adaptation  for  legislative  functions — it  did 
not  satisfy  the  ideas  of  many  who  could  make  their  opinions 
heard.  In  those  days  the  plan  of  a  local  legislature  for  each 
province  was  strongly  advocated,  and  in  1 859  Lord  Canning 
sent  home  a  despatch,  in  which  not  only  this  subject  was 
dealt  with,  but  the  practice  of  the  existing  Council  was 
criticised.  Lord  Canning  advocated  a  separate  legislature 
for  Bombay,  Madras,  Bengal,  the  North-West  Provinces, 
and  the  Panjab.  He  also  desired  that  natives  of  the 
country  should  be  consulted,  and  that  they  should  be  able 
to  give  their  opinions  in  their  own  language. 


a  '  Bill.'  When  the  Acts  are  passed 
by  the  Council  and  have  received 
the  assent  of  the  Governor-General, 
they  are  also  published  in  the 
Gazette. 

The  Superintendent  of  Govern- 
ment Printing  (at  his  office,  No.  8, 
Hastings  Street,  Calcutta)  publishes 
authorized  copies  of  all  Acts,  which 
can  be  bought  by  the  public  at  a 
small  price,  varying  according  to 
the  length  of  the  Act.  The  Legisla- 
tive Department  is  also  issuing  a 
collected  series  of  the  Acts,  grouped 
in  volumes  of  '  General  Acts,'  and 
in  '  Codes,'  i.  e.  the  Acts  referring 
specially  or  solely  to  each  province. 
In  these  editions,  which  are  of  great 
value,  tables  are  published  showing 
how  all  the  Acts  and  Regulations 
are  disposed  of — by  repeal,  &c.  Only 
unrepealed  enactments  are  printed, 
with  the  alterations  introduced  by 
later  Acts  (if  passed  in  time  for  the 
printing).  The  provincial  volumes, 


or  'Codes,'  of  Bengal,  Madras,  and 
Bombay,  give  all  the  Regulations 
and  Acts  of  the  Local  Legislatures, 
as  well  as  the  Acts  of  the  Supreme 
Legislature  ;  and  all  the  provincial 
volumes  contain  the  '  Regulations ' 
issued  for  certain  districts  under 
the  Act  33  Viet.,  cap.  3.  They  do 
not,  however,  give  the  '  rules  made 
pursuant  to  various  Acts,'  which 
are  now  so  conspicuous  a  feature  in 
recent  Acts.  These  must  be  looked 
for  in  local  Gazettes  or  reprints. 
Such  '  rules'  are,  however,  of  great 
convenience,  enabling  a  multitude 
of  details  to  be  locally  provided  for 
which  could  not  be  entered  in  the 
Act  itself  without  swelling  its  bulk 
enormously,  since  the  '  rules '  are 
as  various  as  are  the  conditions  of 
the  provinces.  The  Forest  Officer 
will  remember  how  important  a 
place  '  rules '  have  in  the  Forest 
Acts  of  1878  and  1881. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    INDIAN    LEGISLATURE.  85 

§10.    The  Indian  Legislature  as  it  is  at  present  (under 
the  Indian  Councils  Act). 

In  1861  was  passed  the  24  and  35  Viet.,  cap.  67,  the 
'  Indian  Councils'  Act,'  which  (as  amended  in  some  particu- 
lars by  later  Statutes)  is  the  law  under  which  our  present 
legislature  subsists 1. 

The  nucleus  of  the  Council  is  the  Executive  Council  of 
the  Governor-General.  This  now  consists  of  five  Ordinary 
Members  (with  the  Commander-in-Chief  as  an  Extraordinary 
Member,  if  so  appointed  by  the  Secretary  of  State).  The 
Governor  of  Madras  or  Bombay  becomes  also  another 
Extraordinary  Member  when  the  Council  sits  in  his  Presi- 
dency. 

Of  the  five  Ordinary  Members,  three  are  officials,  Civil 
or  Military  (of  ten  years'  standing  at  least),  and  of  the 
remaining  two,  one  must  be  a  Barrister  (or  Scotch  Advo- 
cate) of  not  less  than  five  years'  standing.  The  Barrister 
Member  is  generally  spoken  of  as  the  '  Legal  Member '  and 
the  other  as  the  '  Financial  Member.'  When  the  Council 
sits  for  legislative  purposes,  it  has  to  be  supplemented  by 
a  number  of  '  Additional '  Members 2,  for  the  purpose  of 
making  Laws  and  Regulations  only.  These  Additional 
Members  have  no  power  of  voting  except  at  legislative 
meetings.  In  number  they  must  be  not  less  than  six  nor 
more  than  twelve  ;  one-half  the  number  so  nominated  must 
(by  section  10)  be  non-official  persons. 

Provision  is  made  for  the  Council  meeting  in  the  absence 
of  the  Governor-General;  and  for  the  Governor-General, 
when  visiting  any  part  of  India,  exercising  his  power  with- 
out his  Council. 

1  All  the  recent  Acts  of  Parlia-  Department. 

ment,  viz.  from  1855,  can  be  found  2  When  the  Council  sits  in  any 

in  the  Collection  of  Statutes  issued  province,  the  Lieutenant-Governor 

by  Mr.  Whitley  Stokes  in  continua-  (and  by  the  33  Viet.,  cap.  3,  sect. 

tion  of  the  'Law  relating  to  India  3,  a  Chief  Commissioner  also)  be- 

and  the  East  India  Company ' ;  the  comes  ex-officio  a  Member  for  legisla- 

former  can  easily  be  obtained,  the  Urn    purposes    only.       The    ex-officio 

latter  is  now  out  of  print  and  scarce.  Members  may  be  in  excess  of  the 

But  an  edition  of  all  the  Statutes  maximum    of    twelve    Additional 

is  being  printed  in  the  Legislative  Members. 


86  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  in. 

But  this  power  does  not  extend  to  legislation.  The 
Governor-General  can  never  legislate  apart  from  his  Council; 
but  the  Council  may  sit  notwithstanding  the  absence  of  the 
Governor-General.  In  such  cases  a  '  President  in  Council ' 
is  appointed  according  to  the  Act. 

The  Governor- General  (alone)  has,  however,  a  special l 
power  to  issue  ordinances  for  the  peace  and  good  govern- 
ment of  the  country  in  cases  of  emergency. 

Power  is  reserved  to  the  Crown  (through  the  Secretary 
of  State  in  Council)  to  disallow  any  law  or  Regulation 
passed  in  India ;  and  the  powers  of  the  Council  are  restricted 
by  section  22  in  respect  of  certain  subjects  of  legislation. 

The  Indian  Councils  Act  was  amended  by  the  32-33 
Viet.,  cap.  98  (1869),  and  by  37-38  Viet.,  cap.  91  (1874), 
and  by  the  39  Viet.,  cap.  7  (1876). 

§  ii.    Powers  of  Local  Legislatures. 

The  Act  gives  legislative  powers  to  the  Madras  and 
Bombay  Governments ;  consequently,  the  Local  Codes  which 
show  a  blank  after  1833,  begin  to  have  Local  Acts  from 
1862  onwards.  For  the  other  provinces  the  matter  is 
differently  stated.  The  provisions  of  the  Act  are  to  be 
extended  to  the  Lieutenant-Governorship  of  Bengal,  and 
may  be  extended  to  the  North -West  Provinces2  and  the 
Panjab  as  soon  as  the  Governor-General  deems  it  expedient. 

1  See  section  23.     This  remains  in       ting  as  legislative  bodies  (pages  122- 
force  for  a  limited  period  only,  and       23)  : — 

is  subject  to  a  '  veto  '  from  the  Home  '  The  character  of  these  Legisla- 

Grovernment  (Secretary  of  State).  tive  Councils  is   simply  this,  that 

2  Under  these  provisions  the  Ben-  they  are  Committees  for  the  pur- 
gal  Council  was  constituted  by  pro-  pose  of  making  laws,  Committees  by 
clamation    on    the    i7th    January,  means  of  which  the  Executive  Go- 
1862.     A   Local    Council    of    nine  vernment  obtains  advice  and  assist- 
Members  for  the  North- West  Pro-  ance  in  their  legislation,  and  the 
vinces  and  Oudh  was  created   by  public   derive   the   benefit    of  full 
Notification,  No.    1704,  dated  Cal-  publicity  being  ensured   at   every 
cutta,  26th  November,   1886,  with  stage   of  the   law-making  process, 
effect  from  the  ist  December,  1886.  Although   the   Government  enacts 
No  local  legislature  for  the  Panjab  the  laws  through  its  Council,  private 
has  yet  been  constituted.  legislation  being  unknown,  yet  the 

The  following  passage  from  the  public  has  a  right  to  make  itself 

Tagore    Lectures  for    1872     may    be  heard,  and  the  Executive  is  bound 

here  quoted  as  well  describing  the  to  defend  its  legislation, 
functions  of  the  Councils  when  sit-  '  And  when   the  laws  are  once 


CHAP.  III.] 


THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATURE. 


The  local  Governor  is  bound  to  transmit  an  authenticated 
copy  of  any  Law  or  Eegulation  to  which  he  has  assented, 
to  the  Governor-General l.  No  such  local  law  has  any 
validity  till  the  Governor- General  has  assented  thereto,  and 
such  assent  shall  have  been  signified  by  him  to  and  pub- 
lished by  the  Governor.  If  the  assent  is  withheld,  the 
Governor-General  must  signify  his  reasons  in  writing  for  so 


doing. 

made,  the  Executive  is  as  much 
bound  by  them  as  the  public,  and 
the  duty  of  enforcing  them  belongs 
to  the  Courts  of  Justice.  Such  laws 
are  in  reality  the  orders  of  Govern- 
ment, but  they  are  made  in  a  manner 
which  ensures  publicity  and  dis- 
cussion, are  enforced  by  the  Courts 
and  not  by  the  Executive,  cannot  be 
changed  but  by  the  same  deliberate 
and  public  process  as  that  by  which 
they  were  made,  and  can  be  enforced 
against  the  Executive  or  in  favour 
of  individuals  whenever  occasion 
requires.  The  Councils  are  not  de- 
liberative bodies  with  respect  to  any 
subject  but  that  of  the  immediate 


legislation  before  them.  They  can- 
not enquire  into  grievances,  call  for 
information,  or  examine  the  con- 
duct of  the  Executive.  The  acts  of 
administration  cannot  be  impugned, 
nor  can  they  be  properly  defended 
in  such  assemblies,  except  with  re- 
ference to  the  particular  measure 
under  discussion.' 

1  And  if  the  Bill  contains  penal 
clauses,  it  is  ordered  (as  a  matter  of 
administrative  regulation)  by  a  de- 
spatch of  the  Secretary  of  State  of 
ist  December,  1862,  that  it  should 
be  submitted  to  the  Governor- 
General  before  it  is  locally  passed 
into  an  Act. 


88 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  in. 


•suoi:>Bin§9ji  PUB  SAYE^  §up[BUi  jo  gsodind 

JOJ  p9[qUI9SSB  JBJ9U9£)-JOU.I9AO£)  JO  JlOUnOQ 

—                     -A- 

^2  <ri 

•MA. 

il 

i  •*=  M  '"•^ 

o  a  3  >  \, 

lljfl'l 

11 

fi 

J?            rrt  & 

•{punoQ  9ui9jdng 

la 

|^-g!^ 

1 

"       ®                a^"     ^    ^               -S 

r2  ra 

.2  §3     eg 

a 

f>>     a                ®         £      ^,                fe   . 

gO                             JH                 S         3                               ^    "5 

So 

-2    ®  ^  "ft 

O 

x. 

a      ^>                  ^          S      ^                  '5s-2 

^    O          ^  OCx  o 

L 

c    a  ^       .2      a   3          £  -2 

§ 

i* 

OH  •                 S                   "                    o  T* 
§  S               4           S       i                     e  & 

§   \ 

® 

. 

-J                 ?           M       §                      §^ 

O     00 

^    rf 

0 

OB 
g 

_"o 

=a     -|iS            *         a     .3               -§'S 

JC                       ^^  ^                ^           °°                               £rt  ^ 

11 

^8 

1 

® 
^ 

c? 

"^                  O   Pfl3                           ^C3                             0>d                                                    ?HfH 

® 

>,  , 

"*Si 

33  i—  T 

fl 

o 

-§ 

1-1 

j  i'j  |l|i{  {     ij 

•ai 

_^ 

-*i 

t>, 

v"2* 
r'Sl 

-u 

v§ 

r  °° 

§ 

CD 

a 

—   — 

1 

CO 

•s 

£ 

6    ISll&sllI     ^         r    II 

1   l^^lllliel      §s|| 

§^ 
|^ 

?  a 

•rt  o 

5- 
5 

o 

® 
5 
2 

*|H 
3 

s«^ 

^ 

*    "3a    b2p^cs-aSo$®        f-iSo. 

.,:<  jj      ^  V  S  «  o  P<^  ^           ®  2  .d 

^m 

o 

° 

,3 

^H           rg»              »        g           •rt""j3S-*J            '^OcO-"S5*H 

*s  - 

2 

CO 

'1 

2      0®      £*'7  «n  _2      P.g  ^      i  O  'S  p  5 

'i'-sj 

.  ci 

• 

-10 

3 

S      S  "d      3  F§  °  '^      ^S-a         -^l^d'^ 

^         SaS 

-g 

<0 

1 

1 

s 

|!p  ll1  |r  Jl1 

lative  Coun 
[,  Bengal. 

lirects  Goven 
eral  to  appo 
eJan.  i7th, 

'3 
1 

1 

3  ^             S 

T 

=  a  a 
•gJ2  S      I 

'1 

^w          ^  § 

^ 

rO 

j^ 

s  "**         ^p         ft  a 

a 

s? 

o  a         °*        -05  •* 
°         a         s 

& 

5, 

5° 

"a  g3       w        *§  a 

f 

1=1 

°*F 

"§  ••*    *S        Jji  M 

'O 

^> 

|£ 

"B  ^^     *       ®  S 

e3 

S 

c3  t*- 

S  3  a     "43          s>  S 

S" 

&. 

15    H 

Co3      2         '•£  > 

bs 

"tij^ 

®  =w    o          S               ^    ° 

75  .2 

^£ 

?^  •S'S  ^sU^  g 

r                "ii 

^ 

a~  —  .b     2^     j  §  *" 

a  ^ 

®s'"a     C"~B     -0> 

a  -u. 

0    g 

O  ^*-*    ®           r*    f^           J5  .e  O 

*3  p§ 

O               HO      O 

> 

^ 

'^s'o  *  3  o  *** 

•_2 

•5S 

OQ~ 

|  s  £  "g  ^^ 

.2 

60 

"sis 

9  *  ^  &  ^-^ 

2j£  A 

'     O                 >  ~S 

"c3 

I*5 

jliOt    ^ 

J 

CHAP,  in.]  THE   INDIAN    LEGISLATURE.  89 


§  12.    Law  of  'Non-Regulation'  Provinces. 

One  section  (25)  of  the  Indian  Councils  Act  I  have 
reserved  for  notice  till  the  conclusion  of  this  chapter. 

I  have  already  spoken  of  'Non-Regulation  Provinces,' 
and  so  far  explained  how  they  came  into  existence.  We 
have  seen  that,  unless  expressly  made  subordinate  to  the 
presidency,  a  province  did  not  come  within  the  operation  of 
the  Regulations.  Consequently,  up  to  1833,  no  provision 
existed  by  which  anything  in  the  nature  of  a  legislative 
power  existed  for  such  places. 

The  Act  3  and  4  Will.  IV,  cap.  85,  afforded  only  a  partial 
remedy.  It  gave,  it  is  true,  power  to  legislate  for  all 
British  territory,  so  that  provinces  which  were  already 
British  territory  at  the  time  were  provided  for;  but 
nothing  was  said  about  the  application  of  such  Acts,  if 
general  in  their  character,  to  provinces  not  at  the  time 
British  provinces,  but  added  afterwards  1.  It  soon  became 
doubtful  how  far  such  Acts  were  practically  in  force.  But 
the  chief  difficulty  was,  that  in  the  newer  provinces  a  num- 
ber of  matters  had  been  provided  for  by  local  rules,  circular 
orders,  and  official  instructions,  which  emanated  from  the 
executive,  but  not  from  any  legislative,  authority.  Busi- 
ness could  not  have  been  carried  on  without  such  rules, 
yet  there  was  no  legal  basis  for  them,  only  the  sanction  of 
practice. 

The  Indian  Councils  Act  of  1861  removed  the  difficulty, 
and  by  section  25  provides  that  '  no  rule,  law,  or  regulation 
which,  prior  to  the  passing  of  this  Act,  shall  have  been 
made  by' 

the  Governor-General, 

the  Governor-General  in  Council, 

the  Governor, 

the  Governor  in  Council, 

the  Lieutenant-Governor, 


1  Vide  note,  p.  79  ;   the  remarks  able  to  all  British  territory,  was  not 

there    quoted   were    made   in    the  legally  in  force,  e.  g.  in  the  Panjab, 

Council  with  reference  to  the  Act  because  in  1835  the  Panjab  was  not 

XI  of  1835,  which,  though  applic-  British  territory. 


9O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  HI. 

for  and  in  respect  of  any  such  non-regulation  province  (i.  e. 
territory  known  from  time  to  time  as  a  non-regulation  pro- 
vince) shall  be  deemed  invalid,  '  only  by  reason  of  the  same 
not  having  been  made  in  conformity '  with  the  provisions  of 
Acts  regarding  the  powers  and  constitution  of  Councils  and 
other  authorities 1. 

§  13.    Local  Laws  Acts. 

In  order  to  remove  any  possible  doubt  on  the  subject,  the 
Indian  Legislature  has  since  expressly  enacted  '  Local  Laws 
Acts,'  which  state  what  Rules  and  Acts  and  Regulations  are 
to  be  deemed  to  be  in  force  in  the  chief  non-regulation  pro- 
vinces. In  the  Panjab  we  have  Act  IV  of  1872  (amended 
by  XII  of  1878);  for  Oudh,  Act  XVIII  of  1876;  for  the 
Central  Provinces,  Act  XX  of  1875. 

In  1874,  also,  an  Act  was  passed  (No.  XV  of  1874)  which 
is  called  the  '  Laws  Local  Extent  Act,'  and  this,  in  a  series 
of  schedules,  gives  a  list  of  previous  Acts  and  Regula- 
tions which  extend  to  the  whole  of  India,  or  to  the  particular 
province  (as  the  case  may  be),  and  the  applicability  of  which 
was,  or  might  be,  previously  doubtful. 

§  14.    Scheduled  Districts. 

As  regards  the  extent  and  nature  of  the  law  in  force,  the 
old  distinction  of  '  Regulation '  and  '  Non-Regulation '  has 
entirely  lost  its  meaning.  Many  of  the  old  Regulations 
have  been  repealed  or  superseded,  and  some  of  those  that 
remain  have  been  expressly  declared  to  apply  to  the  Non- 
Regulation  Provinces.  Not  only  so,  but  all  the  more 
important  branches  of  legislation — Civil  and  Criminal 
Procedure,  Land  Revenue,  Stamps,  Excise,  Irrigation,  the 

1  When   rules  and   orders  were  Governor-General.    In  this  way  the 

made  by '  Boards  of  Administration '  Panjab  Forest   Rules  of   1855  had 

or    'Chief    Commissioners,'     they  validity,  owing  to  their  confirmation 

would  not  have  validity  under  the  by  the  Governor-General  in  Council. 

Indian   Councils  Act,  unless  they  This  validity  has  since  been  affirmed 

had  been  confirmed  by  the  Governor-  by  the  insertion  of  the  rules  in  the 

General,  in  which   case  they  vir-  schedule  of  the  Panjab  Laws  Act. 
tually  became  rules  made  by  the 


CHAP.  III.] 


THE    INDIAN   LEGISLATIVE. 


Law  of  Contract,  the  Criminal  Law — have  been  provided 
for  either  by  general  Acts  which  apply  to  all  the  provinces 
at  large,  or  by  special  Acts  containing  local  details,  but 
resembling  each  other  in  principle.  But  there  is  still  a 
practical  distinction  of  another  kind  to  be  mentioned,  which 
is  of  importance  and  likely  long  to  be  maintained. 

There  apportions  of  the  older  Eegulation  Provinces,  and 
also  portions  of  the  newer  Non-Regulation  Provinces  them- 
selves, which  are  '  Extra  Regulation '  in  a  perfectly  valid  and 
current  sense.  These  are  now  spoken  of  as  the  '  Scheduled  dis- 
tricts,' under  the  Act  (XIV  of  1874)  passed  to  place  them  on 
an  intelligible  basis  as  regards  the  laws  in  force  in  them l. 

The  districts  are  called  '  Scheduled '  because  they  are 
noted  in  the  '  Schedules '  of  Act  XIV  of  1874. 

None  of  the  Acts  of  a  general  character  passed  before 
1874,  the  local  application  of  which  is  settled  by  Act  XV  of 


1  The  list  may  be  summarised  as 
follows : — 

Scheduled  Districts,  Bengal 
I. — The  Jalpaigiiri  and  Darjil- 

ing  Divisions. 
II.— The  Hill  Tracts  of  Chitta- 

gong. 

III.— The  Santal  Parganas. 
IV.— The  Chutlya  Nagpur  Divi- 
sion. 

North-Western  Provinces. 
I. — The  Jhansi  Division,  com- 
prising the   districts  of 
Jhansi,  Jalaun,  and  La- 
litpur. 
II. — The  Province  of  Kumaon 

and  Garhwal. 

III. — The  Tarai  Parganas,  com- 
prising Bazpur,  Kashi- 
pur,  Jaspur,  Rudarpur, 
Gadarpur,  Kilpuri, 

Nanak-Mattha,  and  Bil- 
heri. 
IV. — In  the  Mirzapur  District — 

(1)  The    tappas    of  Agori 
Khas  and  South  Kon  in 
the  pargana  of  Agori. 

(2)  The  tappa   of  British 
Singrauli  in  the  pargana 
of  Singrauli. 

(3)  The  tappas  of  Phulwa, 
Dudhi,  and  Barha  in  the 
pargana  of  Bichipar. 


(4)  The   portion  lying    to 
the  south  of  the  Kaimxir 
range. 
V. — The  Family  Domains  of  the 

Maharaja  of  Benares. 
VI. — The  tract  of  country  known 
as  Jaunsar-Bawar  in  the 
Dehra-Dun  district. 

Punjab. 

The  districts  of  Hazara,  Peshawar, 
Kohat,  Bannu,  Dera  Ismail  Khan, 
Dera  Ghazi  Khan,  Lahaul,  and 
Spiti. 

Central  Provinces. 

No  part  of  the  Central  Provinces 
is  now  '  scheduled.' 
The  Chief  Commissionership  of  Ajmer 

and  Merwdra. 
The  Chief  Commissionership  of  Assam. 

British  Burma. 
The  Hill  Tracts  of  Arracan. 

Madras. 

Certain  estates  in  Ganjam,  Viza- 
gapatam,  and  Godavari  districts 
^besides  the  Laccadive  Islands). 

Bombay. 

Sindh  ,the  Panch  Mahals  (attached 
to  the  Kaira  Collectorate),  Aden, 
and  certain  villages  of  Mehwasi 
Chiefs. 

Coorg. 

The  whole  province  (Chief  Com- 
missionership). 


92  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  HI. 

this  same  year,  apply  directly  to  the  Scheduled  districts  ;  it 
is  left  to  the  Local  Government  to  define  by  notification  in 
each  case, — 

(a)  what  laws  are  not  in  force  (so  as  to  remove  doubts 
in  case  it  might  be  supposed  that  some  law 
was  in  force) ; 
(6)  what  laws  are  in  force ; 

(c)  and  to  extend  Acts  or  parts  of  Acts  to  the  dis- 
trict in  question. 

Of  course  all  Acts  passed  since  1874  themselves  define  to 
what  territories  they  extend,  so  that  there  can  be  no  further 
doubt  on  the  matter. 

§  15.    Regulations  under  33  Viet.,  cap.  3. 

In  order  to  provide  a  still  more  elastic  and  adaptable 
method  of  making  rules  which  have  legal  validity,  for  pro- 
vinces in  an  elementary  stage  of  progress,  the  Act  33  Viet., 
cap.  3  (1870),  provides  that  certain  territories  may  at  any 
time  be  declared  by  the  Secretary  of  State  to  be  territories 
for  which  it  is  desirable  that  special  Regulations  (other  than 
the  Acts  of  the  Legislature)  should  be  made.  The  districts 
so  declared  (if  not  already  under  Act  XIV)  become  '  Sche- 
duled '  whenever  such  declaration  is  made,  so  that  there  is 
in  fact  a  power  of  creating  new  scheduled  districts  in  addi- 
tion to  those  in  that  Act.  The  Regulations  regarding  Hazara 
in  the  Panjab,  the  Santal  Parganas  in  Bengal,  regarding 
Assam,  Ajmer,  and  the  Hill  Tracts  of  Arracan,  &c.,  are  all 
under  this  law.  They  are  at  once  known  from  the  old 
'Regulations'"  (of  1793-1833)  by  their  bearing  date  since 
1870. 

§  1 6.    Re'sume". 

In  order  to  aid  the  student  in  remembering  the  principal 
stages  in  the  growth  of  the  Legislature,  I  present  the  follow- 
ing skeleton  or  abstract : — 

(i)  Originally  each  presidency  had  its  own  President 
and  Council :  no  formal  legislature  being  needed 
for  settlers  who  bring  their  own  law  with  them 
to  the  '  factory '  in  which  they  settle. 


CHAP.  III.] 


THE   INDIAN   LEGISLATURE. 


93 


(2)  Territories  acquired  and  formal  govern-, 

A.  D.         ment   begins  ;  Courts   have   to 

1773 

I78i!          deal  with  natives  of  the  country ; 

1797.  Legislative  power  necessary: 
given  by  the  '  Regulating  Act '  of 
1773,  subject  to  supervision  of  Supreme 
Court.  This  does  not  work,  and  is 
amended  in  1781,  but  incompletely. 

(3)  A  number  of '  Regulations '  made ;  codified 

in  1793  ;  recognised  as  valid  by  Act  of 
Parliament,  1797.  This,  with  subse- 
quent additions  up  to  1833,  forms  the 
Code  of  '  Bengal  Regulations.' 

(4)  Legislature  of  1834  (3  and  4  Will.  IV, 

A-  D-         cap.  85)  for  British  India. 

1833. 

The  '  Acts '  begin  1 834  and  onwards. 

(5)  Improved     in    1853     by    adding    local 

A.  D.         members  from  provinces  and 
some  judicial  authorities. 


tt* 


ill! 


a  S 


1853. 


(6)  Finally  improved  by  Indian  Councils' 
Act,  1 86 1. 


a  $ 

o  "O 


A.  D. 

1861. 


Bfi.S    O 


IfjiJ* 


(7)  Special  power  given  to  Secretary  of  State  to  declare 
A.  D.         certain   territories   amenable   to   the  33 
1870.         Viet.,  cap.  3.     Thereon  the  head  of  the 
Local  Government  or  Administration  may  pro- 
pose to  the  Governor-General  in  Council  a  Regu- 
lation, which,  on  being  approved  by  him,  becomes 
law. 


CHAPTEE  IV. 


A   GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE   LAND-TENURES    OF 
BRITISH    INDIA. 


SECTION  I — THE  LINES  OF  STUDY. 

§  i.   Object  of  the  Chapter. 

THE  heading  of  this  chapter  is  perhaps  a  somewhat 
startling  one.  I  ma}7  therefore  express  a  hope  that  it  will 
not  be  misunderstood  or  taken  as  indicating  an  attempt  to 
propound  a  general  theory  of  origin  for  all  the  varieties  of 
land-tenure  that  are  to  be  found  in  India.  It  may  well  be 
doubted  whether  any  such  theory  is,  at  present  at  any  rate, 
possible ;  certainly  I  have  no  pretensions  to  be  competent 
to  suggest  one.  And,  even  if  such  a  theory  were  possible, 
it  might  be  further  questionable  whether  it  would  be  of  use 
to  the  student  of  practical  land-administration. 

At  the  same  time  there  may  be  great  advantage  to  be 
derived  from  bringing  together  in  one  chapter  various 
leading  facts  about  Indian  land-tenures.  It  would  be 
strange  if  the  comparative  method,  which  has  been  found 
fruitful  in  other  branches  of  study  bearing  on  the  language 
and  progress  of  mankind,  should  be  infructuous  here.  I  am 
not  aware  of  any  treatise  in  which  facts  regarding  various 
provincial  and  local  forms  of  land-holding  in  India  have 
been  brought  together  for  the  purpose  of  comparative  treat- 
ment. The  attempt  made  in  this  chapter  will  not  then  be 
going  over  old  ground. 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  95 

§  2.    Value  of  the  Comparative  Method. 

A  comparative  study  of  land-tenures  will  bring  out 
one  thing :  there  are  certain  common  factors  which  have, 
at  least  within  wide  geographical  or  ethnical  limits, 
always  been  at  work  in  the  production  of  the  tenures 
we  actually  see  around  us  in  the  several  provinces.  Had 
these  been  always  observed,  we  should  have  been 
spared  some  strange  mistakes.  I  may  instance  the 
case  of  that  curious  district  on  the  west  coast  of  India 
known  as  Malabar.  From  the  tenure  point  of  view  Mala- 
ba"r  presents  in  its  limited  area  quite  a  number  of  instruc- 
tive and,  in  one  sense,  unique  facts.  It  is  like  one  of  those 
little  glens  sometimes  found  by  botanists,  in  which  a  group 
of  plant-treasures — not  to  be  found  over  many  square  miles 
outside — all  at  once  reward  his  search.  Malabar  was  long 
a  source  of  puzzled  remarks  from  reporters  on  land  affairs. 
It  was  supposed,  for  instance,  that  here  '  private  property  ' 
in  land  had  existed,  while  it  could  not  be  found  anywhere 
else.  It  was  also  asserted  that  here,  exceptionally,  no  land- 
revenue  had  been  levied  on  the  '  proprietor '  before  the 
Mysore  conquest.  Both  remarks,  though  often  repeated, 
are  quite  without  foundation.  A  study  of  the  early  Dra- 
vidian-Hindu  organization,  and  a  comparison  of  the  history 
of  the  military  chiefs  of  the  country  with  that  observable 
in  Oudh  and  other  parts,  would  have  enabled  a  more  correct 
interpretation  to  be  put  on  the  facts.  The  strong  proprie- 
tary holdings  of  Malabar  in  all  probability  grew  up  in 
exactly  the  same  way  as  similar  rights  did  in  Northern 
India.  And  as  to  land-revenue,  wherever  chiefs  of  a  con- 
quering or  military  caste  are  known  to  have  held  estates  on 
a  sort  of  feudal  system,  they  will  be  found  never  to  have 
paid  land-revenue  to  the  Raja  or  over- lord.  But  when  in 
the  ups  and  downs  of  fortune  the  rule  was  lost,  and  the 
chiefs'  estates  became  dismembered,  and  the  descendants 
(as  often  happens  in  such  cases)  managed  to  regain  the  land 
in  a  new  capacity,  it  was  not  to  be  supposed  that  they  could 
escape  the  natural  responsibilities  of  the  changed  position ; 


96  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

in  other  words,  it  was  not  in  the  nature  of  things  to  be 
supposed — in  Malabar  any  more  than  elsewhere — that  the 
next  ruling  power  should  abstain  from  levying  a  land- 
revenue  on  such  lands.  However,  this  is  all  by  way  of 
anticipation :  I  must  not  go  into  details ;  what  has  been 
said  is  only  with  a  view  to  illustrate  the  uses  of  comparison 
in  the  study  of  land-tenures.  It  cannot  be  a  matter  of 
chance,  nor  a  case  in  which  we  must  abstain  from  drawing 
inferences,  that  a  claim  to  strong  '  birth-right '  tenures  is, 
all  over  India,  found  to  arise  among  the  descendants  of 
military  chieftains  who  had  been  colonizers  or  conquerors 
and  who  have  undergone  the  usual  changes.  And  if  so,  the 
origin  of  Malabar  claims,  and  their  relative  value,  is  ex- 
plained. 

Whatever  may  be  thought,  however,  of  the  benefits 
to  be  derived  from  a  comparison  of  local  tenures,  it  can 
hardly  be  doubted  that  by  a  preliminary  study  of  this 
kind,  we  can  gain  a  certain  familiarity  with  common 
forms  and  with  terms  of  constant  occurrence  in  revenue 
literature,  which  will  greatly  simplify  our  after  study,  and 
will  enable  the  separate  provincial  chapters  in  the  sequel 
to  be  written  without  the  necessity  for  explaining  over 
and  over  again  terms  and  facts  which  must  recur  in 
each. 

And,  fortunately,  there  are  certain  features  in  the  circum- 
stances of  our  Indian  provinces  which  indicate  the  lines  on 
which  a  general  study  may  be  pursued. 

§  3.    Land  grouped  in  '  Villages.' 

We  can  hardly  help  beginning  with  the  general  fact  that 
all  the  races  of  India  whose  history  we  are  to  any  extent 
acquainted  with,  have,  when  they  passed  the  nomadic  or 
pastoral  stage,  and  took  to  settled  agriculture,  formed 
certain  groups  of  land-holdings,  more  or  less  connected 
together,  and  which  we  call '  VILLAGES.'  At  least  that  is 
true  for  all  the  districts  in  the  plain  country  where  there 
are  no  exceptional  features. 

I  have  already  explained,  in  an  introductory  chapter,  that 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  97 

the  term  'village,'  as  we  use  it,  means  a  group  of  land- 
holdings,  with  (usually)  a  central  aggregate  of  residences, 
the  inhabitants  of  which  have  certain  relations,  and  some 
kind  of  union  or  bond  of  common  government l.  In  the 
course  of  time  modifications  arise  in  the  ownership  and 
constitution  of  village  societies ;  but  once  given  a  local 
name,  the  '  village '  remains  a  feature  on  the  district  map 
in  spite  of  all.  Family  partitions,  for  instance,  and  transfers, 
may  cause  one  village  to  be  divided  between  several 
estates,  or  may  unite  twenty  villages  under  one  owner,  but 
as  a  local  feature  the  '  village  '  always  remains. 

The  village,  its  various  forms  and  the  modifications  it 
undergoes,  will  then  form  a. natural  starting-point  for  our 
study  of  tenures. 


§  4.   Effects  of  Land-Revenue  Administration  and 
Revenue-farming. 

Then  again,  the  greater  Oriental  governments  which 
preceded  ours,  have  always,  in  one  form  or  another,  de- 
rived the  bulk  of  their  State-revenues  and  Royal  property 
from  the  land.  In  one  system  known  to  us,  '  Royal  lands  ' 
were  allotted  in  the  principal  villages,  and  this  fact  may 
have  suggested  to  the  Mughals  their  plan  of  allotting 
special  farms  and  villages  to  furnish  the  privy  purse,  and 
has  had  other  survivals.  Eut,  speaking  generally,  the 
universal  plan  of  taking  revenue  was  by  taking  a  share  of 
the  actual  grain  heap  on  the  threshing-floor  from  each 
holding.  Afterwards  this  was  commuted  for  a  money 
payment  levied  on  each  estate  or  each  field  as  the  case 

1  In  revenue  language,  I  may  which  had  features  in  common 
repeat,  the  village  is  the  '  mauza '  with  some  forms  of  Indian  village. 
or  'din'  (P.).  In  the  Hindi  dia-  The  'village'  group  varies  in  size, 
lects  it  is  variously  ganw,  gramam,  In  the  Panjab  it  averages  goo  acres, 
graon,  gaum,  or  some  similar  form.  in  the  Central  Provinces  1300  acres, 
In  Elphinstone's  History  of  India  in  the  North-West  Provinces,  where 
and  many  other  works,  the 'village'  population  is  denser,  and  land 
is  called  a  '  township.'  I  am  not  highly  cultivated  and  much  sub- 
aware  of  any  advantage  possessed  divided,  it  is  600  acres  (Stack's  Memo- 
by  this  term,  except  that  it  is  randum  on  Temporary  Settlements,  1880, 
equivalent  to  the  Saxon  'fill'  p.  8). 

VOL.  I.  H 


98  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  IV. 

might  be.  The  nature  and  consequence  of  this  system  as 
it  affects  our  modern  land-revenue,  will  be  dealt  with  in 
detail  in  the  next  chapter.  Here  I  only  state  the  fact. 
To  collect  this  revenue,  the  ruler  appointed  or  recognized 
not  only  a  headman  and  accountant  in  each  village,  but 
also  a  hierarchy  of  graded  officials  in  districts  and  minor 
divisions  of  territory  formed  for  administrative  purposes. 
These  officers  were  often  remunerated  by  holdings  of  land, 
and  a  class  of  land-tenures  will  be  found  in  some  parts  of 
India  owing  its  origin  to  these  hereditary  official  holdings. 
Not  only  so,  but  during  the  decline  which  Oriental 
governments  have  usually  undergone,  the  Revenue  officials 
have  been  commonly  found  to  merge  in,  or  be  superseded 
by,  revenue-farmers — persons  who  contracted  for  a  certain 
sum  of  revenue  to  be  paid  into  the  Treasury  from  a  given 
area,  as  representing  the  State  dues  exigible  from  the  land- 
holdings  within  that  area.  Such  revenue-farmers,  or 
officials,  whatever  their  origin,  have  always  tended  to 
absorb  the  interests  of  the  land-holders  1  and  to  become  in 
time  the  virtual  landlords  over  them. 

Nor  is  it  only  that  landlord  tenures  arise  in  this  way. 
No  sooner  does  the  superior  right  take  shape  than  we  find 
many  curious  new  tenures  created  by  the  landlord  or 
arising  out  of  his  attempts  to  conciliate  or  provide  for 
certain  eminent  claims  in  the  grade  below  him. 


§  5.  Effects  of  Assignment  or  Remission  of  Land-Revenue. 

Yet  another  class  of  tenures  arises  in  connection  with  the 
State  Revenue-administration  ;  and  that  is  when  the  ruler 
either  excuses  an  existing  land-holder  from  paying  his  re- 
venue, either  wholly  or  in  part ;  or  '  alienates '  or  assigns 
the  revenue  of  a  certain  estate  or  tract  of  country  in  favour 
of  some  chief,  or  other  person  of  importance,  or  to  provide 
funds  for  some  special  objects,  or  to  serve  as  a  recompense 
for  services  to  be  rendered. 

1  See  Maine,  Early  History  of  Institutions,  p.  150. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  99 

At  first  such  grants  are  carefully  regulated,  are  for  life 
only,  and  strictly  kept  to  their  purpose,  and  to  the  amount 
fixed.  But  as  matters  go  on,  and  the  ruler  is  a  bad  or 
unscrupulous  one,  his  treasury  is  empty,  and  he  makes 
such  grants  to  avoid  the  difficulty  of  finding  a  cash  salary. 
The  grants  become  permanent  and  hereditary ;  they  are  also 
issued  by  officials  who  have  no  right  to  make  them ;  and 
not  only  do  they  then  result  in  landlord  tenures  and 
other  curious  rights,  but  are  a  burden  to  after  times, 
and  have  furnished  a  most  troublesome  legacy  to  our 
own  Government  when  it  found  the  revenues  eaten  up  by 
grantees  whose  titles  were  invalid,  and  whose  pretensions, 
though  grown  old  in  times  of  disorder,  were  inadmissible. 

Such  grants  may  have  begun  with  no  title  to  the  land 
but  only  a  right  to  the  revenue,  but  want  of  supervision 
and  control  has  resulted  in  the  grantee  seizing  the  landed 
right  also.  Here  we  have  another  '  common  factor '  which 
has  everywhere  been  at  work — the  influence  of  State 
organization  and  revenue  systems  on  landholding. 

§  6.    Superimposition  of  Landed  Rights. 

The  mention  of  tenures  arising  out  of  official  relations 
with  the  land  and  revenue-farming,  reminds  us  that  these 
tenures  do  not  always,  or  even  generally,  arise  over  un- 
occupied lands,  or  where  there  are  no  pre-existing  interests. 
They  strike,  in  fact,  the  key-note  of  '  superimposition ' 
and  'modification';  one  set  of  tenures  supervening  on 
another  and  producing  changes. 

This  will  not  be  understood  as  leading  the  reader  to 
suppose  that  the  great  historic  conquests  with  their  new 
systems  of  government  produced  any  radical  or  wholesale 
disruption  of  the  previous  state  of  things,  as  the  Roman 
conquest  did  in  Europe.  The  changes  were  gradual  and 
often  insensible  ;  the  modified  tenures  were  not  the  result  of 
any  defined  purpose  to  change,  or  any  distinct  principle 
which  was  enforced.  They  represented  an  indefinite  sort  of 
compromise  between  old  facts  and  new  conditions:  still 

H  2 


IOO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  IV. 

there  was  modification.  For  example ;  a  man  represents 
the  family  of  the  leader  of  a  party  of  colonizers  who  founded 
'a  Bengal  village  generations  ago.  As  such  he  is  the  vir- 
tual, though  not  legally  defined,  proprietor  of  the  best 
lands  in  the  village  formed  by  the  groups  of  colonists. 
But  time  goes  on,  and  a  State  '  Zamindar '  arises  to  con- 
tract for  the  revenues,  and  gradually  destroys  the  rights 
under  him ;  but  the  man  we  have  spoken  of  is  strong 
enough  or  respected  enough  to  influence  even  the  '  Zamin- 
dar,' who  thereon  gives  him  a  writing  acknowledging  or 
granting  to  him  a  perpetual  tenure  at  a  fixed  and  unalter- 
able rent.  Practically  the  man  is  as  well  off  as  he  was 
before — perhaps  better ;  but  it  is  impossible  to  deny  that 
the  colour  of  his  tenure  is  changed. 

Or  again,  let  us  go  back  to  an  early  cultivating  settle- 
ment, perhaps  in  the  days  of  the  Gond  or  other  ancient 
kingdoms.  Even  this  represents  a  somewhat  advanced 
stage,  for  before  the  ideas  of  the  people  had  got  to  appre- 
ciate a  definite  right  to  clear  and  cultivate  permanently 
a  given  area,  there  must  have  been  a  previous  stage  of 
nomadic  and  shifting  cultivation  in  the  forest.  But  let 
that  pass.  The  village  may  remain  for  centuries  in  this 
stage.  The  different  members  all  claim  their  own  cleared 
holdings,  and  perhaps  one  or  two  leading  men  hold  a  here- 
ditary headship  with  certain  customary  powers  and  privi- 
leges. The  time  however  comes  when  it  is  conquered  by 
a  marauding  Rajput  clan,  or  interfered  with  by  some  of  the 
indigenous  princes  converted  to  Hinduism  and  adopting 
Aryan  ideas  of  government ;  or  the  Raja  or  chief  makes' 
a  grant  of  the  village  to  some  member  of  his  family.  In 
short,  a  landlord  is  found  for  the  village.  The  lord  dies  and 
is  succeeded  by  sons  and  grandsons.  A  change  in  the  village 
constitution  thus  occurs.  The  family  form  a  '  community  ' 
jointly  claiming  to  own  the  whole.  They  have  themselves 
cleared  and  cultivated  the  surrounding  waste  ;  they  have 
bought  up  some  of  the  older  cultivated  lands,  and  got  rid  of 
the  holders  of  others,  and  the  relics  of  the  original  village 
body  that  remain  are  now  the  'tenants'  of  the  superior 


CHAP,  vi.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  IOI 

family.  This  landlord  family,  or  'proprietary  body,'  is  at 
first  closely  united  ;  all  have  equal  rights,  and  they  do  not 
divide.  But  in  time  quarrels  arise,  and  a  desire  for  sepa- 
rate enjoyment  grows.  The  '  community  '  then  divide  the 
land  into  major  and  minor  shares  or  lots,  but  still  hold 
together  and  have  certain  common  rights  and  the  waste  in 
common.  This  state  of  things  is,  however,  in  its  turn 
affected  by  the  Muhammadan  conquest  and  by  the  or- 
ganized system  which  the  Mughal  Empire  introduced.  Not 
so  much  at  first:  they  are  ruthlessly  assessed  to  a  full 
revenue,  and  this  a  little  damps  their  pretensions  ;  they 
are  more  and  more  evidently  graded  as  peasant- proprietors, 
that  is  all.  But  in  time  the  proprietary  body  find  their 
rights  ignored ;  a  revenue-farmer  first  acts  as  their  landlord, 
and  ends  by  calling  himself  so,  till  his  descendants  are 
found,  after  a  generation  or  two,  talking  about  their  '  an- 
cient rights '  under  the  '  law  and  constitution  of  the  coun- 
try ! '  The  old  village  rights  have  disappeared  altogether. 

Then  come  Maratha  plunderers,  Rohilla  adventurers,  or 
an  advance  of  Sikh  clans.  All  fasten  on  the  land,  and  all 
devise  some  scheme  of  making  a  profit  out  of  it,  which  in 
the  end  affects  the  land-tenures. 


§  7.    Effect  of  Modern  Laws. 

Lastly,  the  British  rule  comes  upon  the  confusion  and 
ruin  caused  by  centuries  of  such  changes.  Able  adminis- 
trators, often  actuated  by  the  highest  motives,  but  necessarily 
guided  by  the  ideas  which  are  natural  to  their  age  and 
antecedents,  endeavour  to  settle  landed  rights  and  the 
revenues  of  the  State  on  some  equitable  system.  They 
perceive  that  the  result  of  all  that  has  gone  before  has  been 
not  merely  to  efface  old  tenures,  and  substitute  new 
interests  in  their  places,  but  rather  to  leave  traces  of  several 
different  rights,  and  to  impose,  as  it  were,  layer  upon  layer 
of  interests,  each  revealing  itself  in  varying  degrees  of 
strength  or  preservation. 

In  dealing  with  such  a  state  of  things  many  mistakes  are 


102  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

made.  Tenures  are  not  understood,  or  are  misunderstood  ; 
faulty  systems  of  revenue-assessment  and  collection  are 
adopted,  and  great  distress  and  much  injustice  result.  In 
the  end  matters  slowly  right  themselves ;  and  then  it  is 
desired  to  fix  by  law,  in  a  definite  manner,  the  principles 
on  which  rights  are  to  be  enjoyed  and  the  form  in  which 
they  are  to  be  secured  and  recorded.  The  task  is  one  of 
great  difficulty :  as  its  accomplishment  progresses,  diverg- 
ence of  authorities  occurs,  evidence  is  found  conflicting,  and 
public  opinion  changes.  With  the  best  intention  of  avoid- 
ing special  theories,  Western  terms  and  the  principles  of 
Western  jurisprudence  make  their  influence  felt,  and  the 
last  stage  in  modification  of  the  old  order  is  only  reached 
when  the  British  legislation,  earnestly  desiring  to  do 
practical  justice  to  all  classes  of  rights,  establishes,  confers 
and  consolidates  rights,  defining  and  classifying  them  as 
best  it  may,  calling  this  man  a  landlord  and  that  a  tenant, 
and  shading  off  the  intermediate  claims  into  defined  grades 
of  '  inferior-proprietor,'  '  tenure-holder,'  '  occupancy-tenant,' 
and  what  not ;  trying  always  to  provide  equitably,  but  not 
always  succeeding  in  doing  so,  in  order  that  no  really  sur- 
viving rights  may  be  ignored. 


§  8.   Effects  of  Economic  Conditions. 

Nor  must  we  attribute  all  modification  to  historical  events 
and  legislative  efforts.  All  the  time  economic  conditions 
are  silently  bearing  their  part  in  modifying  ideas  and  cus- 
toms of  land-holding.  Originally  the  foundation  of  every 
one's  interest  in  land,  whether  it  is  the  king's,  or  the  landlord- 
family's,  or  the  cultivator's,  is  the  grain  heap,  the  natural 
produce,  divided  by  some  process  or  another,  in  kind. 

But  as  cultivation  occupies  more  and  more  of  the  area, 
and  waste  for  new  tillage  diminishes,  population  increases, 
and  farms  become  more  and  more  subdivided.  No  doubt 
subdivision  means  increased  care  and  effort  bestowed  on 
the  land,  the  increase  of  works  of  irrigation  and  the  use  of 
manure,  and  thus  the  produce  is  largely  increased  ;  but  this 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  1 03 

cannot  go  on  for  ever,  and  the  time  comes  when  the  shares 
of  the  produce  for  the  different  parties  cannot  all  be  taken. 
For  the  share  which  meets  the  expense  of  cultivation  and 
feeds  and  clothes  the  ploughman,  remains  a  constant,  at  any 
rate  a  not  diminishing  quantity,  and  the  surplus  from  each 
diminished  holding  becomes  less.  Meanwhile  coined  money 
comes  into  common  use,  and  the  king  or  the  chief,  instead 
of  facing  the  inevitable  and  reducing  his  grain  share  to  a 
lower  fraction,  seizes  on  the  fact  that  he  can  take  coin 
instead  of  grain.  Grain  shares  are  given  up,  and  money 
payments  adjusted  in  the  rough,  and  without  attempting 
a  valuation  of  the  actual  produce,  still  less  of  appraising 
the  acres  according  to  their  different  productive  capacities. 
This  changes  the  relations  of  cultivator  and  over-lord,  and 
modifies  the  whole  basis  of  agricultural  society.  'Rent,' 
'  enhancement,'  '  competition,'  or  their  equivalent  phrases 
begin  to  be  talked  of.  When  population  increases  also, 
land  ceases  to  be  over-abundant,  the  race  to  secure  land 
for  cultivation  begins,  and  not  as  before  to  coax  cultivators 
to  the  land.  Waste  is  increasingly  broken  up  and  new 
forms  of  tenure  depending  on  arrangements  for  utilizing 
the  waste  land  multiply.  Here  again  is  a  new  field  for 
settled  law  and  orderly  administration  to  define,  to  regu- 
late, and  to  protect. 

§  9.   Resume. 

Let  us  now  gather  up  these  various  heads  of  study,  and 
we  may  arrange  our  subjects  for  a  '  general  view '  in  the 
following  order : — 

(1)  The  village  and  its  modifications. 

(2)  Tenures  arising  from  official  position,  State  grants, 

and  assignment  or  remission  of  State  revenue, 
as  well  as  for  the  conversion  of  revenue-farmers 
or  collecting  agencies  into  proprietors  and  pro- 
prietary bodies. 

(3)  The  grades  of  land-right  resulting  from  the  super- 

position, by  conquest  or  otherwise,  of  new  layers 
of  interest  in  the  soil. 


IO4  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  IV. 

(4)  The  growth  and  present  position  of  what  has  be- 

come '  cultivating  tenancies '  under  the  newly 
recognized  landlords. 

(5)  To  these  I  shall  add  a  section  containing  some 

general  ideas  regarding  '  property '  in  land  as  it 
is  understood  in  India.  This  is  a  sort  of  epi- 
sode or  collateral  subject,  the  consideration  of 
which  is  rendered  necessary  by  every  remark 
we  make  on  land-tenures. 


SECTION  II. — THE  VILLAGE. 

§  i.   Existing  accounts  of  the  Village. 

Considering  the  very  great  interest  which  attaches  to  the 
VILLAGF,  as  it  is  found  under  its  varied  conditions  and 
with  its  different  origins,  in  different  parts  of  India,  it  is 
surprising  to  find  that  it  is  practically  impossible  to  put 
one's  hand  on  a  single  book  that  has  collected  and  reduced 
to  shape  the  information  which  exists  in  Settlement  Reports 
and  local  and  special  papers  and  minutes,  official  and 
other *. 

The  only  detailed  attempt  to  account  for  the  village 
constitution  I  have  met,  is  in  Mr.  Phillips'  Tagore  Lectures 
for  1874-5.  The  author  has  set  about,  with  his  usual  skill 
and  industry,  to  collect  facts  from  different  sources;  but 
unfortunately  he  has  been  dominated  with  the  idea  that 
villages  are  always  '  Hindu,'  and  that  there  is  one  kind  of 

1  In  Dr.  Field's  valuable  work  a  valuable  paper  by  Sir  G.  Camp- 
on  Landholding  in  various  countries,  bell,  but  it  is  too  brief  and  general- 
very  little  is  said  about  the  villages  ;  ized  to  be  altogether  satisfactory. 
— the  perfect  communities  of  the  There  are,  of  course,  the  valuable 
Panjab  are  hardly  alluded  to,  and  conclusions  as  to  early  forms  of 
those  of  the  North- West  Provinces  property,  which  Sir  H.  Maine  has 
described  only  in  extracts  from  made  us  familiar  with  in  his  Village 
some  official  Minutes,  which,  what-  Communities  and  other  works  ;  but 
ever  may  have  been  the  ability  of  these  do  not,  and  do  not  profess  to, 
their  authors,  still  were  written  specially  analyze  the  Indian  village 
when  the  settlement  enquiries  under  or  give  any  details  as  to  the  actual 
the  new  system  of  1822  had  hardly  facts  of  origin,  constitution,  and 
commenced,  and  when  knowledge  history,  of  the  different  types  of 
on  the  subject  was  most  elementary.  village  in  the  various  countries  of 

The  Cobden  Club  Essays  contain  India. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENUEE.  1 05 

village  only ;  the  consequence  is  that  he  tries  to  explain 
everything  by  the  ideas  of  the  much  later  Hindu  law- 
books  ;  he  pieces  together  various  items  of  information 
gathered  from  totally  different  provinces ;  and  thereout 
evolves  a  picture  of  a  single  form  of  village  constitution, 
which  thus  represents  nothing  that  really  exists,  or  ever 
did  exist,  as  far  as  evidence  goes.  '  The  village  referred  to 
in  Manu1'  (he  writes)  '  was,  we  can  hardly  doubt,  the  well- 
known  village  community,  the  constitution  and  position  of 
which  are  so  important  in  the  Hindu  land  system ;  the 
village  is,  in  fact,  the  key  to  that  system.'  '  From  the 
slight  reference  to  it  in  Manu,'  he  continues,  '  we  have  to 
pass  by  a  long  stride  of  centuries,  to  what  has  been  observed 
in  such  recent  times  as  the  period  since  British  rule.  It  is 
from  such  observations,  with  the  aid  of  analogies  from 
similar  institutions  existing  in  modern  times  in  other 
countries,  that  we  have  to  construct  the  idea  of  the  village 
community  of  Hindu  times.' 

§  2.  Remarks  on  the  Quotation. — Origin  of  Villages. 

But  in  order  to  get  a  notion  how  the  village  system 
arose  and  grew  in  early  times,  and  how  it  has  since  been 
modified,  it  is  necessary  to  throw  away  all  theories  and 
to  observe  and  collate  the  facts  as  far  as  they  can  be 
established  by  evidence,  carefully  distinguishing  different 
localities,  and  only  generalizing  when  we  have  a  safe  basis. 

The  first  point  to  be  noted  is  that  there  is  no  such 
thing-  as  one  form  of  the  'well- known  village  community' ; 
and  that  the  village-system  should  not  be  referred  to 
Hindu  law  influences  without  a  great  deal  of  considera- 
tion— at  any  rate,  if  by  '  Hindu  law '  we  mean  the  later 
embodiment  of  modified  custom  in  the  now  well-known 
commentaries  and  text-books. 

In  the  first  place,  as  I  have  already  remarked,  there  can 

1  Manava-dharma-sastra,   or   the  version,  that  by  Biihler,  forming  vol. 

Institutes  of  Manu,  with  the  gloss  xxv.    of  Triibner's  series  of  Sacred 

of  Kulluka  Bhatta.     I  always  refer  Books  of  the  East.    See  Phillips,  Lect. 

to  the  best  and  most  recent  English  I,  p.  6. 


IO6  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

hardly  be  any  doubt  that  the  formation  of  village  groups — 
that  is  the  aggregation  of  land-holdings  in  one  place,  and 
with  a  certain  degree  of  union  among  the  cultivators — is  not 
peculiar  to  Hindu  races,  either  original  or  converted.  It 
is  found  in  India,  among  the  great  races  which  were  cer- 
tainly antecedent  to  the  Hindus,  and  which  still  survive 
(with  their  institutions)  in  widely  distant  parts  of  the 
country.  The  village — apart  from  questions  of  particular 
forms — is  not  so  much  the  result  of  any  system  as  it  is  of 
a  natural  instinct.  We  find  it  everywhere,  especially  in 
the  plain  country,  where  circumstances  invited  it ;  at  the 
same  time,  we  do  not  find  it  in  other  places — on  the  Hima- 
layan hill-sides,  on  the  west  coast  (Kanara  and  Malabar) 
and  in  the  dry  regions  of  the  Southern  Panjab.  In  these 
latter  situations  we  find  individuals,  or  a  few  con- 
nected families  with  individual  holdings ;  the  residences 
are  separately  located  within  the  holdings,  or  perhaps  (as 
on  the  west  coast)  a  few  family  houses  are  arranged 
in  a  group  ;  and  we  find  that  on  the  west  coast  there  is 
no  word  for  '  village,'  but  the  term  for  a  family  group  of 
houses  with  its  dependencies  is  some  word  such  as  'tara/ 
meaning  a  '  street.'  It  is  true  that  for  Government  pur- 
poses these  holdings  are  artificially  grouped  into  circles 
of  some  kind,  and  that  some  sort  of  headman,  or  chief  over 
the  circle,  is  recognized,  partly  as  a  matter  of  social  con- 
venience, partly  as  a  matter  of  State  management  with  a 
view  to  the  collection  of  revenue  or  taxes. 

But  over  the  greater  part  of  India  aggregates  of  cultiva- 
tors forming  regular  villages  are  the  rule,  the  other  cases 
are  the  exception. 


§  3.    Two  types  of  Village  distinguished. 

And  then,  there  is  not  one  type  of  village  community, 
but  two  very  distinct  types,  one  of  which,  again,  has 
marked  and  curious  forms  or  varieties.  And,  without  an- 
ticipating details,  which  must  come  later,  I  may  say  at  once 
that  these  two  types  are  distinct  in  origin. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  107 

In  the  one  type  the  aggregates  of  cultivators  have  no 
claim  as  a  joint-body  to  the  whole  estate,  dividing  it 
among  themselves  on  their  own  principles  ;  nor  will  they 
acknowledge  themselves  in  any  degree  jointly  liable  for 
burdens  imposed  by  the  State.  Each  man  owns  his  own 
holding,  which  he  has  inherited,  or  bought,  or  cleared  from 
the  original  jungle.  The  waste  surrounding  the  village  is 
used  for  grazing  and  wood-cutting,  but  no  one  in  the 
village  claims  it  as  his,  to  appropriate  and  cultivate  without 
leave ;  still  less  do  the  whole  group  claim  it  jointly,  to 
partition  when  they  please. 

In  the  other  type — owing  to  causes  which  we  shall 
presently  investigate — a  strong  joint-body,  probably  de- 
scended (in  many  cases)  from  a  single  head,  or  single 
family,  has  pretensions  to  be  of  higher  caste  and  supe- 
rior title  to  the  '  tenants '  who  live  on  the  estate.  The 
site  on  which  the  village  habitations,  the  tank,  the  grave- 
yard, and  the  cat  tie -stand  are,  is  claimed  by  them ;  and 
the  others  live  in  and  use  it  only  by  permission  —  per- 
haps on  payment  of  small  dues  to  the  proprietary  body. 
The  same  body  claim  jointly  (whether  or  not  they  have 
separate  enjoyment  of  portions)  the  entire  area  of  the 
village l,  both  the  cultivated  land  and  the  waste.  If  this 
waste  is  kept  as  such,  they  alone  will  receive  and  distribute 
any  profits  from  grazing,  sale  of  grass  or  jungle  fruits  or 
fisheries  ;  if  it  is  rented  to  tenants,  they  will  divide  the 
rents  ;  if  it  is  partitioned  and  broken  up  for  tillage,  each 
sharer  will  get  his  due  portion.  There  are  other  differences, 
but  these  suffice  for  our  immediate  purpose. 

As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  first  type  of  village  is  the 
one  most  closely  connected  with  Hindu  government  and 
Hindu  ideas.  And  the  second  type  is  found  strongly 
developed  among  the  Panjab  frontier  tribes  who  were  con- 
verted to  Muhammadanism :  it  is  also  universal  among 
Jat,  Gujar.  and  other  tribes  in  the  Central  Panjab,  as  well 

1  There  may  be  two  or  more  such       take  the  case  of  a  simple  village  as 
bodies,    each    claiming    a    certain       better  expressing  my  point, 
known  section  of  a  village  ;   but  I 


IO8  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

as  among   conquering  Aryan   tribes   and   descendants    of 
chiefs  and  nobles  in  other  parts. 

So  much  then  for  there  being  one  general  type  of  village 
to  be  described,  and  for  that  type  being  due  to  Hindu 
influences.  In  making  the  latter  remark,  I  wish,  however, 
to  qualify  it  by  adding  that  it  is  perfectly  true  that  the 
second  type  of  village  does  arise  largely  from  those  deep- 
seated  archaic  notions  of  family  property  and  of  the  joint 
and  equal  inheritance  of  the  members  which  have  formed 
the  basis  of  the  later  Hindu  law,  as  much  as  they  do  that 
of  the  custom  which  governs  the  Panjab  tribes. 

§  4.   Sources  of  information  regarding  Villages. 

Let  us  now  proceed  to  examine  our  sources  of  information 
as  to  the  two  types  of  village  I  have  indicated,  and  see 
how  such  villages  grew  up  and  how  they  have  been  modified. 

§  5.    Causes  of  Village  grouping. 

It  has  been  said  that  the  idea  of  aggregating  men  in 
village  groups  for  the  purposes  of  agriculture  is  a  matter  of 
natural  instinct ;  so  it  is  to  a  great  extent1.  Not  only  is  it 
true  that '  union  is  strength,'  but  the  situation  of  villages 
in  most  parts  of  India  was  such  as  specially  to  call  for 
some  kind  of  union.  In  the  first  place,  the  early  villages 
would  be  situated  in  the  midst  of  often  dense  jungle  ;  and 
the  depredations  of  deer  and  pig  on  the  crops,  and  of  the 
danger  to  human  life  from  the  larger  beasts  of  the  forest, 
are  such  as  an  English  farmer  could  hardly  realize.  Then, 
too,  there  were  adventurous  armies  on  the  move,  hill- 
tribesmen  and  local  robbers  to  be  dreaded,  to  say  nothing 
of  the  need  of  presenting  an  united  front  against  forces 
employed  by  iniquitous  revenue-farmers  in  the  later  days 
of  misrule. 


1  And   we   shall    hereafter    find  recent  associations  of  enterprising 

evidence    from    several    provinces  settlers — perfectly    voluntary    and 

that  many  villages  owe  their  exist-  quite  unconnected  with  any  tribal 

ence  to  more    or  less   ancient  or  notions  or  dynastic  changes. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  IOQ 

Nor  were  neighbouring  villages  always  friendly  to  one 
another.  It  would  often  happen  that  a  group  of  settle- 
ments on  one  side  of  a  boundary  would  be  at  feud  with 
those  on  the  other,  and  union  for  defence  became  a  normal 
condition  on  either  side. 

It  is  not  wonderful,  therefore,  that  '  village  grouping ' 
should  have  been  adopted,  where  local  circumstances  suited 
it,  by  all  races  in  India. 

And  then  there  was  another  influence  which  tended  to 
fix  the  institution,  as  well  as  to  determine  the  size  and 
composition  of  the  groups.  Some  land-owning  castes  in 
parts  of  India  still  retain  a  distinct  tribal  organization. 
What  happened  in  this  respect  with  the  earlier  races  we  only 
know  partially.  But  we  'have  the  example  of  tribes  who 
settled  in  parts  of  the  Panjab  at  a  comparatively  late  date 
— long  after  the  Aryans — and  we  find  them  not  only 
forming  villages,  the  holders  of  which  have  a  strong  joint- 
claim  to  the  whole,  but  forming  them  on  the  plainly  evident 
basis  of  tribal  divisions  and  sub-divisions.  First,  we  find 
an  allotment  of  certain  larger  areas  to  whole  tribes  or 
clans,  and  then  sub- divisions  forming  villages,  the  elders 
carrying  out  the  scheme  down  to  making  a  specific  allot- 
ment for  their  several  family  holdings.  Some  villages  are 
then  clearly  due  to  tribal  instincts.  And  even  among  the 
Aryan  tribes  who  had  Rajas  and  chiefs  over  them,  and  among 
whom  we  cannot  trace  a  detailed  tribal  allotment,  we  shall 
occasionally  find  certain  clans  or  branches  among  whom  no 
family  was  sufficiently  predominant  to  furnish  a  Raja ;  and 
among  these  we  shall  find  villages  divided  up  and  allotted 
from  the  first  on  a  tribal  and  family  basis. 

In  fact,  we  can  follow  out  three  conditions  of  the  existence 
of  villages.  The  first  is  where,  as  withDravidian  and  Aryan 
tribes,  there  is  a  central  government  and  a  series  of  terri- 
torial officers,  but  where  the  villages  are  aggregates  of 
cultivators,  and  no  principle  of  allotting  the  original 
village  areas — if  there  ever  was  any — is  now  traceable,  and 
where  the  village  grouping  appears  to  depend  partly  on 
the  natural  necessities  of  the  population,  partly  on  the 


IIO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.      [CHAP.  IV, 

State  jurisdiction  of  headmen.  The  second  is  where  we 
can  trace  the  village  back  to  the  settlement  of  a  clan  or 
tribe,  and  have  evidence  of  the  formation  of  village  groups 
and  the  allotment  of  lands  on  tribal  principles  from  the 
first.  The  third  is  where  a  landlord-body,  having  acquired 
predominance  in  an  existing  village,  or  having  founded  a 
new  one  themselves,  and  being  now  represented  by  a  more 
numerous  body  of  descendants,  the  existing  grouping  and 
distribution  of  holdings  is  the  result  of  joint-inheritance 
and  partition. 

§  6.    Villages  how  far  'joint.' — The  stages  of  property. 

It  may  not  unnaturally  be  asked  why  are  the  two  dis- 
tinct types  of  village  spoken  of  not  always  recognized  and 
kept  apart  by  Revenue  writers  1  I  think  it  is  due  to  the 
fact  that  they  have  been  too  often  regarded  as  if  one  was 
only  some  kind  of  modification  of  the  other.  Even  if  it 
were  so,  it  would  not  justify  us  in  overlooking  the  distinc- 
tion that  certainly  now  exists ;  but  the  existence  of  such 
an  opinion  gives  me  an  opportunity  of  introducing  some 
remarks  that  ought  to  be  made  at  an  early  stage,  regarding 
ideas  of  'joint  property'  and  'communities/  as  these  terms 
are  applied  to  villages. 

It  is  commonly  said  that  property  in  land  passes  through 
three  stages.  First,  it  is  held  by  the  tribe  or  clan,  and  is 
regarded  as  the  common  property  of  the  whole  body. 
Holdings  indeed  are  allotted  or  recognized,  because  without 
that  agricultural  labour  could  not  be  performed ;  but  pe- 
riodically the  holdings  are  exchanged  or  redistributed, 
showing  (it  is  said)  that  no  one  regards  any  particular 
field  as  his  private  property.  The  next  stage  is  reached 
when  redistribution  is  abandoned,  because  each  several 
holding — that  of  the  man  with  his  sons,  has  become  improved, 
and  each  family  desires  to  retain  permanently  its  own.  But 
still  the  paterfamilias  is  not  the  individual  owner :  he  cannot 
sell  or  will  away  the  holding.  He  must  share  it  equally 
with  his  sons  if  he  makes  a  partition,  and  on  his  death  it 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  I  I  I 

will  go  to  all  sons  equally,  or  to  all  other  heirs  if  there 
are  no  surviving  sons. 

That  is  said  to  be  the  stage  when  property  vests  in  the 
family.  This  stage  evidently  subsists  to  a  great  extent  in 
most  parts  of  India.  The  Hindu  law  and  local  custom  (as  I 
have  mentioned)  recognize  a  joint  succession,  and  provide 
some  other  rules  which  I  need  not  here  allude  to,  for  keep- 
ing the  property  in  one  family. 

But  gradually  the  desire  to  profit  by  one's  own  skill  and 
labour  individualizes  property.  A  number  of  things  con- 
duce to  this  end.  Family  quarrels  are  an  unfortunate  but 
very  common  factor.  Differences  of  taste  and  agricultural 
capability  also  have  their  sphere.  Coined  money  comes  into 
use,  and  men  begin  to  buy  and  sell  land.  Finally,  families 
break  up,  and  individual  ownership,  such  as  we  see  it  in 
Europe,  with  or  without  the  last  restraints  and  survivals  of 
the  preceding  stage,  is  the  third  or  final  condition. 

These  stages  must  certainly  be  borne  in  mind  in  any 
attempt  to  account  for  Indian  villages.  At  the  same  time 
it  must  be  clearly  stated  that  we  have  no  actual  evidence 
of  the  first  stage — evidence,  I  mean,  showing  that  univer- 
sally at  one  time,  there  was  no  such  thing  as  individual 
or  even  a  family  right,  but  that  the  whole  tribe  or  clan 
regarded  the  land  as  really  '  common '  in  a  communistic 
or  socialist  sense. 

It  is  true  that  we  have  ample  evidence  of  a  primal 
custom  of  re-distributing  the  holdings  in  particular  tribes  ; 
but  it  always  followed  a  distinct  allotment  of  lands,  and  an 
allotment  which  showed  that  there  was  a  desire  to  equalize 
the  holdings,  and  not  give  all  the  best  to  some  and  the 
inferior  to  others.  It  is,  therefore,  open  to  us  to  inter- 
pret the  distribution,  not  so  much  as  indicating  a  com- 
munistic idea  of  property  as  indicating  a  desire  to  equalize. 
For  after  all  devices  (and  very  inconvenient  devices  we 
shall  find  them  to  have  been)  adopted  by  the  tribesmen  for 
classifying  lands,  and  giving  families  a  bit  of  this  and  a  bit 
of  that,  instead  of  one  compact  lot  in  one  place,  still 
inequality  was  not  completely  remedied,  and  therefore  a 


112  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

periodic  interchange  may  have  been  intended  rather  to  give 
each  his  turn  at  the  best  and  inferior  holdings x. 

If  we  look  to  the  earliest  villages  found  under  the  Aryans, 
or  before  that,  we  have  no  evidence  (other  than  that  of  the 
re-distribution,  which  I  do  not  regard  as  conclusive)  of 
a  tribal  stage;  and  even  among  the  later  Panjab  tribes, 
where  tribal  occupation  and  allotment  are  clearly  discern- 
ible, any  previous  stage  of  the  joint  holding  by  the  tribe 
collectively,  hardly  seems  deducible  from  the  known  facts. 

But  we  certainly  must  recognize  that,  as  regards  most 
villages,  property  is  still  in  the  'family'  stage.  The  principle 
of  joint  succession  when  the  head  of  the  family  deceases,  is 
clearly  an  indication  of  '  family '  property,  and  so  are  the 
devices  of  excluding  females  (who  marry,  and  so  would  take 
the  land  into  another  family),  the  restrictions  on  alienation 
by  sonless  male  proprietors,  and  the  right  of  pre-emption 
by  which  strangers  can  be  kept  out. 

And  it  may  be  argued  that  this  idea  of  the  family  own- 
ing is  necessarily  the  sequel  of  an  earlier  idea  of  a  common 
holding  by  the  tribe  or  clan.  Those  who  think  so  point  to 
certain  large  areas  in  the  Panjab,  now  forming  separate 
villages,  which  were  once  believed  to  have  formed  units  of 
tribal  holdings  divided  into  shares  2.  I  do  not  then  wish  to 
deny  the  possibility  of  some  early  stage  of  joint  tribal  hold- 
ing, but  to  point  out  that  it  is  a  theory,  and  not  a  matter 
that  can  be  asserted  with  any  approach  to  certainty. 


1  We  have  no  evidence  of  any  such  qu'on  puisse  proceder  a  un  nouveau 

stage  as  mentioned  by  M.  de  Lave-  partage,'   &c.     Still    less   have   we 

leye,  pp.  4,  5,  17) :  '  Peu  a  peu  une  any  trace  of  Virgil's  'Golden  Age' 

partie  de  la  terre  est  momentane-  (Georg.  i.  125  > : 

ment  mise  en  culture,  et  la  regime  'AnteJovemnullisubigebantarva 

agricole  s'etablit :  mais  la  territoire  coloni  ; 

que  le  clan  ou  la  tribu  occupe  de-  Nee  signare  quidein  aut  partiri 

meure   sa   propriete   indivise.      La  limite  campum 

terre  arable,  le  paturage  et  le  foret  Fas  erat:  in  medio  quaerebant ; 

sont  exploites   en   commun.     Plus  ipsaque  tellus 

tard,   la  terre   cultivee  est  divisee  Omnia   liberius,  nullo   poscente, 

en  lots,  repartis  entre  les  families  ferebat.' 

par  voie  du  sort :  1'usage  temporaire  2  See  some  curious  instances  given 

est  seul  attribue  ainsi  a  1'individu.  in  Tupper's  Customary  Laic  (Panjab 

Le  fonds  continue  a  rester  la  pro-  Government,  5  vols.)  regarding  the 

priete  collective  du  clan  a  qu'il  fait  Jihlam  district, 
retour   de   temps  ^en   temps,   afin 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  113 

§  7.    Meaning  of  the  term  '  Community.' 

And  this  leads  me  to  remark  that  though  we  talk  about 
'  village  communities,'  we  ought  not  to  give  that  term  any 
meaning  of  such  a  kind  as  to  indicate  anything  like  a 
communistic  or  socialistic  right  or  interest.  As  regards 
a  large  proportion  of  villages  there  is  no  evidence  what- 
ever of  their  being  held  actually  in  common  in  that  sense. 
Villages  held  for  a  time  in  common  are  always  so  held  by 
the  joint  descendants  of  a  conqueror  or  chief  who  in  some 
way  acquired  the  estate.  The  descendants  are  jealously 
disposed  to  insist  on  equal  privileges  and  position,  and  so 
remain  joint  as  long  as  circumstances  render  it  possible. 
I  have  come  across  a  few  instances  where  a  tribe  (in  the 
Panjab)  has  from  the  first  held  a  part  of  the  land  in  com- 
mon, but  there  it  is  due  to  local  circumstances,  and  the 
produce  is  always  divided  out  according  to  certain  shares. 
The  term  '  community '  might,  if  not  explained,  be  apt 
to  mislead.  It  can  be  correctly  used  only  with  reference  to 
the  fact  that  in  many  villages  families  live  together  under 
a  system  which  makes  them  joint  owners  ;  while  in  others 
the  people  merely  live  under  similar  conditions  and  under 
a  sense  of  tribal  or  caste  connection,  and  with  a  common 
system  of  local  government.  It  cannot  be  used  as  suggest- 
ing any  idea  of  having  the  land  or  anything  else  'in 
common.' 

§  8.   Kinds  of  right  actually  found  to  be  asserted. 

But  whatever  the  truth  may  be  in  this  matter,  we  are 
introduced  at  a  very  early  stage  to  the  existence  of  an  idea 
of  an  individual  (or  rather  family)  right  to  the  land  in 
favour  of  the  person  who  cleared  and  reclaimed  it  from  the 
jungle.  In  such  a  situation  as  the  forest-clad,  or  again  the 
very  dry,  portions  of  India,  it  is  hardly  surprising  that  this 
feeling  should  have  arisen  at  a  very  early  stage  and  rapidly 
gained  ground.  There  are  of  course  places  where  the  soil 
is  soft  and  the  labour  of  preparing  it  for  its  first  ploughing 

VOL.  I.  I 


114  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.      [CHAP.  I v. 

is  comparatively  light.  But  in  large  areas  the  most  severe 
and  protracted  labour  has  to  be  undergone  in  getting  the 
dense  forest  and  jungle  cleared,  and  in  digging  out  masses  of 
stumps  and  roots,  with  no  aid  beyond  manual  labour,  and 
very  rude  if  not  inefficient  tools.  And  this  labour  has  to  be 
unremittingly  continued  or  the  jungle  again  encroaches. 
In  other  parts,  agriculture  is  impossible  without  embanking 
and  terracing  fields  on  the  hill  side,  and  making  water 
courses  to  divert  the  streams  of  hill  torrents.  In  all 
these  cases  the  man  (or  family)  whose  hands  and  funds  have 
effected  the  change,  is  sure,  at  an  early  stage,  to  regard 
himself,  and  be  regarded  by  others,  as  peculiarly  entitled. 
In  the  concluding  section  on  property  we  shall  find  that  at 
least  500  years  B.C.  the  Institutes  of  Manu  had  acknow- 
ledged this  principle,  and  it  is  highly  improbable  that  it 
was  then  a  new  idea  inscribed  in  the  text  for  the  first  time. 

I  have  said  that  right  resides  in  the  family, — though 
the  sentiment  is  slowly  disappearing.  The  principle  just 
spoken  of  does  not  militate  against  this.  For  it  is  the  man 
and  his  relations  together,  who  '  cleared '  the  fields  ;  and  to 
this  day  in  the  most  purely  raiyativdri  villages, — where 
nothing  but  the  most  ancient  several  holding  is  traceable, 
the  sons  or  other  heirs  succeed  jointly  to  the  holding.  And 
as  for  the  cases  where  (as  in  the  Panjab)  we  see  the  tribes 
allotting  land  to  families  who  hold  separately,  but  in  village 
groups ;  or  where  (as  in  villages  acquired  in  landlord  right 
by  families)  there  is  at  first  a  joint  holding  by  all  the  mem- 
bers collectively,  we  are  obviously  in  the  '  family  '  stage. 

Eut  while  we  see  especially  the  influence  of  the  '  right  of 
the  first  clearer '  in  one  type  of  village  where  the  individual 
or  family  holdings  are  all  separate,  and  never  were  (as  far 
as  we  know)  anything  else ;  we  also  see  an  idea  of  right  by 
conquest  which  is  not  so  called,  but  is  distinguished  as 
the  l  birthright '  or  claim  by  inheritance.  It  prevails  in 
villages  of  the  second  type  where,  between  the  ruling 
power  and  the  cultivating  families,  there  is  a  landlord,  or 
a  family  claiming  superior  rights  as  owners.  How  these 
landlords  came  to  have  such  rights  we  shall  presently  see. 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  115 

Here  the  object  of  these  remarks  is  to  disabuse  the  reader's 
mind  of  the  idea  that  in  some  way  a  'joint '  village  is 
necessarily  the  earliest  or  original  type,  and  that  it  is  a 
process  of  decay  and  flux  of  time,  whereby  joint  rights  are 
forgotten,  and  the  other  type  (which  I  have  suggested  to  be 
really  the  oldest)  arises.  That  cases  of  decay,  by  which  one 
form  passes  into  the  other,  have  occurred,  I  do  not  doubt ; 
but  it  is  not  the  general  rule.  We  shall  also  see  the  joint 
villages  partitioned,  splitting  up,  and  becoming  individual 
properties,  but  that  again  is  quite  a  different  and  easily 
recognizable  condition. 


§  9.    Successive  immigrations  into  India. 

It  is  well  known  that  India  has  been  the  scene  of  a  series 
of  tribal  immigrations — a  phenomenon  which  stretches 
back  into  the  remote  past.  Antiquarians  will  long  con- 
tinue to  explore  such  authorities  as  the  Brdhmanas  for 
evidence  as  to  the  successive  races, — some  coming  from  the 
north,  others  by  sea  from  the  west.  But  in  a  work  of  this 
kind,  I  must  avoid  the  path  of  antiquarian  speculation, 
however  tempting,  and  leave  the  real  detail  to  others. 
For  our  present  purpose  we  shall  find  it  sufficient  to  take 
note  of  three  great  races, — those  whose  effect  on  the  land- 
tenures  is  evident.  One  of  the  early  races,  which  still  sur- 
vives, is  the  Kolarian  (or,  as  some  write  it,  Kolharian). 
Tribes  belonging  to  this  race  are  still  to  be  found  in  South- 
western Bengal,  and  in  Central  India  along  the  Vindhyan 
mountains.  Their  origin  I  cannot  discuss,  but  they  were 
followed  by  Dravidian  tribes,  whose  rule  they  often 
accepted.  The  Kol  races  are  still  represented  by  the  Ho 
and  Munda  tribes  in  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  division  of 
Bengal,  by  some  primitive  tribes  called  Korwa  in  the  same 
country,  and  by  the  Hors  of  Singhbhum.  The  Bhumij  and 
the  Santal  people,  who  settled  in  what  are  known  as  the 
'  Santal  Parganas '  of  Bengal,  belong  to  the  same  race. 
Along  the  Vindhyan  hills  these  races  are  traced  in  the 
Kols  of  Gujarat,  the  Bhils  of  Malwa.  the  Kuars  of  Ellichpur 

I  2 


1 1 6  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

(in  Berar),  and  the  Kurku  tribe  of  Hushangabad  in  the 
Northern-Central  Provinces.  To  the  present  day  they 
represent  various  stages  of  tribal  progress. 

The  Kolarian  races  hardly  interest  us  from  the  tenure- 
point  of  view  so  much  as  the  Dravidians — except  in  this 
respect  that,  while  some  of  these  tribes  mixed  with  the 
Dravidians  and  submitted  to  their  government,  others 
remained  distinct,  and  still  remain,  to  show  us  all  grada- 
tions of  tribal  progress.  Some  are  still  nomadic,  living 
only  in  the  forest  by  hunting  and  collecting  forest  produce, 
and  if  they  practise  cultivation,  it  is  by  that  method  of 
shifting  or  temporary  cultivation  which  is  common  in 
many  parts  of  India. 

§  10.   Shifting  Cultivation  in  the  Hill  Forests. 

As  this  shifting  cultivation  marks  the  first  stage  in  pro- 
gress from  the  pastoral  and  hunting  stage,  I  may  briefly 
describe  the  method  adopted.  The  tribes  who  practise  it, 
commence  by  selecting  a  suitable  site  on  not  too  steep  a 
slope,  and  cutting  down  all  the  smaller  tree  and  shrub 
vegetation,  which  is  heaped  on  the  ground  to  dry  during 
the  hot  season.  The  larger  trees  are  killed  by  ringing ;  the 
rest  is  burned.  As  soon  as  the  rains  fall,  the  ashes  mixed 
with  seed — usually  hill-rice,  pulses,  and  (in  places)  cotton — 
are  dibbled  into  the  ground.  One  crop  is  taken,  perhaps 
followed  by  a  second,  on  the  same  place,  and  then  the  tribe 
moves  to  a  new  locality.  They  return  to  the  first  only 
after  a  period  sufficient  for  the  vegetation  to  grow  up 
again.  If  space  is  ample  and  the  tribes  not  numerous, 
it  may  be  twenty,  thirty,  or  forty  years  before  the  same  place 
is  cut  again.  But  where  the  population  is  denser,  and 
space  limited,  the  rotation  is  reduced  to  ten  or  even  seven 
years,  and  less. 

In  Burma  we  shall  see  an  instance  of  this  form  of  culti- 
vation becoming  organized,  and  evidently  on  the  way  to 
change  into  settled  land-holding1. 

1  Shifting  cultivation  is  practised  under  the  name  of  'jum'  (and 
largely  in  Assam  and  Eastern  Bengal  many  other  tribal  names).  It  is 


CHAP,  iv.]     GENERAL  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-TENURE.  I  I  J 

§  ii.    The  Kol  Institutions. 

The  Kol  tribes  do  not  appear  to  have  had  any  central 
government.  Their  village  settlements — when  they  were  of 
a  permanent  character — were  united  in  tribal  areas,  as  were 
those  of  the  Dravidians,  and  known  as  '  parha '  in  that  part 
of  India  where  they  still  survive.  A  chief  or  '  manki '  pre- 
sided over  the  parha.  In  each  village,  a  hereditary  head- 
man called  '  munda '  was  acknowledged.  The  final  reference 
was  to  the  mdnki,  or  to  the  mankis  in  council  united  with 
the  mundds  and  chief  land-holders.  This  resembles  the 
Dravidian  form,  so  clearly  traceable  in  South  India,  where 
the  village  or  other  family  groups  were  aggregated  into 
unions  called  'nad'  or  '  nadu,"  with  some  kind  of  chief,  acting 
alone  as  regards  the  nad,  or  in  council  with  the  other  chiefs 
in  affairs  affecting  the  whole  country.  Nothing  under  this 
system  indicates  that  the  village  land-holder  claimed  any 
other  right  than  to  hold  his  own  clearing.  The  munda, 
Mr.  Hewitt  informs  us,  disposed  of  lapsed  or  abandoned 
holdings ;  and  probably  no  theory  as  to  general  right  in 
unoccupied  land  existed,  except  possibly  that  it  belonged 
to  the  ;  parha  ' — representing  the  original  territory  allotted 
to  a  tribal  section.  In  time  each  village  expanded  by  new 
cultivation ;  hamlets,  offshoots  of  existing  villages,  spread- 
ing into  the  waste. 

No  regular  system  of  revenue  can  be  traced,  but  the 
munda  and  the  manki  held  lands  in  their  respective  villages, 
and  gifts  of  grain — the  early  forerunner  of  the  regular  grain 
share — were  received. 

§  12.    The  Dravidian  Races. 

These  tribes  are  said  to  have  come  from  the  west,  and 
undoubtedly  spread  over  a  great  part  of  India.  They 

a  great  feature   in   the   forests   of  taken  place  is  '  punzo ').     In  South 

Burma    where  forest  officers  have  India  it  is  Kumri  or  Kumeri  (Cana- 

carefully  to  deal  with  the  custom,  rese)  or  podu  in  Telugu.     In  the 

and  arrange  grounds  for  its  prac-  Central  Provinces  it  is  '  dahya '  or 

tice.    In  Burma  it  is  called  '  toung-  '  bewar.'     It  was   formerly  known 

ya '   (and  the  tangled  jungle  that  in  the  Simla  hills, 
springs  up  where  a    cutting    has 


Il8  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

established  great  kingdoms  in  South  and  Central  India, 
and  it  is  difficult  to  say  how  far  their  influence  extended. 
It  appears,  for  instance,  that  the  Takshakas,  a  race  which 
occupied  the  northern-central  regions  of  the  Panjab,  and 
were  snake  worshippers,  were  Dravidians.  The  Central 
Provinces  and  Berar  were  peopled  by  Gonds  or  Khonds, 
who  were  Dravidians — and  the  Central  Provinces  '  Zamin- 
dari  estates  '  are  the  surviving  traces  of  the  chiefships  held 
by  Gond  nobles.  These  people  left  more  than  others  a 
strong  mark,  because  they  had  a  central  government — a 
king  whose  territories  were  in  the  centre,  and  chiefs  holding 
the  outer  circle  of  estates — like  the  Aryans.  It  is  fairly 
certain  that  the  Dravidians  were  partly  conquered  and 
partly  peaceably  mingled  with  the  Aryan  races  who  came 
afterwards.  They  had  the  habit  of  educating  their  children  ; 
hence  Brahmans  of  the  literary  Aryan  stock  were  welcomed, 
and  thus  it  was  that  while  the  Sanskrit  language  adopted 
those  peculiar  letters,  which  are  found  in  none  of  the 
Europaeo-Aryan  tongues,  in  time  the  Dravidian  princes 
took  Brahman  counsellors,  adopted  Hinduism,  and  often 
took  Hindu  names  and  called  themselves  Rajputs,  with 
fanciful  genealogies  derived  from  the  heroes  of  the  Mahd- 
bhdrata  l.  Dravidian  tenures  and  institutions  still  survive 
in  Chutiya  Nagpur  side  by  side  with  the  Kolarian.  The 
Uraoas,  who  conquered  and  gave  their  name  to  Orissa,  were 
also  Dravidians. 

Some  interesting  details  will  be  found  in  the  chapters  in 
the  Bengal  section  devoted  to  Orissa  and  Chutiyd  Nagpur  2. 

As  already  stated,  the  Dravidians  had  a  central  govern- 
ment of  a  king  or  Raja — the  original  title  has  perished — 
and  chiefs.  They  occupied  (as  far  as  the  Kol  countries  are 
concerned)  lands  already  cultivated.  What  is  interesting 

1  The  Dravidians  are  also  repre-  2  The  vernacular  terms  given  in 

sented  by  the  Bhars  who  had  im-  the  text  in  connection  with  these 

portant  kingdoms  in  Oudh,  and  re-  institutions  are  those  which   now 

present  the  '  Bharata '  tribes  of  the  obtain  in  the  South-west  of  Bengal, 

Brdhmanas.     It  is    curious    also  to  where    the    institutions    are    still 

note  the  Burman  institutions  which  most    clearly  in    evidence.     Simi- 

show    a    Dravidian    origin.      Dra-  lar  institutions  survive  elsewhere, 

vidian  institutions  have  also  been  and  of  course  the  names  are  dif- 

observed  in  Sumatra.  ferent. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  I  1 9 

about  them,  besides  the  system  of  Rajas  and  chiefs,  which 
is  thus  a  pre- Aryan  organization,  is,  that  at  first  the  chiefs 
raised  their  principal  revenue  by  holding  special  lands  in 
each  village  throughout  the  country ;  the  whole  produce 
being  taken  by  the  ruler.  The  villages  were  divided  into 
lots  called  '  Khunt.'  One  of  these  was  the  '  majhas  '  land 
or  royal  farm  spoken  of ;  another  went  to  the  headman,  and 
another  to  the  '  pahan '  or  priest ;  this  being  subdivided 
into  shares  for  the  worship  of  the  great  goddess,  the  district 
god,  and  the  village  deity  respectively.  After  a  time  the 
kings,  not  feeling  satisfied  with  the  '  majhas '  produce, 
took  a  grain-share  also,  from  all  lands  except  the  priest's, 
and  the  headman's  ;  and  then  it  was  that  some  further 
changes  took  place.  The  king  first  introduced  a  State 
headman  or  accountant  called  '  Mahto,'  who  speedily 
reduced  to  a  shadow  the  position  of  the  old  '  Munda  '  or 
natural  headman.  Of  course  the  '  Mahto  '  got  his  allot- 
ment of  land :  and  the  lands  held  by  the '  bhuinhar  '  families 
— those  of  the  original  settlers  who  furnished  the  headman 
and  other  chief  men  including  the  Mahto,  were  exempt 
from  revenue.  In  this  stage,  the  king  also,  to  provide  for 
the  cultivation  of  the  royal  farm  or  'majhhas'  land,  made 
an  allotment  (betkhe'ta)  to  certain  cultivators,  which  was 
exempt  from  revenue,  on  condition  that  they  should  work 
the  '  majhhas  '  lands.  Then  it  was  that,  excepting  the  lands 
of  the  bhuinhar  officials  and  the  '  betkhe'ta,'  all  other  land 
paid  a  share  to  the  king  or  chief,  and  so  was  called  '  Raj  has  ' 
land. 


§  13.    How  far  the  Aryans  copied  the  Dravidian 
System. 

It  is  certainly  a  remarkable  fact,  that  while  we  know 
the  Aryan  races  to  have  been  originally  a  pastoral  race, 
but  including  a  strong  military  caste,  the  institution  of 
the  Raja  and  his  chiefs  forming  a  sort  of  feudal  govern- 
ment, as  well  as  taking  a  grain-share  by  way  of  revenue, 
were  apparently  in  existence  before  the  Aryans  came. 


I2O  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

This  fact  has  led  Mr.  J.  F.  Hewitt  to  study  the  whole 
question.  This  author  has  had  exceptional  facilities  for 
examining  the  evidence  on  the  spot,  having  long  resided  in 
the  Central  Provinces,  and  also  been  Commissioner  of  the 
Chutiya  JMagpur  division  of  Bengal l. 

Seeing  the  undoubted  influence  that  the  Dravidian  and 
Aryan  races  had  on  one  another,  and  that  something  must 
have  brought  about  the  change  in  the  Aryans  from  a  con- 
quering and  pastoral  people  to  a  settled  ruling  race,  with  an 
orderly  government  and  village  cultivation  and  a  regular 
hierarchy  of  officials  over  the  land ;  it  is  at  least  a  probable 
explanation  to  suggest  that  they  simply  copied  the  Dra- 
vidian institutions  which  they  found  ready  to  hand.  On 
the  other  side,  it  may  be  urged  that  the  plan  of  forming 
villages  is  a  natural  one,  and  that  taking  a  grain-share  is 
also  natural.  We  see  it  among  the  Arabians.  (The  early 
Muhammadan  plan  was  that  of  the  tithe,  or  'ashr,  paid  by 
the  faithful,  and  the  '  khiraj,'  or  tribute  taken  from  the 
conquered,  and  both  probably  in  kind.) 2  But  I  must  leave 
the  question  an  open  one.  At  any  rate,  we  have  a  very 
perfect  coincidence,  amply  justifying  a  prominent  notice 
in  this  place.  We  must  admit  that,  whether  or  no  the 
Aryans  could  have  had  the  'grain-share'  idea  of  revenue  by 
nature,  they  certainly  found  it  practised  when  they  came. 

I  must  also  add  that  the  Dravidian  institution  of  the 
'  Majhhas '  lands  explains  the  prevalence  of  '  Koyal '  lands 
or  farms  in  Burma,  and  in  many  parts  of  India,  where,  for 
instance  in  Coorg,  we  also  find  it,  the  land  being  worked  by 
slaves.  It  seems  to  have  been  at  one  time  adopted  in  Mala- 
bar, and  perhaps  affords  one  (alternative)  explanation 


1  See     on    the    subject    of    the  of  the  one-fifth  produce  taken  by  the 
tribes,0unningham,^4wciew<  Geography  Pharaohs  is  familiar.     Having  ac- 
(Triibner,  1871)  pp.  505  7.  and  Mr.  quired   the   land  in   exchange  for 
Hewitt's  paper  in  the  Journal  of  the  food  during  the  protracted  famine, 
Society  of  Arts  for  May  6,  1887  (vol.  the  ruler  could  not  of  course  dis- 
xxxv.     p.     613)     and     subsequent  pense  with  the  original  cultivators ; 
papers   in  the  Journal  of  the  Royal  so  he  left  them  in  possession,  stipu- 
Asiatic  Society,  April   1890.  lating  for  an  annual   fifth  of  the 

2  And  so  in  the  remote  times  of  produce  (Gen.  xlvii.  20-24). 
the  Old  Testament.     The  instance 


CHAP.  IV.]  GENEEAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENUEE.  121 

of  the  fact  that  the  king  did  not  take  a  general  land- 
revenue.  There  is  also  no  doubt,  to  my  mind,  that  the 
'  watan,'  or  land  held  ex  officio  by  village  headmen — of 
which  we  shall  presently  hear — is  a  distinct  Dravidian 
survival. 

In  short,  when  our  books  speak  of  the  pre-Muhammadan 
government  and  land  organization  as  '  ancient  Hindu,'  it  is 
really  a  fusion  of  Aryan  and  Dravidian  ideas  which  they 
refer  to ;  a  system  the  original  elements  of  which  can  hardly 
be  separated. 

§  14.   The  Aryan  Immigration. 

Notwithstanding  the  question  of  origin  alluded  to,  I 
shall  speak  of  the  Aryan  or  Hindu  system  when 
referring  to  the  revenue-system  which  preceded  the  Mu- 
hammadan  conquest,  chiefly  because  the  Aryan  and  Dravi- 
dian races  merged  into  one  another,  and  also  because  the 
system  is  more  perfectly  preserved  to  us  through  Aryan 
writings,  and  is  most  clearly  exhibited  to  us  in  the  Aryan 
(Rajput)  states,  where  it  has  found  an  enthusiastic  historian 
in  Colonel  Tod,  whose  well-known  Rajasthdn — fortunately 
reprinted— is  a  mine  of  information  on  the  subject. 

So  that  the  Aryan  immigration  is  really,  for  our  special 
purpose,  the  most  important.  To  this  we  will  now  turn. 

At  some  remote  period  one  of  the  great  waves  of  im- 
migration brought  a  race  from  the  North-west,  which  was 
originally  pastoral ;  it  is  believed  that  their  taking  to 
settled  agriculture  was  a  later  development,  and  may 
perhaps  be  traced  to  the  time  when  they  began  to  leave 
the  hill  kingdoms  which  they  first  occupied — where  culti- 
vation was  limited  to  narrow  valleys  or  terraced  fields 
on  the  mountain-side — and  descend  to  the  wider  spaces  of 
the  alluvial  plains  of  Upper  India.  It  is  certain  that 
such  a  change  did  take  place.  There  can  be  no  reasonable 
doubt  that  the  Aryan  tribesmen  at  first  established  them- 
selves, with  their  chiefs,  along  the  Himalayan  slopes — in 
Kashmir,  in  the  hills  now  forming  the  Chamba  State,  and 


1 2  2  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

in  the  hills  near  Simla.  In  the  Kangra  district  (Panjab 
Himalaya)  we  find  a  distinct  tradition  that  the  present 
Rajput  chiefs  and  landholders  were  only  the  successors  of 
a  much  earlier  race  of  Hindu  settlers  and  conquerors,  they 
themselves  having  occupied  land  in  those  hills  at  a  period 
no  earlier  than  the  beginning  of  the  Muhammadan  con- 
quest, when  they  fled  from  oppression.  In  Chamba  and  in 
Kashmir  there  are  stone  temples  marking  colonies  of  great 
antiquity.  In  the  latter  valley  many  ruins — like  those  cele- 
brated ones  of  Martand — are  Buddhist ;  but  in  Chamba  the 
old  conical  stone  temples,  with  their  finials  resembling  a 
grooved  or  fluted  and  flattened  sphere  (called  by  Fergusson 
the  '  Amlika '),  may  go  back  to  a  really  ancient  establish- 
ment of  the  princes  and  people  who  afterwards  conquered 
India,  and  fought  in  the  battles  which  have  been  half 
mythically,  half  historically,  described  in  the  epic  of  the 
Mahabharata.  It  is  common  to  find  in  books,  statements 
to  the  effect  that  after  a  long  sojourn — perhaps  of  centuries 
— in  the  hills,  they  descended  on  to  the  'plains  of  the 
Panjab.'  But  the  Aryans  at  first  did  not  descend  far,  if  at 
all,  into  the  Panjab  plains1  properly  so  called.  The 
Rajput  bodies  now  found  there  are  all,  by  tradition,  later 
settlements ;  princes,  with  their  followers,  or  individual 
adventurers  (whose  descendants  have  since  multiplied  into 
clans)  returned  from  kingdoms  established  further  on  into 

1  We  have  no  old  Hindu  remains  races,  but  that  was  later.     I  do  not 

in  the  Panjab  plains  ;  but  the  Greek  venture  here  to  discuss  what  was 

writers    tell    us    of    a    number    of  the  origin  or  date  of  the  Jat  tribes 

(Aryan)  kingdoms  to  the  north  (near  and  many  others  who  form  so  large 

the    hills),    and    beside    them   we  a    portion    of    the   Panjab   village 

have  traces  of  tribes  of  non- Aryan  population,  but  they  certainly  were 

origin,  viz.  the  Malli,  Cathoei  and  much  later  than  the  Aryan  immi- 

other  tribes  (of  the  Greek  authors)  gration,  and  they  were  not  Aryans  in 

to   the    south   and    east,   and    the  that  sense.    Dr.  Muir  (Sanskrit  Texts, 

Takshakas  or  Takkas  who  had  their  ii.  482,  &c.)  cites  passages  from  the 

capital  at  Takashila  i^Taxiles  of  the  Mahabharata  which   confirm  this. 

Greeks)  not  far  from  Rawalpindi.  The  people 'who  dwell  between  the 

Presumably  Poms    (Purusha)   was  five    rivers    which    are    associated 

an  Aryan  prince,  but  his  conflict  with  the  Sindhu  (Indus' as  a  sixth' 

with  Alexander  was  on  the  Jihlam  are  '  those  impure  Bahikas  who  are 

river,    and    that    is    not  far  from  outcast  from   righteousness.'     '  Let 

the   hills  which   the   Rajputs   cer-  no  Aryan  dwell  there  even  for  two 

tainly  occupied.  In  time,  too,  Aryan  days.     There  dwell  degraded  Brah- 

families  allied  themselves  with  the  mans.  .  .  .  They  have  no  Veda  nor 

Panjab  tribes  and  formed  mixed  Vedic  ceremony  nor  any  sacrifice.' 


CHAP,  iv.]    GENERAL   VIEW    OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.  123 

Hindustan.  But  the  site  of  the  first  Aryan  settlement  in 
the  plains  of  India  was  to  the  north-west  of  Delhi,  in  the 
vicinity  of  the  Jamna  river,  where  they  established  king- 
doms— of  which  Hastinapura  is  a  historic  example — and 
thence  they  spread  over  the  North -West  Provinces  and 
Oudh  (properly  Awadh — the  ancient  Ayodhya).  The  ad- 
vance could  not  stop  here.  Although  the  old  writers 
attempted  to  describe  '  the  country  where  the  antelope  was 
found'  as  the  proper  abode  of  the  Aryans — and  this  phrase 
points  to  the  open  plains  about  the  Jamna  and  Ganges — 
the  tribes  or  clans  gradually  advanced  over  Bengal  and 
Bihdr  *,  and  conquering  portions  of  them,  at  any  rate  ob- 
tained a  kingdom  in  Orissa z ;  others  went  to  Central,  and 
perhaps  to  Southern  India  ;  others  conquered  Guzarat  in 
Northern  Bombay,  where  their  remains  are  found  to  the 
present  day.  The  group  of  states  now  known  as  Rajpu- 
tana  and  Kathiawar,  represent  the  last  refuge  of  these  clans 
at  a  time  when  the  Muhammadan  conquest  began  to  disturb 
them.  It  is  impossible  to  state  in  what  order  these  con- 
quests and  settlements  occurred,  except  that  they  were  after 
the  primal  settlement  in  the  region  of  the  Jamna. 

Pure  Aryan  settlements  were,however,not  the  only  feature 
of  the  immigration ;  it  is  certain  that  many  alliances — both 
political  and  social — early  took  place 3.  Dravidian  and 
Aryan  rapidly  mingled,  both  as  to  race,  language,  and 
forms  of  government ;  and  the  influence  of  their  religious, 
social,  and  political  system  spread  in  other  ways.  Brah- 
mans  travelled  to  the  remotest  parts,  and  soon,  as  I  have 
said,  converted  the  Dravidian  chiefs  to  Hindu  ideas  and 
made  them  '  Rajputs.'  In  reading  accounts  of  the  southern 
kingdoms — the  CheVa,  Chola,  and  Pandyan  dynasties,  in 
the  Madras  territories,  or  the  states  on  the  west  coast,  now 

1  A  distinct  legend  describes  how  2  vols. 

the  ancestor  of  the  Videhas  of  Bihar  3  Mr.  Hewitt  has  endeavoured  to 

set  out  bearing  the  sacred  fire  with  trace    many   of   these    movements 

him  towards  Bihar.  and    alliances    in    his    interesting 

1  As  set  forth  by  Stirling  in  the  papers  on  the  Early  History  of  Northern 

Asiatic  Researches,  an  authority  ren-  India.   Journal    R.   A.    S.,  vol.    xx. 

dered  more  accessible  to  us  in  the  July  1888,  and  vol.  xxi.  April  1889. 
graphic  pages  of  Hunter's  Orissa, 


1 24  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

called  Kanara  and  Malabar — it  is  impossible  to  feel  certain 
whether  we  are  to  read  through  the  records  of  Brahmanical 
authors,  that  the  princes  and  chiefs  were  actually  Rajput 
immigrants,  or  were  (as  is  more  probable)  local  Dravidian 
princes  who  had  adopted  the  Hindu  system.  It  is  quite 
certain  that  the  Gond  kingdoms  of  Central  India,  and  the 
Assam  dynasty  in  the  north-east,  were  '  Hinduized '  in  this 
way,  and  we  shall  see  the  same  thing  in  south-west 
Bengal. 

Then,  again,  in  spite  of  caste  prohibitions  and  a  great 
strictness  in  marriage  rules  observed  by  the  purest  families, 
it  is  quite  certain  that  the  Aryans  mixed  freely  with  other 
tribes,  their  predecessors,  and  that  tribes  of  half-blood 
multiplied  rapidly;  some  of  them,  at  least,  would  be 
Hindu  and  claim  to  be  Rajput.  Among  the  Jats  of  the 
Panjab,  for  example,  while  some  of  the  clans  assert  a 
separate  tribal  immigration  from  beyond  what  is  now 
Afghanistan,  others  declare  they  are  Rajputs  who  lost 
caste  by  adopting  irregular  marriage  customs.  There  are 
castes  in  the  North-west  Himalaya  who  are  known  to  be  of 
this  mixed  origin,  and  very  sturdy  races  they  are.  The 
Bihar  people  are  probably  a  mixture  of  the  antecedent 
'  Magadhas  '  and  Aryans  ;  and  the  important  agricultural 
caste  of  Kurmis,  or  Kunbis,  are  said  to  be  a  mixed  race 
from  the  Kaurava  or  Kuru  clan.  Tribes  of  this  kind,  and 
Rajputs  of  purer  origin  also,  spread  (as  I  have  already 
remarked)  over  the  Panjab  and  other  places,  by  what  I  may 
call  a  reflex  movement — settling  as  individuals  or  groups, 
who  returned  upon  their  steps,  after  the  original  tribes  had 
advanced  to  the  country  of  the  Jamna  and  beyond  it.  The 
once  extensive  settlement  of  'Chib'  Rajputs  in  the  Gujrat 
district  of  the  Panjab,  may  with  tolerable  certainty  be 
ascribed  to  this  origin1. 

1  Many  settlements  now  forming  or  Mew&r,  or  wherever  else  they 
groups  of  Rajput  villages,  in  the  had  settled  in  Hindustan  returned, 
Panjab  were  due  to  single  ad-  founded  villages,  and  gradually 
venturers,  cadets  and  members  of  multiplied  into  clans.  The  Rajput 
families  who,  dissatisfied  with  their  race  is  everywhere  noted  as  ex- 
position and  prospects  in  Bikanir  tremely  prolific. 


CHAP.  IV.]  GENERAL    VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.  125 

§  15.  Importance  of  the  Hindu  system. 

The  land-system  of  the  Aryans — whether  really  Dravi- 
dian  or  not — is  the  one  that  has  come  down  to  us  in  the 
greatest  perfection.  It  survives  to  this  day  in  Rajputana 
and  in  the  Hindu  states  of  the  Himalayan  mountains.  We 
can  see  its  identity,  at  least  in  all  main  features,  with  the 
system  of  the  Aryan  tribes  as  it  was  in  Manu's  time.  We 
have  also  evidence  of  what  it  was  in  the  small  Hindu  states 
that  once  spread  over  Oudh ;  we  trace  it  in  Orissa ;  we 
can  follow  the  same  organization  as  it  was  adopted  by  the 
Marathas  and  by  the  Sikhs.  We  can  gather  similar  inform- 
ation also  about  the  Hindu  states  in  South  India.  Every- 
where we  have  the  same  broad  outlines  of  State  and  social 
organization  in  their  relation  to  land-holding. 

The  Rajas  of  one  place  may  regard  those  of  other  parts 
as  having  lost  caste,  and  they  may  refuse  intermarriage  ; 
they  may  regard  themselves  as  the  representatives  of  the 
pure  stock,  and  other  princes  as  nobodies  ;  but  all  that 
has  nothing  to  do  with  the  fact  that  they  all  adopt, 
and  have  adopted  from  time  immemorial,  a  system  of 
organization  and  land-administration  which  is  the  same 
in  all  essentials. 

What  is  more  strange,  the  Muhammadan  conquest  did 
little  directly  to  modify  the  old  system  of  Hindu  land- 
holding  ;  though  indirectly,  as  we  shall  see,  it  caused  a  new 
race  of  landlords  to  arise,  who  ignored  and  gradually 
caused  the  decay  of,  the  special  features  of  village  or- 
ganization. But  it  is  not  to  the  Muhammadan  conquest, 
speaking  of  the  country  as  a  whole,  that  we  owe  any  irre- 
coverable loss  of  evidence  as  to  what  the  old  forms  of  land- 
holding  were. 

§  1 6.    The  Hindu  Land-system. 

Although  in  the  chapter  (which  follows  this)  on  the  Land- 
Revenue  Systems,  I  have  fully  described  the  method  of 
State  organization  which  marks  the  Hindu  Raj  or  kingdom, 


126  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

and  all  others  which  assimilated  to  it,  I  had  better  give 
a  similar  outline  here,  and  the  repetition  will  be  forgiven. 
No  doubt  the  different  clans  or  sections  of  the  Aryan  tribe 
occupied  denned  territories  which  they  conquered.  There 
is  everywhere  evidence  that  the  tendency  was  to  form  a 
number  of  comparatively  small  States  or  territories,  and 
the  Rajas,  or  head  chiefs,  and  minor  chiefs,  called  Thakur, 
Rana,  Babu,  &c.,  of  each,  divided  the  land  amongst  them- 
selves. Sometimes  particular  clans  had  no  Rajas,  and  they 
then  made  an  equal  division  into  villages  and  family  estates. 
There  was  also  a  marked  tendency  for  a  number  of  these 
States  to  be  united  in  a  sort  of  confederacy  under  some 
greater  emperor.  Such  was  the  case  in  the  days  of  the 
great  kings  of  Kanauj,  and  with  the  empire  of  Chandragupta 
and  Asoka l.  The  Chinese  pilgrim  in  the  seventh  century 
A.D.,  notes  that  he  saw  the  State  barge  of  the  Maharaja,  or 
great  king  of  Kanauj.  being  drawn  along  on  some  ceremo- 
nial occasion,  by  eighteen  minor  Rajas. 

We  are,  however,  only  concerned  with  the  individual 
States.  The  Raja,  as  the  chief  power  of  the  clan,  received 
the  largest  and  best  group  of  lands 2  (usually  in  the  centre 
of  the  country)  as  his  royal  demesne,  and  this  was  in  after 
times  called  his  '  Khalsa,'  the  Persian  term  of  course  indi- 
cating its  later  introduction.  Smaller  estates  were  assigned 
to  the  other  tribal  or  clan  chieftains  (Thakur,  Rana,  &c.), 
and  they  governed  these  estates  without  interference  from 
the  Raja.  They  were  only  bound  to  feudal  service,  to 
appear  at  the  Raja's  court  from  time  to  time,  to  receive 
investiture,  and  to  pay  a  succession  fee  on  the  occasion  of 
a  succession  by  inheritance. 

§  17.    Manu's  idea  of  land-holding. 

Unfortunately  we  have  no  information  as  to  how  indivi- 
dual families  and  members  of  the  clans  received  holdings  of 

1  Just  as  there  was  an  overlord ,  p.  220)  says :  '  The  domains  reserved 

a  Rex  gentis  Anglorum,  in  the  days  of  for  the  crown  constituted,  if  not  the 

the  heptarchy  in  England.  largest,  at  least  the  most  valuable 

1  Stirling,  in  his  remarks  on  and  productive  share  of  the  whole 

Orissa,  (Asiatic  Researches,  vol.  xv.  territory.' 


CHAP,  iv.]   GENERAL  VIEW   OP   THE    LAND-TENURE.  127 

land.  By  the  time  which  Harm's  Institutes  represent,  the 
tribes  had  settled  down,  and  agriculture  was  well  esta- 
blished. Manu  has  nothing  to  tell  us  of  how  individual 
(family)  holdings  were  apportioned.  In  the  times  repre- 
sented by  his  Code,  there  were  already  separate  villages,  a 
headman  over  each  village,  and  other  officials  over  groups  of 
villages,  and  over  larger  areas  (des),  which  probably  still 
survive  under  the  more  familiar  revenue  name  of  '  pargana,' 
a  term  introduced  at  a  later  period  by  the  Mughals.  who 
simply  followed  the  old  Hindu  organization  of  territory 
under  new  names. 

It  is  not  easy  to  explain  why  Manu  tells  us  nothing  of 
the  original  possession  of  cultivating  holdings.  He  is, 
however,  chiefly  concerned  with  the  Raja  of  high  or  mili- 
tary caste  and  his  learned  Brahman  counsellors,  and  how 
these  allotted  the  country  for  rule  and  overlordship.  It  is 
probable  that  the  cultivators,  who  were  called  Vaisyas  and 
Sudras  by  caste,  were  some  of  them,  dependents  or  followers 
of  particular  chiefs,  who  settled  on  the  territories  of  their 
respective  heads ;  but  they  must  also  have  represented 
the  mixed  race  formed  by  the  union  of  Hindus  and  Dravi- 
dians.  They  cultivated  each  man  (or  family)  according  to  his 
ability.  The  higher  military  caste,  when  not  of  rank  to 
hold  estates  as  chiefs,  or  become  headmen  and  district  officers, 
either  lived  apart  as  soldiers,  or  fell  into  the  humbler  posi- 
tion of  cultivators.  In  a  great  many  instances  the  land 
occupied  must  have  been  waste  and  covered  with  jungle, 
and  its  reclamation  may  have  been  without  any  formal 
division  other  than  the  allotment  (of  ultimate  holdings) 
under  the  direction  of  headmen,  such  as  we  see  in  so  many 
parts  in  later  times 1.  However  this  may  be,  all  that  Manu 
notices  is  the  right  possessed  by  the  'first  clearer'  of  the  jungle. 
He  has  the  right,  just  as  the  hunter  who  first  wounded  the 
deer  in  the  chase. 

In  the   concluding   section  on  property  we   shall  give 

1  I  refer  to  the  process  of  village       devoted   to    the    tenures    of    those 
founding  in  the  Central  Provinces,       provinces, 
described  more  fully  in  the  chapter 


128  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

some  further  details  about  Manu,  and  the  state  of  things  in 
his  time.  Here  I  am  only  concerned  to  note  that  it  is 
doubtful  if  there  is  any  suggestion  of  a  landlord  between 
the  cultivators  and  the  Raja,  and  certainly  nothing  like  a 
tribal  or  a  joint  ownership  on  the  part  of  the  body  of  culti- 
vators or  holders  of  land  in  the  '  Gramam '  or  village 1. 
Indeed,  if  there  had  originally  been  a  joint  ownership, 
I  do  not  see  how  any  such  ownership  could  have  grown  up 
afterwards,  not  universally,  but  in  particular  cases,  as  it 
certainly  did.  The  process  of  such  growth  is  clearly  trace- 
able in  the  Hindu  states  of  Oudh,  and  is  well  described 
in  Mr.  Bennett's  excellent  Settlement  Report  on  the  Gonda 
District  (1878).  It  is  also  clearly  traceable  in  Guzarat 
(Bombay  Presidency),  not  to  mention  numerous  other 
instances. 

§  1 8.    The  Right  to  the  Waste. 

The  conclusion  that  the  earliest  villages  consisted  of  ag- 
gregates of  individual  holders,  with  only  the  Raja  or  chief 
over  them  as  ruler  not  landlord,  depends  to  some  extent  on 
what  was  held  regarding  the  ownership  of  the  uncultivated 
and  unoccupied  lands.  Where  there  is  a  true  joint  village, 
as  we  shall  presently  see,  we  find  some  person  (or  body) 
claiming  the  entire  area  in  a  ring  fence,  uncultivated  as 
well  as  cultivated.  But  in  the  ordinary  village  of  Manu, 
the  individual  cultivators,  each  strongly  attached  to  his  own 
holding,  make  use  of  the  adjacent  waste  for  grazing  and 
wood-cutting,  but  do  not  claim  it  as  theirs.  Certainly  the 
Raja  or  the  chief  exercised  the  right  of  making  grants  and 
locating  settlers  on  this  waste,  and  the  village  headman  was 
applied  to  to  authorize  the  breaking  up  of  fresh  waste.  In 
some  parts  of  Oudh,  where  there  was  valuable  timber  on 

1  It    is    quite    certain    that    no  to    imply   the    contrary.      I    have 

phrase  in  Manu  gives  the  slightest  carefully      re-examined      Biihler's 

hint  of  any  joint-body  owning  in  translation,  and   find  nothing  ap- 

common  a  certain  group  of  territory  preaching  an  indication  of  anything 

in  a  ring-fence.      Mr.   Phillips  in  beyond     a     group     of     cultivators 

his  first  lecture,  and  M.  de  Lave-  (under  a  common  headman)  whose 

leye,  if  I   rightly  understand   his  individual  right  depends  on  the  first 

use    of   the    term    '  communaute '  clearing  of  the  jungle. 
(Proprietd Primitive,}).  66\ would  seem 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL   VIEW   OP   THE    LAND-TENURE.  1 29 

the  land,  we  find  the  Raja  levying  (as  one  of  his  State 
rights)  an  '  axe-tax '  on  the  felling  of  timber,  from  all  out- 
siders. This  is,  again,  quite  inconsistent  with  the  idea  of  a 
communal  group  or  body  owning  the  waste.  As  a  matter 
of  practice,  the  rulers  and  the  headmen  of  the  villages  (on 
their  behalf)  would  allow  any  one  to  extend  his  tillage 
to  the  neighbouring  waste,  because  the  king's  share  of  the 
produce  at  once  became  due,  and  so  the  total  was  augmented. 
Naturally,  as  long  as  waste  was  abundant  and  land  had  no 
great  value,  the  authorities  were  only  too  glad  to  see  culti- 
vation extended  and  a  title  acquired  by  first  clearing  the 
land,  and  did  not  think  of  asking  questions,  or  raising 
objection  to  its  occupation. 

§  19.    Conclusion  as  to  the  oldest  known  form  of 
Village. 

Thus  we  must  conclude  that  the  first  (and,  as  far  as  we 
know,  the  oldest)  form  of  village  is  where  the  cultivators 
— practically  owners  of  their  several  family  holdings — 
live  under  a  common  headman,  with  certain  common 
officers  and  artisans  who  serve  them,  of  which  presently; 
and  there  is  no  landlord  (class  or  individual)  over  the  whole. 
The  Rajas  now  (where  they  survive,  as  in  the  Himalayan 
States)  claim  to  be  themselves  landlords  or  owners  of  all 
the  soil,  and  only  recognize  landholders  as  tenants,  here- 
ditary indeed,  after  holding  for  some  generations  ;  but  then 
they  are  conquerors,  or  rather  descended  from  conquerors 
or  adventurers  who  gained  the  superior  position,  in  one  way 
or  another,  only  a  few  centuries  ago.  No  such  claim  on  the 
part  of  a  Raja  (as  we  shall  presently  see)  is  traceable  in 
Manu.  The  Raja  had  his  own  private  lands  ;  but  as  ruler  of 
the  whole  country,  his  right  is  represented,  not  by  a  claim 
to  general  soil-ownership,  but  by  the  ruler's  right  to  the 
revenue,  taxes,  cesses,  and  the  power  of  making  grants  of 
the  waste.  For  this  reason  I  have  called  the  first  of  the 
two  types  of  village  above  spoken  of  the  RAIYATWAB!  or 
NON-LANDLORD  VILLAGE. 

VOL.  i.  K 


130 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.      [CHAP.  IV. 


(«)  Land- 
lord rights 
have 

grown  up 
over  the 
village  of 
the  first 
type. 


(fc)  Land- 
lord rights 
were  (as 
far  as  we 
know) 
claimed 
from  the 
first  allot- 
ment 
or  found- 
ation. 


§  20.    Modes  in  which  the  second  type  arises. 

Let  us  now  enquire  how  the  second  class  of  village  which 
I  have  stated  to  exist,  comes  to  light  or  has  grown  up.  It  is 
distinguished  by  the  fact,  which  the  reader  will  have  already 
surmised,  that  there  is  a  landlord,  or  a  body  of  landlords, 
claiming  right  over  an  entire  village,  intermediate  between 
the  Raja  or  chief,  and  the  humbler  body  of  resident  cul- 
tivators and  dependants.  It  will  be  found  to  be  (a)  a 
growth  among  and  over  the  villages  of  the  first  type  ;  and 
(6)  to  be  the  form  resulting  from  the  original  conquest  and 
occupation  of  land — as  far  as  we  know — previously  un- 
occupied, by  certain  tribes  and  leaders  of  colonists  who 
settled  in  the  Panjab  and  elsewhere.  I  shall  first  enu- 
merate the  different  origins  of  which  we  have  distinct 
evidence,  and  then  I  shall  offer  explanatory  remarks  on 
each  head  seriatim. 

Every  one  of  these  heads  is  derived  from  an  observation 
of  the  recorded  facts  in  Oudh,  the  North- West  Provinces, 
Madras,  Bombay,  and  the  Panjab. 

The  village  of  the  second  type  arises : — 

(1)  Out  of  the  dismemberment  of  the  old  Rajd's  or 

chief's  estate,  and  the  division  or  partition  of 
larger  estates. 

(2)  Out  of  grants  made  by  the  Raja  to  courtiers,  fa- 

vourites, minor  members  of  the  Royal  family, 
&c. 

\  (3)  By  the  later  growth  and  usurpation  of  Government 
Revenue  officials. 

(4)  In  quite  recent  times  by  the  growth  of  Revenue 

farmers  and  purchasers,  when  the  village  has 
been  sold  under  the  first  laws  for  the  recovery 
i  of  arrears  of  revenue. 

(5)  From  the  original  establishment  of  special  clans 

and  families  by  conquest  or  occupation,  and  by 
the  settlement  of  associated  bands  of  village 
families  and  colonists  in  comparatively  late 
times.  (This  applies  specially  to  the  Panjab.) 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL    VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.  131 

§  21.    (i.)  The  dismemberment  of  the  Edj. 

The  Raja's  position  was  distinctly  that  of  an  overlord ; 
the  title  and  its  appanages  descended  by  primogeniture  to 
one  son  only,  so  that  as  long  as  affairs  went  prosperously, 
there  was  no  tendency  to  any  alteration.  But  cases  oc- 
curred, where,  from  family  dissensions,  or  misfortune  of  war, 
or  both,  the  Raja's  principality  broke  up ;  and  then  indi- 
vidual members  of  the  family  seized  upon,  or  managed  to 
retain  in  their  hands,  certain  portions,  and  of  that  they 
became  in  process  of  time  the  practical  owners — landlords 
in  something  of  the  modern  sense. 

Still  more  easily  would  this  follow  with  the  smaller 
chief's  estates  that  were  not,  like  the  'Raj,'  indivisible. 
Primogeniture  is  there  the  exception,  not  the  rule  ;  and  I  can- 
not state  any  definite  rule  as  to  the  particular  grade  of  rank 
at  which  there  ceases  to  be  a  '  coronet '  or  a  '  throne '  right 
which  only  goes  to  the  eldest.  Among  the  chiefs  who  held 
estates  in  the  ancient  Oudh  kingdoms,  some  families  divided 
the  estates,  and  some  did  not.  When  such  an  estate 
divided,  it  was  almost  certain  to  be  the  case  that  one 
member  got  one  village,  another  two  or  three,  and  so 
on,  till  it  came  to  pass  that  each  family  endeavoured  to 
reproduce  in  the  small  area  of  one  or  two  villages,  the  rights 
of  the  chief  to  the  grain-share  and  other  dues  ;  and  of  course 
seized  on  the  waste  as  an  important  means  of  increasing  its 
wealth.  In  time  these  claims  have  always  developed  into 
a  landlord  right  over  the  village.  And  when  the  original 
acquirer  of  such  rights  dies,  and  a  body  of  joint  heirs  suc- 
ceeds, we  soon  find  a  number  of  co-sharers,  all  equally 
entitled,  claiming  the  whole  estate,  and  (whether  remaining 
joint  or  partitioning  the  fields)  forming  what  is  called  a 
( joint  village-community.' 

§  22.    (2.)  The  Rdjas  Grants. 

In  Oudh  we  have  instances  where  the  Raja  has  made 
grants  to  younger  members  of  his  family,  or  to  courtiers, 

K  2 


132  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

or  where  some  family  in  the  village  of  higher  caste  or  more 
energy  than  the  rest,  has  asked  for  and  obtained  the  king's 
favour.  The  grant  is  called  '  birt,'  or,  in  the  Sanskrit  form, 
1  vritti.' 

As  long  as  the  old  Hindu  kingdoms  remained  in  their 
pristine  state,  such  grants  were  only  made  for  life  to  mem- 
bers of  the  king's  family  for  their  subsistence  (jewan  birt), 
or  were  grants  of  the  waste — in  revenue  language  jangal- 
tarashi — to  clear  the  forest  and  found  new  villages.  But 
when  the  Rajas  came  into  conflict  with  the  Muhammadan 
power,  and  were  dispossessed  or  reduced  to  subordinate 
positions,  we  find  cases  where  they  raised  money  by 
selling  '  birts.'  This  can  be  clearly  traced  in  Oudh,  where 
we  have  a  full  account  of  the  ancient  States  within  what 
is  now  the  Gonda  district1.  The  Utraula  State  is  one 
that  exhibits  examples  of  the  sale  of  birts.  In  all  these 
cases  we  find  that  the  management  of  a  village,  the  whole 
or  a  part  of  the  Raja's  grain-share,  and  the  manorial  rights 
(tolls.,  ferries,  local  taxes)  were  made  over  to  the  grantee,  the 
aggregate  of  such  rights  being  called  the  '  zamindarf/  and 
the  birt  being  called  a  '  zamindari  birt  V 

Exactly  the  same  thing  happened  when  powerful  families 
settled  in  the  villages,  raised  their  position,  either  with  the 
Raja's  tacit  consent,  or  merely  by  usurpation. 

In  Ajmer,  among  the  Rajputs,  we  shall  find  certain  hold- 
ings called  '  bhumiya,'  which  were  in  fact  landlord  holdings, 
created  apparently  for  smaller  chiefs  and  others  who  had 
fallen  out  of  the  ruling  rank ;  and  thus  holding  the  land 
more  directly  than  the  chief  in  his  greater  estate,  they  be- 
came in  every  sense  the  landlord  over  the  cultivators. 

In  all  these  cases  it  might  be  asked  what  became  of  the 

1  Benett's  Settlement  Report  of  Gondd,  jal'  (water),  'sakat'  (forest  rights), 

1878.    Mr.  Benett  remarks  that  such  •  sa-path  '  (right  over  roads,  ferries, 

grants  were  made  chiefly  when  the  &c.)     In  Utraula,  besides  the  Raja's 

Raja  was  in  a  precarious  position  or  grants,   the    Muhammadan    power 

out  of  possession  altogether.     The  settled   its   own   soldiers    in    some 

taking  money  was  sub  rosd,  as  be-  villages,  granting  them  the  Revenue 

neath  the  dignity  of  the  prince.  as  petty  '  jagird&rs.'     In  time  their 

*  The  grant  disposed  of  the  Rajd's  families   became  landlords  of  the 

right  over  the  waste,  to  tolls,  fishing  granted  villages, 
rights,  &c.t  with  the  formula  '  sa- 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.  133 

rights  of  the  original  villagers  whose  title  by  clearing  the 
waste  had  already  been  acknowledged?  But  in  Oriental 
affairs  we  must  not  look  for  definiteness  and  for  consist- 
ency :  doubtless  in  practice  the  old  holders  went  on  exactly 
as  before,  and  had  an  hereditary  right,  which,  though  un- 
defined, was  practically  respected  by  all  decent  grantees 
and  landlords. 


§  23.    Illustration  of  the  effect  of  dismemberment  of  a 
<Rdj'  or  Chiefs  Estate. 

It  is  exceedingly  important  to  remember  how  easily  in 
the  course  of  a  few  generations  a  single  family  multiplies — 
and  the  Rajput  race  is  extraordinarily  prolific — so  that 
when  we  now  see  a  whole  group  of  villages  in  one  locality 
having  the  same  origin,  we  might  almost  suspect  the  settle- 
ment of  a  whole  tribe ;  whereas  really  it  is  a  case  of 
multiplication  of  descendants  and  the  separation  of  in- 
terests, consequent  on  the  dismemberment  of  one  single 
family  estate.  I  cannot  help  alluding  to  the  remarkable 
illustration  of  this  afforded  by  the  clan  of  Tilok  Chand 
Bais  in  the  Rai  Bareli  district  of  Oudh1.  This  locality 
once  formed  the  centre  of  an  extensive  kingdom  or  over- 
lordship,  established  by  Raja  Tilok  Chand.  After  his 
death — spite  of  the  usual  rule  of  primogeniture  which 
applies  to  the  ruling  family  as  regards  the  chiefship, 
though  not  otherwise — the  family  broke  up  into  a  number 
of  petty  estates  ;  i.  e.  the  heads  claimed  the  landlordship 
over  numerous  villages  and  founded  other  new  ones.  After 
some  time  the  family  agreed  to  divide  no  further.  The  result 
has  been  a  large  number  of  small  (village)  estates,  and  a 
certain  number  of  larger  estates  of  many  villages — 537  of 
the  former  and  60  of  the  latter — all,  of  course,  of  the  land- 
lord or  joint  type.  Out  of  1735  villages  in  the  district,  no 
less  than  1719  are  owned  by  descendants  of  this  one  Raja's 
family — in  fact,  the  '  Tilok  Chand  Bais '  have  become  a 

1  See   Gazetteer  of  Oudh,   s.  v.  Ifcii   Bareli,   vol.   iii.,  and   Mr.   Benett's 
Clans  of  Rdi  Bareli. 


134  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  IV. 

numerous  clan,  forming  a  section  of  some  great  branch  of 
the  Rajput  race. 

Many  other  instances,  perhaps  not  on  quite  such  a  large 
scale,  could  be  quoted  from  Oudh,  the  North- West  Pro- 
vinces, and  from  the  Panjab. 


§  24.    Special  features  noticed  in  connection  with  these 
first  heads. 

The  discussion  of  the  two  first  named  among  the  modes 
of  origin  assignable  to  the  present  joint  villages,  leads  me 
to  invite  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  claim  to  be  landlord 
is  due  to  the  same  feeling  of  superior  caste,  with  its  senti- 
ment of  graded  rank  and  obedience  to  the  ruler,  as  produced 
the  organization  of  Raja  and  subordinate  chiefs1.  It  is 
also  worth  noticing  that  it  is  this  kind  of  claim  to  the  soil 
which  is  the  subject  of  discussion  when  we  find  'property 
in  land '  brought  into  question  in  books  and  reports.  The 
humbler  but  strongly-felt  right  of  cultivators  not  claiming 
'  birthright,'  under  the  name  of  '  janmi '  or  '  mirasi '  right,  or 
other  similar  title — in  other  words,  the  right  of  the  '  first 
clearer '  of  the  soil,  is  not  so  much  asserted  and  talked 
about.  But  what  I  desire  especially  to  press  on  the  atten- 
tion of  the  reader  is  how,  as  long  as  the  superior  caste  is 
represented  by  a  Rajd,  or  a  chief  holding  a  great  estate  as 
ruler,  the  original  title  of  the  soil-occupants  is  not,  either 
in  theory  or  practice,  interfered  with.  The  chief  remains 
apart,  receiving  revenue,  levying  tolls  and  taxes,  administer- 
ing justice,  with  perhaps  some  vague  claim  as  conqueror  to 
be  lord  of  all,  but  not  claiming  any  actual  concern  with  the 
occupied  land  in  the  villages.  But  no  sooner  is  this  domain 

1  As  a  matter  of  fact,  in  a  majority  to  any  other  principle.     They  are 

of  cases,    landlord   villages   which  usually  high  caste,  or  military  caste, 

derive  their  origin  from  some  dis-  Of  course  some  are  due  to  strong 

tant  but  still  remembered  ancestor  and  able  families  not  originally  of 

who  was  of  the   Raja's  family,  or  high  caste,  and  these  will   derive 

was  a  royal  grantee,  or   simply  a  their  origin  from  Revenue  farming 

man  of  superior  energy  and  talent  arrangements,  not  being  under  the 

who  pushed  his  way,  will  be  found  head  we   are  at  present  confining 

to  be  held,  or  once  to  have  been  our  attention  to. 
held,  on  ancestral  shares  in  preference 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENEEAL    VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.  135 

dismembered  owing  to  war  or  family  feuds,  and  the  mem- 
bers of  the  family  retain  or  seize  upon  separate  villages ; 
no  sooner  is  there  a  succession  and  a  partition  of  the  family 
estate,  than  the  sense  of  lordship,  focussed  as  it  were  on 
the  more  limited  area,  becomes  fixed  on  the  land  itself,  and 
developes  into  a  claim  to  be  owner  of  the  actual  acres  of 
the  village  area. 

But  there  is  the  same  feeling  of  superiority  that  the  Raja 
or  the  chief  had  in  his  domain  when  it  was  in  its  original 
state  and  dignity,  the  same  sense  that  the  family,  even 
though  it  now  is  a  peasant  family  engaged  in  agriculture l, 
is  far  above  the  plough-drivers  and  humbler  occupants  of 
the  fields.  In  the  case  of  the  great  estate,  the  feeling  is 
expressed  by  holding  the  ruler's  seat  and  taking  the  reve- 
nue ;  in  the  petty  estate,  it  is  expressed  by  the  claim  to  be 
owner  of  everything  within  the  boundaries  of  the  village — 
which  is  now  called  the  '  birthright '  of  the  family  or  joint 
body. 

This  claim  invariably  results  in  the  ultimate  overshadow- 
ing of  all  preceding  rights.  In  time  these  would  have 
become  ignored  altogether,  were  it  not  for  the  existence  of 
provinces  in  which  those  rights  have  never  been  overborne 
by  any  landlord  class  arising  over  them,  and  were  it  not  for 
the  policy  of  some  of  our  revenue-systems  which  were  de- 
vised when  the  Bengal  landlord  settlement  had  been  found 
to  be  fraught  with  troubles,  and  when  a  great  desire  to 
protect,  if  not  to  push  forward,  the  humbler  classes,  began 
to  be  felt. 

The  phenomenon  described — the  change  from  rulership 
to  landlordship — of  which  instances  so  often  occur  in  Oudh 
and  the  North- West  Provinces,  is  by  no  means  peculiar  to 
them.  Many  cases  are  traceable  in  the  Panjab.  To  this 
cause  also  must  be  ascribed  the  direct  origin  of  the  land- 
lord tenures  of  Malabar  so  often  alluded  to.  The  military 
caste,  called  Nayar  in  that  district,  at  one  time  furnished  the 

1  Necessity   has    forced    Rajputs  themselves  to  certain  parts  of  the 

and  others  to  take  to  agriculture  ;  process  of  tillage,  avoiding,  for  ex- 

but    some    still    compromise   with  ample,   the   actual  handling    of  a 

their    old    dignity    by    confining  plough. 


136  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

ruling  chiefs  and  filled  the  higher  official  positions  over  the 
land.  But  the  historical  fortunes  of  the  country  were 
strange  ;  the  rulership  was  lost,  but  still  the  Nayars  main- 
tained their  claims  (supposed  to  be  quite  an  exceptional 
instance  of  '  private  property '  in  land !)  as  landlords  of  the 
soil,  including  both  cultivated  land  and  forest  waste,  and 
then  began  to  talk  about  their  'janmam'  or  birthright, 
as  is  the  usual  course. 

In  Bombay  the  joint  or  landlord  villages  of  the  Guzarat 
country,  which  are  well  marked  exceptions  to  the  (there) 
usual  raiyatwdri  type  of  village,  are  clearly  traced  to  the 
decay  or  dismemberment  of  former  Rajput  chiefships. 
The  descendants  have  retained  a  village  here  and  a 
village  there,  or  even  small  groups  of  villages,  and  all 
the  families  are  more  or  less  connected  by  community 
of  descent.  The  sharers  in  these  villages  will  all  regard 
themselves  as  superior  to  the  cultivators,  and  will  prob- 
ably be  addressed  by  some  honorific  title  or  appellation, 
and  are  sure  to  speak  of  their  '  birthright '  in  the  soil. 

We  may  now  proceed  to  consider  the  remainder  of  the 
five  suggested  origins  of  landlord  or  joint  villages. 


§  25.    (3.)  Usurpation  of  Land-officers. 

We  come  to  the  third  head,  the  growth  (and  often  the 
usurpation)  of  Government  officials. 

As  long  as  the  Muhammadan  Government  was  strong, 
it  maintained,  under  changed  names,  but  without  real 
alteration,  the  Aryan  or  Hindu  system  of  territorial  revenue 
administration.  But  it  was  under  this  Government,  in  the 
days  of  its  decline,  that  the  local  officers  were  gradually 
left  with  less  and  less  control,  to  manage  the  revenues ; 
ultimately  they  (and  also  non-official  persons  who  had  in- 
fluence or  capital)  were  recognized  as  contractors  for  fixed 
sums  of  revenue  over  defined  or  undefined  areas.  This 
brought  them  into  closer  managing  contact  with  the  land, 
and  enabled  them  to  become  landlords,  a  process  which 
they  effected  by  clearing  fresh  waste  lands,  buying  up 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL   VIEW    OF   THE    LAND-TENUKE.  137 

others,  and  ousting  the  old  cultivators.  Sometimes  this 
process  extended  over  large  areas,  and  resulted  in  the  form- 
ation of  great  estates  (known  as  those  of  '  Zamindars '  and 
'  Taluqdars ') ;  but  often  also  the  contractor  became  landlord 
of  one  or  more  villages,  and  his  multiplied  descendants,  in 
the  course  of  a  generation  or  two,  formed  landlord  bodies 
or  '  village  communities.' 

§  2,6.    (4.)  Effects  of  Revenue-systems. 

The  fourth  head  is  really  the  same  thing,  only  in  a  more 
modern  form.  It  is  exemplified  chiefly  in  the  North- West 
Provinces.  There,  at  the  beginning  of  the  century,  the 
real  condition  of  the  village  bodies  was  unknown,  the  single- 
landlord  idea  was  the  only  one  familiar  to  the  minds  of  the 
Collectors,  and  the  revenue  management  of  villages  was 
leased  to  one  man ;  he  might  be  a  leading  land-owner  or 
headman,  or  he  might  be  a  capitalist  or  speculator.  In  time 
this  person,  whose  name  might  have  been  recorded  by  some 
device  and  without  any  just  title,  had  opportunities  of  put- 
ting himself  forward  and  getting  a  Settlement  which  con- 
firmed his  position.  In  those  days,  too,  revenue  sales  were 
common  ;  directly  any  arrear  of  revenue  occurred,  the  estate 
was  put  up  to  auction,  very  often  at  the  instance  of  a 
designing  purchaser,  who  had  contrived  the  default  by 
unknown  but  nefarious  means.  The  auction  purchaser  of 
course  became  landlord,  and  his  descendants  now  form  the 
regular  proprietary  community,  either  holding  the  village 
jointly,  or  having  divided  it  up  into  shares J. 

1  In  Holt  Mackenzie's  great  sized  estates  were  doubtless  fairly 
Minute  on  the  North- West  System,  created,  by  the  successive  purchase 
there  are  many  allusions  to  this  of  individual  villages  from  their  ori- 
subject.  He  complains  of  the  ten-  ginal  owners,  or  by  the  extension  of 
dency  there  was  to  refer  merely  to  cultivation  by  means  of  contract- 
records  and  see  whose  name  was  cultivators,  in  districts  having  a 
down  as  the  nominal  holder  of  a  large  proportion  of  desert  waste. 
village,  and  consider  him  as  the  But  the  origin  of  others  was  of  a 
owner  irrespective  of  facts  (§  414).  more  questionable  character.  .  .  . 
And,  speaking  of  the  Revenue  far-  He  appears  to  have  engaged  in  a 
mers,  and  other  persons  who  claimed  constant  struggle  for  the  extension 
to  be  owners,  some  of  several  vil-  of  his  "  zamindari "  property  ;  and 
lages,  others  of  single  villages,  he  as  he  generally  had  the  hand  of 
says  (§  406), 'Some  of  the  moderate-  power  and  a  preponderating  in- 


138  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

Under  this  head  I  ought  to  mention  the  Central  Province 
villages.  As  they  came  under  our  rule  they  were  certainly 
raiyatwdri  villages,  but  it  was,  in  pursuance  of  the  North- 
West  System,  desired  to  treat  them  as  if  they  were  joint 
landlord  villages,  and  make  a  village  Settlement  for  one 
sum  of  revenue.  This,  as  we  shall  learn  more  in  detail  in 
the  chapters  on  the  Central  Provinces,  could  not  be  carried 
out;  and  the  Government  determined  to  confer  on  the 
pdtels  or  headmen,  or  the  revenue-farmers  (called  'mal- 
guzar '  under  the  Marathd  rule)  the  proprietary  title.  Since 
those  days  the  original  grantee-proprietor  has  often  given 
place  to  a  body  of  descendants  who  now  form  a  landlord 
community.  Only  that  in  this  case  Government  repented, 
if  I  may  so  say,  of  what  had  been  done,  and  therefore  early 
took  steps  to  secure  the  rights  of  the  original  village  culti- 
vators, on  whom,  speaking  generally,  it  conferred  the 
privilege  of  an  occupancy  tenure  with  rents  fixed  by  the 
Settlement  Officer  for  the  term  of  Settlement,  leaving  to 
the  landlords  the  free  control  only  of  such  lands  as  were  in 
their  own  direct  cultivation  (called  in  revenue  language 
their  '  sir '  lands).  The  Central  Provinces  thus  exhibit  the 
somewhat  curious  spectacle  of  villages  held  by  artificially 
created  landlord  bodies,  but  with  a  '  tenantry '  whose  land 
is  for  the  most  part  held  quite  independent  of  any  contract 
with  the  landlords  and  beyond  the  reach  of  their  inter- 
ference. 


§  26.    (5.)  Colonization  and  conquest. — Individual  and 
tribal  Settlements. 

The  fifth  head  is  one  which  is  of  great  importance,  as 
under  it  several  varieties  of  origin  may  be  collected. 

The  matter  may  be  stated  thus :  the  result  of  the  Aryan 
immigration  all  over  India  was  the  fusion  of  the  Aryan 
and  Dravidian  races,  and  the  general  establishment  of 

fluence  with   the    "  'Amil "    (local       too  frequently  converted  by  force  or 
Revenue   officer),   the  various   vil-       fraud  into  one  Zaminddri  estate.' 
lages    of    the    farm   or  taluq  were 


CHAP,  iv.]   GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.  139 

smaller  and  larger  rulerships  or  States,  whose  component 
units  were  village  groups.  These  villages  were  owned,  not 
by  joint  bodies,  but  by  aggregates  of  separate  families  of 
landholders.  In  the  course  of  time,  as  the  rulerships  broke 
up,  and  new  conquering  chiefs  established  themselves,  the 
villages  fell  under  the  power  of  new  families  who  soon 
formed  joint-communities  claiming  the  whole  village — either 
single  villages  or  groups.  This  did  not  take  place  over  the 
whole  country,  but  sporadically  or  occasionally,  leaving 
large  areas  with  the  villages  in  their  former  condition.  But 
in  the  Panjab  (more  especially)  we  find  that  there  were 
tracts  of  country  where,  at  a  later  date,  other  tribes  estab- 
lished themselves,  and  where  small  bodies  of  adventurers 
found  a  home :  and  these,  from  the  first,  formed  joint  bodies 
claiming  the  entire  area  of  their  settlements.  This  state 
of  things  is  markedly  illustrated  by  the  Panjab  frontier 
districts. 

All  over  the  North-West  frontier  we  shall  find  the  dis- 
tricts occupied  by  comparatively  small  tribal  and  family 
groups  who  conquered  or  took  possession  of  the  land  at  a 
late  date,  not  before  the  twelfth  and  as  late  as  the  fifteenth 
and  sixteenth  centuries,  before  which  time  the  history  of 
the  land  is  a  blank.  It  is  known  that  in  these  cases  the 
land  was  at  once  allotted  into  villages,  sections,  and  family 
holdings,  so  that,  as  far  as  we  know,  the  groups  always 
regarded  the  whole  area  as  theirs,  and  thus  formed  virtually 
a  proprietary  body  over  each  village.  It  is  possible  indeed 
that  their  own  theory  may  have  been  different ;  but  as  our 
revenue  system,  borrowed  from  the  North- West  Provinces, 
at  once  assumed  these  village  bodies  to  be  joint  and  entitled 
to  all  the  land  inside  their  local  village  area,  and  as  the 
feelings  of  the  people  evidently  fell  in  with  this  position, 
it  is  impossible  to  suggest  any  antecedent  condition  and 
any  subsequent  growth  of  a  landlord  class,  or  gradual 
development  of  landlord  claims.  Most  of  the  tribes  brought 
with  them  camp  followers,  dependants  and  inferiors  of 
various  sorts,  who  became  tenants — however  privileged  in 
some  cases — and  there  never  was  any  doubt  about  the 


140  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

superiority  and  landlord  spirit  of  the  conquering  tribes- 
men, whatever  levelling  effects  later  misrule  may  have 
had,  and  whatever  equitable  claims  the  other  castes  may 
have  been  able  to  urge.  On  the  frontier  this  is  ex- 
tremely marked,  and  the  evidence  is  clear  and  beyond 
dispute. 

The  same  is  hardly  less  true  of  the  Central  Panjab,  though 
the  origin  of  the  villages  is  often  more  remote  and  there- 
fore more  obscure.  Indeed,  for  the  Panjab  generally,  I  am 
unable  to  suggest  that  the  joint  or  landlord  village  arose 
over  an  antecedent  type  in  the  way  it  did  in  the  North- 
West  Provinces  and  Oudh. 


§  27.    Panjdb  Tribes. 

The  Panjab  exhibits  quite  a  peculiarity  in  this  respect ;  • 
we  know  that  originally  the  Aryans  did  not  occupy  the 
plains ;  their  kingdoms  were  only  along  the  Himalayan 
range.  And  where  we  now  find  'Aryan'  Rajputs,  it  is 
probable  that  they  always  represent  later  settlements,  the 
result  of  what  I  may  call  a  reflex  immigration  of  single 
adventurers  or  small  bodies.  But  it  is  also  certain  that 
the  Gujars  and  Jats  were  tribes  who  entered  the  country 
independently,  and  established  villages  which,  as  I  have 
said,  were,  owing  to  tribal  sentiment,  always  landlord  or 
joint  villages.  In  Campbell's  Modern  India  (p.  8)  it 
is  said  '  we  are  not  without  a  historical  glimpse  of  the 
facts.  We  have  very  good  and  accurate  accounts  of 
Northern  India  as  it  was  in  Alexander's  time,  and  we  find 
that  in  addition  to  the  Hindu  kingdoms  ...  he  found 
settled  or  encamped  in  the  Panjab,  great  tribes  of  a  purely 
republican  constitution,  far  more  warlike  than  any  others 
which  he  encountered.  The  best  account  of  this  is  to  be 
found  in  Heeren,  in  the  volume  on  the  Persians  (p.  310). 
Heeren  represents  their  constitution  as  aristocratic  or  under 
the  government  of  their  optimates.'  And  when  Alexander 
treated  with  300  deputies  of  such  tribes,  the  author  goes  on 
to  say  (what  is  doubtless  true),  that  these  were  the  '  pan- 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENEEAL   VIEW   OP   THE    LAND-TENURE.  141 

chayats'  or  councils  of  the  elders  of  the  villages  l.  I  cannot 
help  concluding,  then,  that  while  in  other  parts  of  India 
joint  villages  arose  in  the  various  ways  described,  a  number 
of  joint  villages  in  the  Panjab  are  due  to  the  special  cus- 
toms of  the  particular  tribes  which — distinct  from  the 
Aryan  race  that  overspread  India — settled  there.  That  is 
unquestionably  the  case  with  the  later  tribes  in  the  districts 
on  the  North-West  frontier,  and  it  is  probably  the  case 
with  some  of  the  Gujar  and  Jat  tribes  of  earlier  origin,  and 
some  of  the  less  familiarly  known  castes  also.  The  Jats 
and  the  Gujars  I  distinguish  because  they  went  beyond  the 
Panjab  and  formed  settlements  in  Hindustan  also,  and  are 
therefore  better  known 2.  The  name  '  Jat '  becomes  '  Jat ' 
in  Hindustan. 


1  The  allusion  is  to  Historical  Re<- 
searches  into  the  Politics,  <fcc.,  of  the 
principal  nations  of  Antiquity,  by  A.  H. 
Heeren  (.translated  from  the  Ger- 
man), vol.  i.  The  Persians.  Ox- 
ford :  Talboys,  1833,  p.  310.  The 
author's  account  is  very  note- 
worthy. He  distinctly  shows  that 
there  were  states  under  the  Rajas 
in  the  North  Panjab — i.  e.  near 
the  hills,  where  the  Aryans  (Raj- 
puts) settled  ;  and  mentions  that 
one  of  them,  called  Porus  (perhaps 
this  word  is  '  Purusha '  and  is  only 
a  title  (confer.  Dow's  Hindostan,  i. 
24),  was  at  enmity  with  the  Takka 
or  people  of  Taxila — who,  as  I  re- 
marked, were  still  earlier  Dravidian 
settlers.  There  were  also  kingdoms 
along  the  Indus  ^which  exactly 
corresponds  to  what  we  know  of 
the  early  history  of  Sindh).  'When,' 
he  says,  '  Alexander  crossed  the 
Chinab  (Acesines).  he  fell  in  with 
other  nations  not  living  under  the 
rule  of  princes,  but  possessing  a  re- 
publican constitution.  These  Indian 
republics  occurred  in  the  country 
between  the  Acesines  and  Hyphasis 
(Chinab  and  Bias,  i.  e.  Central 
Panjab),  or  on  the  east  of  the  pro- 
vince of  Lahore.'  He  mentions  the 
Cathcei,  Adriaticae,  and  (in  the 
Souths  the  Malli  and  Oxydraceae  of 
the  Greek  writers.  Heeren's  at- 


tempt to  identify  these  tribes  is  less 
happy  ;  for  in  his  time  nothing  was 
known  about  the  Panjab  tribes.  No 
doubt  many  of  the  races — who  really 
were  our  Jats,  Gujars  and  other 
tribes — became  afterwards  Sikhs, 
but  they  cannot  be  identified  with 
either  Rajputs  or  Marathas.  It  is 
true  that  among  them,  some  clans, 
for  whatever  reason,  never  had 
Rajas,  but  lived  under  their  elders 
in  groups  of  equal  right.  And  it  was 
clans  who  did  this  that  originated 
the  form  called'  bhaiachara,' village, 
as  distinct  from  the  ancestral-share 
or  '  pattidari '  villages.  But  this 
fact  does  not  identify  them. 

2  I  cannot  discuss  the  origin  of 
Jats,  but  it  is  remarkable  that  Panj- 
ab Jats  are  distinct  from  the  Jats 
of  other  provinces,  and  in  South- 
east Panjab  we  have  both  Jat  and 
Jat  tribes  physically  unlike  each 
other.  I  can  only  conjecture,  fol- 
lowing local  tradition,  that  some 
were  really  Rajputs  who  lost  caste 
by  making  mixed  marriages,  &c., 
others  are  a  distinct  race.  A 
great  number  of  the  Panjab 
tribes,  Awans,  Khokhars,  Arams, 
&c.,  may  be  mixed  races,  formed  by 
the  union  of  the  original  Takka  and 
other  tribes  with  Rajputs,  or  with 
later  tribes  colonizing  from  beyond 
the  North- West  frontier. 


142  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

§  38.    Colonies  'multiplied  from  individuals  or 
small  groups. 

But  in  any  case  a  large  number  of  joint  villages  are  due 
to  the  multiplication  of  villages  from  single  centres.  There 
are  numerous  local  traditions  of  scions  of  Rajput  and  other 
'noble'  families  who,  dissatisfied  with  their  prospects  at 
home  (the  parent  stock  had  then  found  a  home  in  Hindu- 
stan, Bikanir,  &c.)  turned  on  their  steps  and  obtained  land 
in  the  Panjab,  where  doubtless  it  was  abundant.  Single 
adventurers  or  small  parties  thus  established  themselves, 
and  spreading  and  multiplying  founded  village  after  village, 
over  which  of  course  the  descendants  are  regarded  as  the 
landlord  communities.  Traditions  to  the  effect  are  too 
numerous,  coherent,  and  intrinsically  probable,  to  be  set 
aside.  We  may  often  distinguish  villages  of  this  class  by 
their  adhering  to  ancestral  fractional  shares  in  holding  the 
land.  Such  shares  show  descent  from  a  common  ancestor, 
the  colonizing  founder  or  conquering  chief. 

There  are  no  doubt  a  large  number  of  villages  where  the  co- 
sharers  now  hold  on  the  basis  of  actual  separate  possession. 
Many  of  these  are  true  landlord  villages,  only  the  accidents 
and  the  fortunes  of  the  times  have  destroyed  the  ancestral 
shares.  Others  may  have  originally  been  of  the  raiyatwdri 
type.  But  if  so,  the  example  of  numerous  landlord  or  joint 
villages  round  them,  and  the  fact  that  when  our  Revenue 
Settlement  began,  they  were  treated  as  joint  and  the  waste 
adjoining  made  over  to  them, — either  of  these  may  have 
induced  them  to  accept  the  lump  assessment  and  the  (nomi- 
nal) joint  responsibility  without  demur.  We  know  this  to 
have  been  the  case  with  the  Kangra  district  villages,  and 
how  far  it  may  have  been  the  case  with  others  it  is  impos- 
sible to  say.  In  fact  it  is  now  hopeless  to  argue  what  the 
original  constitution  may  have  been  \ 

1  I  have  spoken  before  of  the  locally,  owing  to  the  force  of  ex- 
failure  of  the  attempt  in  Bombay  ample,  or  to  the  value  of  the  joint- 
and  elsewhere  to  force  the  joint  waste  conferred  when  the  village 
constitution  on  raiyatwari  villages  ;  was  settled  by  the  Kevenue  officers, 
but  it  might  always  happen  that,  or  from  other  causes,  the  joint  con- 


CHAP,  iv.j    GENEEAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.          143 

In  the  south-east  Panjab  we  shall  also  find  villages, 
which  have  accepted  the  joint  constitution,  whose  origin  is 
clearly  traceable  to  voluntary  associations  of  different 
individuals  and  families,  who  applied  to  a  local  ruler  for 
permission  to  settle,  and  thereon  founded  villages,  only 
within  the  present  century. 

And  the  mention  of  this  form  of  co-operative  colonization 
leads  me  to  speak  of  the  survival  of  joint  or  landlord 
villages  in  Madras. 

The  Presidency  of  Madras  affords  another  instance  of  the 
occurrence  of  landlord  villages  only  in  some  places,  or 
sporadically,  as  it  were,  among  villages  of  the  raiyatwdri 
type.  In  most  cases  it  is  a  mere  trace  of  such  villages  that 
now  survives.  The  details  "will  be  given  in  the  chapters 
devoted  to  Madras  ;  but  I  may  here  give  a  brief  outline  of  the 
events  which  led  to  the  discovery  of  such  traces,  and  notice 
how  they  illustrate  the  subject  we  are  now  considering. 

When  the  failure  of  the  first  attempted  Settlements  in 
Madras  caused  an  enquiry  to  be  made  (about  1814)  as  to 
the  constitution  of  villages,  with  a  view  to  determining 
what  form  of  revenue-settlement  could  best  be  adopted,  it 
was  discovered  that  a  number  of  villages  existed,  in  which 
a  class  of  landholders,  generally  known  by  the  Perso-Arabic 
name  1  '  mirasdar ' — holders  of  the  '  miras '  or  inheritance 
right — was  found.  A  selection  from  the  rather  voluminous 
evidence  on  the  subject  has  been  reprinted  in  an  official 
collection  of  papers  issued  in  1862.  The  conclusion  to  be 
drawn  is,  that  the  villages  with  a  mirdsddr,  or  .landlord 
class,  where  they  existed,  were  survivals  of  some  high  caste 
families  who  by  conquest  or  grant  had  obtained  the  over- 
lordship.  But  in  the  neighbourhood  of  Chingleput  the 
villages  of  this  class  were  more  continuous,  and  evidence  was 

stitution  would  be  accepted  without  practical   non-enforcement  of  any 

question.     It  is  quite  certain  that  real  joint   revenue- liability,   made 

in  the  Kangra  district  (a  hill  and  the  people  accept  the  system  with- 

partly  submontane  district)  '  land-  out  demur. 

lord' villages,  or  indeed  villages  of          l  The     people    had    their    own 

any  kind,  did  not  exist,  and  so  in  names  ;  for  instance,  '  Kani-atchi ' 

the  dry  tracts  in  the  South  Panjab  ;  expresses  birthright  or  inheritance, 
yet  the  grant  of  the  waste  and  the 


144  LANI)    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

forthcoming  to  show  that  they  were  due  to  the  fact  that 
there  had  been  a  great  colonizing  party  sent  out  by  one  of 
the  Dravidian  kingdoms  of  Southern  India;  they  had 
advanced  into  what  was  then  an  unpeopled  forest  country, 
and  having  cleared  the  land  and  established  villages,  the 
different  leaders  of  the  colonist  groups  became  the  landlords. 
In  time  the  original  founder  or  founders  were  succeeded  by 
a  numerous  body  of  descendants  who  divided  up  the  land 
into  shares.  This  body,  deriving  their  rights  from  a  special 
emigration  and  colony  planting,  naturally  regarded  them- 
selves as  entitled  to  a  superior  kind  of  right ;  all  others  were 
their  tenants,  namely  the  low-caste  cultivators  and  others 
who  were  either  admitted  at  a  later  period,  or  represented  the 
descendants  of  dependants  and  followers  who  were  called  in 
to  aid  at  the  original  founding,  which  was  a  work  of  great 
labour  requiring  as  many  hands  as  possible.  And  I  may 
here  remark  that  at  the  present  day  we  hear  less  of  claims 
by  '  conquest,'  than  of  those  derived  from  the  '  founding '  of 
the  village,  though  in  many  cases  the  latter  may  be  a 
euphemism  for  conquest  or  usurpation. 

Especially  in  the  Panjab  I  have  noticed  the  landlord 
class  always  claiming  superiority  as  the  descendants  of  the 
'  original  founders  '  (banian-ganw). 

§  29.  Conclusion  regarding  two  types  of  Village. 

This  brief  sketch  will  now,  I  hope,  have  made  it  clear 
that  we  are  to  distinguish  two  distinct  types  of  village:  one 
is  where  the  landholders  are  disconnected  aggregates  of 
families  each  claiming  nothing  but  its  own  holding — the 
RAIYATWARI  or  NON-LANDLORD  TYPE  ;  the  other  is  where 
a  class  in  the  village,  or  it  may  be  the  entire  body,  claim 
to  be  a  superior  order,  descendants  of  former  rulers,  or 
colonizing-founders,  or  conquerors,  or  grantees,  or,  later 
on,  of  revenue-farmers  and  auction  purchasers,  who  claim 
jointly  the  entire  estate ;  and  this  is  the  JOIST  or  LANDLORD- 
VILLAGE  type 1.  The  former  type  prevails  over  the  whole  of 

1  In  the  first  edition  of  this  work  types  as  the  '  non-united '  and  the 
I  essayed  to  distinguish  the  two  'united'  type  respectively.  The 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.         145 

Madras,  Bombay,  and  Central  India.  The  Central  Provinces 
villages  were,  and  would  still  have  been,  of  this  type,  but  for 
the  action  of  our  own  Government  in  conferring  the  pro- 
prietary right,  so  that  these  villages  have  now  passed  into 
the  landlord  class.  On  the  other  hand,  the  landlord  or 
joint  village  now  prevails  in  the  North- West  Provinces 
and  Oudh,  and  in  the  Panjab.  Probably,  in  the  North- 
West  Provinces  and  Oudh  this  type  was  originally  only 
occasional,  as  elsewhere ;  there  must  have  been  many 
groups  of  old  cultivators  who  had  never  been  interfered 
with,  and  whose  system  of  holding  land  is,  and  always  was, 
according  to  actual  possession  only.  But  the  revenue- 
system,  from  the  first,  treated  all  villages  alike,  and 
whether  it  was  the  descendants  of  a  superior  family  or  a 
group  of  cultivators  who  had  no  joint-claims,  all  became, 
by  the  grant  of  the  waste  and  the  (nominal)  joint  and 
several  responsibility  for  the  land-revenue  of  the  entire 
village,  equally  compacted  into  bodies,  the  joint-owners,  in 
name,  of  the  whole  area.  It  is  certainly  also  the  case  that 
in  more  than  one  locality  the  present  joint-villages  are  the 
creation  of  our  own  system,  circumstances  permitting  the 
change  to  be  accepted  or  not  practically  felt. 

§  30.  Importance  of  the  distinction  as  regards   the 

Revenue  system. 

The  existence  of  two  types  of  village  is  a  fact  of  primary 
importance  to  the  Revenue  student,  apart  from  its  interest 

terms  are  not,  however,  satisfactory ;  advantages  :  the  landlord  class  have 
they  do  not  indicate  the  fact  that  in  certainly  a  strong  feeling  of  su- 
one  type  there  is  a  superior,  land-  periority.  But  there  are  many  vil- 
lord,  class,  and  in  the  other  there  is  lages  where  the  truly  landlord 
not ;  while  there  may  be  a  certain  class  acknowledge  no  chiefs,  and, 
union  in  villages  where  no  superior  as  among  themselves,  are  '  demo- 
chief  claims  the  whole.  The  cratic/  but  this  does  not  put  them 
people,  though  each  claims  only  his  on  an  equality  with  the  non- 
own  holding  or  field,  may  very  well  proprietary  residents  and  cultiva- 
be  '  united '  in  another  sense,  under  tors.  On  the  whole,  I  think  that 
a  common  headman  and  with  a  the  terms,  landlord  or  joint  village 
common  staff  of  artisans.  Sir  for  the  one  type,  and  non- landlord 
George  Campbell,  in  his  essay  in  or  raiyatwdri  for  the  other  type,  are, 
the  Cobden  Club  Papers,  has  distin-  though  not  neat  or  compact  terms, 
guished  the  types  as  '  aristocratic '  still  expressive  of  the  main  differ- 
and  'democratic.'  This  has  some  ence. 

VOL.  I.  L 


146  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

as  a  matter  of  history  and  of  the  development  of  land- 
tenures.  Wherever  the  villages  consist  of  the  loose 
aggregates  of  separate  cultivators,  it  has  been  found  ad- 
visable to  adopt  what  we  shall  presently  describe  as  the 
'  Raiyatwari '  method  of  Revenue  management,  under 
which  each  field  or  holding  is  separately  assessed,  and  no 
holder  is  responsible  for  anything  else  but  his  own  revenue, 
nor  has  he  any  common  right  in  an  allotted  area  of  waste l. 
He  is,  of  course,  provided  with  certain  privileges  of  grazing 
and  wood-cutting,  but  the  waste  or  unoccupied  lands  are 
at  the  disposal  of  Government,  and  given  to  whoever  first 
applies  offering  to  pay  the  assessment,  when  they  are  not 
reserved  for  any  other  special  purpose.  Where  there  are 
landlord  villages,  the  '  North- Western '  or  '  Village '  system 
of  Settlement  is  followed ;  the  waste  is  given  over  to  the 
village;  the  entire  estate  so  made  up  (waste  and  arable 
together)  is  assessed  to  one  sum  of  revenue,  for  which  the 
landlord,  or  landlord  body,  are  jointly  and  severally  liable, 
and  which  (in  case  of  several  co-sharers)  they  apportion 
among  themselves  to  pay  according  to  their  customary 
method  of  sharing — i.  e.  according  to  the  constitution  of  the 
body. 

§  31.  Question  as  to  whether  one  type  is  not  a  decayed 
form  of  the  other. 

Seeing  then  that  joint  villages  exist  all  over  the  Panjab, 
and  largely  in  other  parts,  while  in  Central  and  Southern 

1  The  adoption  of  this  system  was  of  each  otherwise  than  according  to 
not  accomplished  without  some  local  custom  fail.  There  were  joint 
struggle.  The  attempt  was  made  villages  in  the  once  Hindu  island  of 
in  Madras  and  Bombay  to  form  Java.  When  this  island  was  under 
village  settlements  with  the  joint  British  rule  (before  its  cession  to 
responsibility  for  a  lump  sum.  But  the  Dutch),  M.  de  Laveleye  men- 
the  plan  failed,  because  nature  and  tions  that  the  Governor  (Sir  Stam- 
the  social  system  were  against  it.  ford  Raffles,  1811-1816)  attempted 
Conversely,  where  circumstances  to  individualize  holdings  by  making 
are  favourable,  the  joint  system  separate  assessments  :  but  the 
alone  succeeds,  and  is  accepted  people  immediately  clubbed  the 
even  where  the  villages  are  really  sums  together  and  redistributed  the 
raiyatwdri.  Where  there  is  a  strong  total,  according  to  their  own  no- 
landlord  body,  attempts  to  indi-  tions  of  responsibility  and  family 
vidualize  property  and  fix  the  shares  custom. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENEEAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENUEE.  147 

India  they  appear  only  sporadically  among  the  raiyatwdri 
villages,  it  is  not  surprising  that  the  question  should  have 
been  raised — May  it  not  have  been  the  case  that  all  villages 
were  once  joint,  and  that  those  which  are  now  not  so 
represent  a  decayed  form  of  the  other?  I  have  already 
admitted  that  there  are  certainly  cases  where  a  joint  vil- 
lage has  decayed.  For  example,  the  ruler  of  the  time 
imposes  a  very  heavy  revenue  burden  on  a  village :  this 
necessitates  an  effort  on  the  part  of  the  co-sharers,  and 
results  in  the  richer  ones  taking  more  than  their  ancestral 
family  share  of  the  payment,  and  demanding  to  hold  more 
land  to  make  up.  Thus  the  proper  shares  are  upset ;  then 
the  co-sharers  fall  into  poverty,  sales  take  place,  strangers 
are  introduced,  and  in  the  end  each  holder  regards  him- 
self as  a  separate  unit,  and  the  memory  of  the  original 
status  is  lost.  Or,  what  is  often  the  case,  the  leading 
families  have  fallen  into  decay,  the  more  energetic  but 
inferior  caste  cultivators  come  to  the  front,  bear  the  revenue 
burden,  and  in  the  end  cannot  be  ousted  with  anything 
like  justice  from  at  any  rate  the  several  but  full  proprietor- 
ship of  their  lands.  But  all  experience  shows  that  such 
is  the  tenacity  with  which  the  superior  classes  remember 
their  rights,  that  the  loss  is  rarely  complete ;  and  it  is 
hardly  possible  to  believe  that  the  whole  districts  where 
nothing  but  raiyatwdri  villages  now  exist,  could  have  owed 
their  present  state  to  a  wholesale  loss  of  rights.  Nor  is  it 
easy  to  see  how  in  such  a  case  some  villages  exhibit  traces 
of  '  mirasi '  claims  and  others  not. 


§  32.    Illustrations  of  decay  of  Landlord  claims. 

I  should  like  here  to  allude  more  specially  to  the  cases 
where  landlord  claims  existed  and  were  lost,  to  show  at 
any  rate  that  I  do  not  leave  them  out  of  account.  It  is 
certainly  the  case  that  in  Madras  the  '  mirasi '  claims  had 
often  become  very  faint,  but  it  is  equally  certain  that  the 
'  mirasi '  or  landlord  right  was  not  a  uniform  feature  of  all 
villages. 

L   2 


148  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

There  is  an  interesting  paper  on  tenures  in  the  Bombay 
Dakhan,  by  Col.  Sykes l,  in  which  it  is  clearly  shown  that, 
after  the  overthrow  of  the  great  kingdoms  which  had 
adopted  the  Buddhist  faith,  and  to  which  the  well-known 
cave  temples  of  Alura  (Ellora)  and  Karli  are  due,  the 
races,  which  afterwards  rose  to  power  as  the  Marathas,  con- 
quered the  country.  And  Col.  Sykes  finds  many  traces  of 
their  allotting  the  land  on  landlord-shares.  The  shares  of 
families  were  called  by  the  now  forgotten  Hindi  term 
'  thai '  (perhaps  the  same  as  the  tula  or  tola).  But  fortune 
had  not  favoured  them ;  and  most  of  the  holdings,  at  the  time 
when  Col.  Sykes  wrote  were  found  in  a  decayed  state, 
described  as  'gat-kul,'  i.e.  the  'family'  (kula)  is  'lost' 
(gata).  Where  the  landlord  families  had  survived,  the 
Muhammadans  called  them  '  mirasdars,'  and  there  were 
also  successors  who  had  purchased  the  '  miras '  right.  But 
it  was  evident  that  these  cases  represented  estates  appro- 
priated here  and  there,  by  conquering  families ;  and  very 
likely  were  the  result  of  the  break-up  of  larger  overlord 
estates  of  early  Marathd  rajas  or  chiefs.  This  case  does 
not  lead  to  the  conclusion  that  the  landlord  type  was  once 
universal  and  that  the  raiyatwari  type  is  merely,  as  a 
general  rule,  the  decay  of  it. 

In  Bengal  again,  all  village  rights  have  been  generally 
obliterated.  This  is  due  to  the  arrangements  made  in  the 
decline  of  the  Mughal  rule  for  the  management  of  the 
State  Kevenues.  This  we  shall  describe  presently.  Here 
I  am  only  concerned  to  remark  that  the  destructive 
influence  did  not  change  one  kind  of  village  into  another 
but  destroyed  all  alike. 


§  33.   Resume  of  the  position. 

In  short,  when  we  consider  the  evidence  we  have  that  the 
earlier  races,  and  the  lower  castes,  among  the  Aryans,  all 

1  Published  in  1835,  Journal  of  the  'thalwai,'  and  the  ancient  lists  of 
Royal  Asiatic  Society,  vol.  ii.  p.  206.  shares,  which  survived,  were  '  thal- 
The  holder  of  the  '  thai '  was  called  jara.' 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.         149 

held  land  separately,  by  right  of  first  clearance1,  and  that 
we  can  in  so  many  cases  trace  distinctly  the  growth  of 
landlord  rights  in  villages  over  an  older  race  of  cultivators 
who  always  had  certain  tangible  rights  in  the  soil ;  when 
we  can  prove  that  landlord  villages  (as  we  see  them)  are 
due  (in  the  Panjab)  to  special  movements  of  colonizing 
bodies,  who  occupied  virgin  soil  independently ;  and  in  the 
North- West  Provinces  and  Oudh,  to  the  dismemberment  of 
kingdoms  and  ruling  families,  and  also  largely  to  later 
acquisitions  of  title  by  revenue-farmers  and  purchasers  ;  we 
must  come  to  the  conclusion  that  the  two  types  of  village 
are  due  to  original  independent  causes ;  and  though  in 
individual  cases,  a  joint  village  may  decay  into  a  raiyat- 
wdri,  or  a  village  of  the  latter  type  may  be  formed,  by 
revenue  administrative  measures,  into  a  joint  village,  such 
a  transformation  is  local  and  occasional:  it  is  not  the 
general  and  everywhere  operative  cause  of  there  being 
two  types  of  village. 

§  34.  Differences  and  common  features  of  the  two  types 
of  Village. — The  Village  artisans. 

Let  us  now  glance  at  the  characteristic  differences  be- 
tween the  '  raiyatwari '  and  the  '  landlord '  village. 

Certain  features,  however,  both  have  in  common.  In 
both  there  is  an  area  of  cultivated  land  and  an  area  (very 
often)  for  grazing  and  wood-cutting  2,  though  the  title,  and 
the  method  of  using  that,  are  of  course  markedly  different. 
In  both  there  will  probably  (but  not  always)  be  a  central 
residence  site,  and  surrounding  it,  an  open  space  for  a 

1  And  be  it  always  remembered,  as  the  humbler  cultivating  classes. 
the  leading  members  of  the  higher  2  It  is  most  unfortunate  that  in 

castes  would  not  themselves  touch  these  days,  when  such  an  area  has 

a  plough.     Hence  they  who   fur-  been  given  over  absolutely  to  the 

nished    the    landlord     class    were  (landlord)    village  they  have  been 

always     rulers,     military     chiefs,  tempted  to  break  it  up  for  cultiva- 

or    state    officials   in    some   grade.  tion,  and  now  are  hard  pressed  for 

Humbler  members  of  high  caste,  fuel  and  grazing,  unless  there  are 

whpm  necessity  compelled  to  take  Government  forests  or  fuel  reserves 

the  plough  and  spade,  fell  to  the  and  grazing  grounds  in  which  they 

lower  level,  and  contented  them-  can  find  a  supply, 
selves  with  the  same  sort  of  tenure 


150  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

pond,  grove,  cattle-stand,  &c.  &c.  In  both  there  will  be  the 
arable  fields  with  their  boundary  marks,  and  their  little 
subdivisions  of  earth  ridges  made  for  retaining  the  rain  or 
other  irrigation-water.  Under  both  forms,  the  people 
require  the  aid  of  certain  functionaries,  artisans  and  traders. 
They  need  a  village  messenger  and  night-watch,  as  well 
as  some  one  to  guard  the  crops :  if  it  is  an  irrigated  village 
probably  some  one  will  be  required  to  distribute  the  water, 
to  stop  this  channel  and  open  that,  when,  according 
to  the  village  custom  of  sharing  the  water,  the  different 
parties  have  had  their  due  share.  A  potter  will  be 
required  to  furnish  the  simple  household  utensils  or  to 
make  waterpots  where  the  Persian  wheel  is  used  in  wells. 
A  seller  of  brass  or  copper  pots  will  also  be  found  in  larger 
villages.  A  cobbler  will  make  the  village  shoes  and  the 
plough  harness  or  gear.  A  carpenter  will  fashion  the 
agricultural  implements  and  help  in  the  housebuilding. 
A  money  broker  will  be  needed,  and  some  one  to  sell 
tobacco,  drugs,  salt,  flour,  spices,  oil  and  other  necessaries 
of  life.  Sometimes  a  dancing  girl  is  attached  to  the 
village ;  always  a  barber,  who  is  the  agent  for  carrying 
marriage  proposals,  besides  his  functions  as  barber  and 
also  surgeon.  Sometimes  there  is  an  ' astrologer'  and 
even  a  '  witch-finder/ 

The  staff  varies  in  different  places  according  to  locality. 
In  Central  India  we  find  this  staff,  theoretically  twelve  in 
number,  called  the  '  bara  bulauti.' 

In  England  such  artisans  in  a  village  would  casually 
settle  where  the  prospects  of  trade  invited,  and  would  in- 
differently accept  work  from  any  comer,  being  paid  by  the 
job.  But  in  India, — and  this  applies  equally  to  both  forms 
of  village, — the  village  community  invites  or  attracts  to 
itself  the  requisite  bands  of  artisans,  finds  them  almost 
exclusive  employment,  and  does  not  pay  by  the  job  for 
services  rendered,  but  establishes  a  regular  income  or 
customary  mode  of  annual  payment,  on  receipt  of  which, 
every  village  resident  is  entitled  to  have  his  work  done 
without  further  (individual)  payment.  In  Central  India, 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.         151 

where  the  system  of  remuneration  by  'watan'  or  official 
holdings  of  land  found  most  favour,  we  find  not  only  the 
headman  or  patel  and  the  accountant  (kulkarni)  with 
their  official  holdings  of  land,  but  also  petty  holdings  rent- 
free  for  the  potter,  the  sweeper,  the  water-carrier,  &c.  In 
other  places  the  more  common  method  was  to  allow  the 
artisans  certain  definite  shares  when  the  grain  was  divided 
at  the  harvest;  besides  which  they  received  periodically 
certain  perquisites,  in  the  shape  of  blankets,  shoes,  tobacco, 
or  sugar-cane  juice.  It  is  not  necessary  for  me  to  quote 
any  detailed  account  of  the  village  servants.  Elphinstone 
has  taken  his  we]l-known  account  from  Central  Southern 
India,  Malcolm  has  given  the  detail  from  Central  India. 
The  numbers  and  names  of -the  artisans  of  course  vary  in 
different  parts 1. 


1  See  Elphinstone  (Cowell's  6th 
edition1',  page  69  and  notes,  and 
Malcolm  (the  reprint  of  1880), 
vol.  ii.  p.  16,  Phillips,  p.  23.  The 
following  is  a  list  of  village  servants 
as  recorded  for  the  Gujranwala  dis- 
trict of  the  Panjab.  This  will  serve 
as  a  fair  general  sample  of  how 
these  people  are  paid.  Their  occu- 
pation, as  well  as  the  right  to  serve 
the  village,  is  often  hereditary.  The 
villages  here  spoken  of  are  landlord 
villages. 

1.  The  blacksmith   (lohar^.     His 
dues  are  one  bhari  or  wheat-sheaf  in 
each  harvest,  one  pai  in  money  on 
each  plough,  two  seers  of  molasses 
(gur),  and  also  one  jar  of  sugarcane 
juice  daily,  while  the  press  (belna) 
is  working ;   and  he  is  allowed  to 
have  one  day's  picking  at  the  cotton- 
field  at  the  end  of  the  season. 

2.  The  carpenter  (tarkhan).     He 
makes  the  well  woodwork,  handles 
for  tools,  beds  (charpai),  stools,  &c. 
His  dues  are  much  the  same  as  the 
lohar's. 

3.  The   kumhar  or   potter,    who 
makes  household  utensils  and  also 
pots. 

4.  The  '  rera'  or  grass-rope  maker ; 
the  ropes  are  necessary  to  form  the 
bands   over  the  well-wheel  which 
carry  the  water-pots.     He  gets  one 


'  bhari  '  and  four  topas  of  grain  per 
well. 

5.  The  '  chuhra  '  or  sweeper.     He 
cleans  the  corn,  cleans  the  cattle- 
sheds,  and  makes  the  manure  into 
cakes  for  fuel  :  a  place  for  drying 
these   cakes   is   often  a  recognized 
common  allotment  outside  the  vil- 
lage site. 

6.  The   '  mochi '  or   cobbler   and 
chamar,  who  also  has   a   right  to 
appropriate  the  skins  of  the  cattle 
that  die. 

7.  The  'hajjam  '  or  '  nai.'     He  is 
the  barber,  but  also  carries  messages 
and  proposals  connected  with  mar- 
riages  and  betrothals,  and   serves 
also  at  funerals. 

8.  The  '  dhobi '  or  washerman. 

9.  The  'jhewar'  (this  is  a  local 
term),    equivalent   to    '  bihisti '    or 
water-carrier. 

Besides  there  may  be  the  village 
astrologer  and  musician  (mirasi) 
and  various  religious  office-holders 
• — the  purohit,  or  brahman,  a  faqir 
who  keeps'  the  takya  or  village 
place  of  assembly  ;  the  '  maulvi ' 
for  the  mosque  service,  a  '  bhai '  at 
a  temple  called  dharmsala,  a  '  sadh ' 
at  a  thakurdwara,  a  pujari  at  a 
shivala  (^temple  of  Siva),  and  a  ma- 
hant  of  a  '  devidwara '  (other 
temple). 


152  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 


§  35.   The  Headman. 

Having  noticed  what  the  villages  have  in  common,  we 
may  proceed  to  describe  the  points  in  which  they  differ. 

If  I  had  to  select  a  characteristic  difference  between  the 
two  types  of  village,  I  should  find  it  in  the  '  headman.' 

When  the  village  consists  of  a  number  of  loosely  aggre- 
gated cultivating  occupants,  it  is  very  natural  that  they 
should  choose  or  recognize  some  one  of  their  number  to 
be  their  headman.  Possibly  this  man  is,  or  represents,  the 
leader  of  the  original  settlers,  or  is  in  some  other  way 
marked  out  as  a  trusty  and  privileged  person.  He  is 
referred  to  to  decide  local  disputes,  to  allot  lands  when 
cultivation  extends,  and  so  forth.  And  when  the  village 
comes  under  a  definite  State  organization  and  pays  a 
revenue  to  the  ruler,  most  naturally  that  ruler  looks  to  the 
headman  for  the  punctual  realization  of  his  rights.  His 
importance  and  dignity  are  then  enhanced  because  he 
becomes  vested  with  a  certain  measure  of  State  authority, 
and  is  probably  remunerated  by  the  State.  His  office  is 
hereditary,  or  becomes  so,  and  the  State  does  not  interfere, 
except  in  some  case  of  manifest  personal  incompetence, 
and  then  probably  another  member  of  the  family  is  se- 
lected, at  any  rate  to  the  practical  functions  of  the  office l. 

Where  the  headman  is  (as  in  Central  India)  allowed  an 
official  holding  of  land — his  watan,  as  it  is  called — the 
office  becomes  still  more  desirable.  In  these  parts  it  will 
generally  be  found  that  the  'patel'  owns  the  best  land; 
he  is  also  the  owner  of  the  central  site  in  the  village, 
frequently  an  enclosed  space  of  some  size,  fortified  perhaps 
by  mud  walls  ;  and  within  this  only  members  of  the  family, 
all  of  whom  will  be  addressed  as  'patel,'  reside,  when 
other  houses  are  situated  around  and  below.  We  shall 


1  Some  trouble  must  have  been  exercised  the  functions  in  a  sort  of 

felt  in  former  days  when  (in  Central  rotation,  one  member  for  one  year 

India)  the  patel's  family  multiplied.  (or  whatever  it  might  be),  and  then 

They  seem   to   have  regarded   the  the  next, 
headman's  office  as  jointly  held,  and 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENBEAL   VIEW    OF    THE    LAND-TENUEE.        153 

afterwards  hear  of  great  princes  being  anxious  to  hold  the 
'  patelship '  of  villages  and  the  (  watan ' l  land  pertaining  to 
it,  because  of  the  permanence  and  stability  of  this  form 
of  right. 

Now  in  the  landlord  village,  naturally  the  headman  as 
such,  did  not  exist.  The  proprietary  families  were  too 
jealous  of  their  equal  rights  to  allow  of  any  great  degree 
of  authority  residing  in  one  head.  Their  system  was  to 
manage  village  affairs  by  a  council  of  the  heads  of  families 
called  '  panchayat.' 

It  is  true  that  in  landlord  villages,  either  one  headman, 
or  one  headman  for  each  division  is  now  to  be  found ;  but 
that  is  an  appointment  of  the  State,  and  for  administrative 
purposes.  In  former  days  such  a  single  headman  selected 
to  answer  for  the  revenue  and  deal  generally  on  behalf  of 
the  villages  with  the  State  officers,  was  called  '  muqaddam2/ 
In  our  own  times,  such  a  headman  has  received  the  name 
of  '  lambardar '  (the  representative  whose  name  bears  a 
separate  'number'  in  the  Collector's  register  of  persons 
primarily  responsible  for  the  revenue),  and  this  modern 
term  at  once  marks  that,  in  the  landlord  village,  the  head- 
man is  no  part  of  the  original  social  system.  The  State 
now  usually  recognizes  his  right  to  office  as  hereditary, 
and  desires  to  make  it  to  some  extent  elective  also.  But 
this  is  with  a  view  of  popularizing  the  institution.  It  is 
essentially  an  administrative  addition  to  the  village. 
Where  a  landlord  village  is  united,  it  still  keeps  up  its 
panchayat,  and  where  the  institution  is  falling  into  dis- 
credit and  the  patwari  or  some  energetic  '  lambardar ' 
begins  to  dominate,  we  may  be  sure  that  poverty  and 
decay  are  affecting  the  body. 

1  See  remarks  on  the  watan  in  the  the  latter  the  direct  duty  of  paying 
next  section.  in   the   revenue.     This   is   because 

2  In  the  Central  Provinces  they  under  the  particular  circumstances 
still  keep  the  name   '  muqaddam '  of  these  provinces,  it  is  possible  that 
(or  in  the  Hindi  form  Mukadam)  as  the    functions    of    office    may    be 
well  as  lambardar,  the  former  ex-  divided  between  two  persons, 
pressing  the   executive    functions, 


154  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

§  36.   Other  Village  officials. 

Just  as  an  artisan  staff  is  found  (necessarily)  under 
either  form  of  village,  so  the  accountant  ('patwari'  in 
Upper  India,  '  karnam '  in  the  South,  '  kulkarni '  in  the 
West)  is  found.  Originally  in  non-landlord  villages,  he 
was  a  State  officer,  and  in  the  others  more  the  servant 
of  the  proprietary  body.  But  now,  of  necessity,  he  is  a 
Government  servant  pure  and  simple,  paid,  controlled  and 
appointed  by  the  State,  and  subject  to  certain  tests  of 
efficiency.  To  popularize  the  institution,  the  office  is 
allowed  to  be  hereditary,  supposing  a  next  heir  is  fit,  and 
is  sent  to  school  to  qualify  himself. 

The  village  'watchman'  is  also  an  important  officer  in 
both,  as  he  is  utilized  and  often  controlled  by  Government 
as  a  sort  of  village  policeman. 

§  37.    General  statement  of  differences. 

I  may  perhaps  best  show  at  a  glance  the  differences 
between  the  villages  by  arranging  in  parallel  columns 
a  list  of  characteristic  features. 

KAIYATWARI  OK  NON-LANDLORD  JOINT  OR  LANDLORD  VILLAGE 

VILLAGE  (Punjab,  Nort h-  West  Provinces, 

(Bombay,  Madras).  Oudh,  and  Central  Provinces). 

1.  The  revenue  is  assessed  i.  The -revenue  is  assessed 
on  each  field  or  holding.     No  on  the  village  as  a  whole,  and 
responsibility  of  one  man  for  the  burden  is  distributed  by 
another's  default.  the  co-proprietors  themselves. 

Village  co-sharers  are  jointly 
and  severally  liable  for  the 
whole. 

2.  The  village   site   is   not          2.  The  village  site  is  owned 
owned  by  any  one   landlord,      by  the  proprietary  body,  who 
except  as  far  as  each  occupant      allow  residences  to — 
householder   is  owner  of  his          (i)  the  '  kamin,'  the  artisan 
site.      The  patel  has  often  a      class,     farm     labourers,     and 
large  central  residence.  menials. 

(2)  The  tenantry. 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL   VIEW   OF    THE    LAND-TENUEE.         155 


(3)  The  traders.  money 
lenders,  &c. 

These  probably  pay  some 
small  dues,  according  to  cus- 
tom ;  and  if  they  leave  the 
village  may  have  no  right  to 
dispose  of  the  site,  and  only  in 
some  cases  to  remove  the  roof 
timbers  and  other  materials. 

3.  The   waste    outside    for          3.  The  waste  is  allotted  to 
grave-yard,  cattle-shed,  pond,      the  village,  forms  part  of  the 
grove,  &c.,  &c.,  is  Government      estate,  and  if  wanted  for  culti- 
land,    the    area   of    which   is      vation,  is   partitioned  among 
allowed   to    the   villages    for      the  share-holders. 

these  purposes,  and  this  land 
cannot  be  diverted  from  such 
purposes. 

No  waste  area  is  granted 
jointly  to  the  village.  Prob- 
ably the  use  of  some  available 
land  for  grazing,  &c.,  is  allowed ; 
and  if  there  are  waste  numbers 
which  may  be  cultivated,  they 
must  be  applied  for  (and  reve- 
nue paid  thereon)  to  the  land 
authorities. 

4.  The  headman  is  an  im-          4.  The  village  government 
portant  functionary  and  part      is  by  the  panchayat  or  group 
of  the  original  constitution.          of   heads    of    families.       The 

headman  is  called  '  lambar- 
dar,'  and  is  (as  the  name  in- 
dicates) a  later  addition,  and 
exists  chiefly  for  revenue  and 
administrative  purposes. 

5.  The   accountant    (patwari,    &c.),    watchman,   messenger, 
artisan,  and  labourer  staff  are  common  to  both  forms. 

§  38.    Constitution  of  the  Raiyativdri  or  Non-landlord 

Village. 

Naturally  there  is   little  to  be   said  about  the  consti- 
tution of  the  non-landlord  village. 


156  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

There  is  no  room  for  any  variety  in  tenure;  for  each 
man  is  master  and  manager  of  his  own  holding.  Modern 
law  defines  his  tenure  as  '  occupant,'  or  leaves  it  undefined 
as  the  case  may  be,  and  there  is  no  question  of  sharing  on 
this  principle  or  that.  Nor  have  I  heard  of  anything  like 
a  common  account  of  expenses  chargeable  to  the  whole 
village  and  which  is  rateably  levied  on  the  members. 

All  that  we  could  have  to  say  about  the  village  would 
be  to  describe  the  routine  of  cultivation,  of  how  the  head- 
man acts  if  his  intervention  is  called  for,  and  how  once  in 
the  year  there  is  the  settling  up  (jamabandi)  with  the 
State  officer  as  to  what  revenue  is  chargeable,  what  fields 
have  been  held,  what  taken  up,  and  what,  if  any,  relin- 
quished, and  what  remissions  are  claimable  (if  the  particular 
system  allows  this).  But  such  a  description  would  be  one 
of  social  life  or  of  revenue  administration,  rather  than  of 
land-tenure,  and  I  shall  dismiss  the  subject  by  quoting 
a  pleasant  account  of  the  raiyatwari  village  (as  found  in 
Southern  India),  which  I  read  in  the  Goddvari  District 
Manual : — 

'  Each  village  1  constituted  in  itself  a  perfect  whole.  Un- 
heeding the  changes  which  may  have  taken  place  in  the 
Government  above  them,  the  cultivators  of  the  ground  quietly 
continued  their  daily  avocations.  They  yoked  their  bullocks 
to  the  plough,  and  followed  them  in  their  uneven  course.  They 
drew  the  scanty  supply  of  water  from  the  neighbouring  stream 
or  tank,  and  wrangled  over  the  precious  liquid.  They  cast 
their  seed  into  the  saturated  soil,  and  transplanted  the  tender 
sprouts  of  the  growing  paddy.  They  gathered  in  the  harvest, 
and  tended  their  bullocks  as  they  trod  out  the  grain.  The 
simple  household  routine  went  on  as  quietly  and  swiftly  then 
as  now.  The  women  met  at  the  village  well  and  joined  in  the 
petty  gossip  of  the  day.  The  only  excitement  occurred  on  the 

1  Godavari  District  Manual,  p.  247.  are  the  staples.     Eice  villages  are 

This  is  a  '  wet '  or  irrigated  village  mostly  found  in  South   and  West 

chiefly    cultivating    rice.      Rice    is  Bombay,  in  East  Bengal,  in  Madras, 

not   the  staple   food   of  India,    as  and  in  a  few  other  localities  on  a 

is  sometimes  supposed.     Through-  smaller  scale.      It   is   the   food  of 

out  the  North  and  North-Central  only  a  very  limited  portion  of  the 

India  wheat,  barley,   and  millets  population. 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENEEAL    VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.        157 

occasion  of  some  feast  in  their  own  or  a  neighbouring  village, 
or  of  a  journey  to  the  festival  at  some  sacred  shrine.  The 
village  shopkeeper  sat  cross-legged  behind  his  store  and  offered 
loans  at  an  extravagant  rate  of  interest.  The  village  scribe 
and  accountant  were  employed  in  writing  the  accounts  on 
palm-leaves,  or  drawing  up  the  simple  bonds  and  documents 
executed  by  the  ryots,  and  in  assisting  the  village  magistrate 
in  his  rude  administration  of  justice  under  the  spreading 
branches  of  the  village  tree,  where  all  trials  were  held  and 
business  transacted.' 


§  39.    Constitution  of  the  Joint  or  Landlord  Village. 

There  is  much  more  to  be  said  about  the  landlord  village, 
because  it  is  in  the  nature  of  things  that  there  should  be 
changes  in  its  course  of  existence.  Suppose,  for  example, 
that  the  village  is  gained  by  a  single  grantee  as  landlord  ; 
before  long  his  sole  tenure — whatever  its  limits — will  be 
replaced  by  the  joint  tenure  of  a  body  of  heirs1.  Suppose, 
again,  that  the  village  has  from  the  first  been  founded  by 
several  '  landlords '  jointly  ;  it  is  improbable  that  they  will 
long  remain  joint ;  they  will  divide  the  land  wholly  or  par- 
tially, and  then  the  shares  will,  from  some  cause  or  another, 
become  altered  or  lost  sight  of.  Moreover,  as  we  have 
seen,  there  are  joint  or  landlord  villages  where  from  the 
first,  the  principle  of  sharing  is  not  that  of  the  inheritance 
law,  but  some  other. 

Evidently  then  there  are  many  points  to  be  dealt  with 
before  we  have  done  with  the  joint  or  landlord  tenure  of 
villages.  The  Revenue  books  have  adopted,  for  the  North- 
West  Provinces,  some  terms  which  describe  the  various 
conditions  of  jointness,  or  division  (or  partial  division)  in 
which  the  landlord  village  may  be  found.  They  are 
unfortunate  terms ;  and  we  shall  presently  see,  from  a 

1  I  take  it  for  granted  that  the  followed  by  agriculturists.     Primo- 

reader  is  aware  that  by  the  Hindu  geniture  only  applies  to  succession 

law,  and  by  custom  also,  the  sue-  to  royal  or  ruling  chief's  titles  and 

cession  of  heirs  is  joint      Even  by  their   appanages.     This    subject   is 

the  Muhammadan  law  also    it    is,  enlarged   upon   in   the  concluding 

though  the  strict  law  is  not  largely  section. 


158  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

quotation  which  I  shall  make,  how  they  mislead  people ; 
but  it  is  necessary  that  they  should  be  understood. 

Where  there  was  a  landlord  claim  over  the  village, 
such  as  that  of  a  revenue  farmer  who  had  become  pro- 
prietor, or  of  some  chief  or  other  high  caste  personage  who 
had,  many  generations  ago,  acquired  the  superior  title,  they 
expressed  the  right  by  the  term  '  zamindari.'  I  suppose  it 
was  meant  that  the  landlord  in  his  small  estate  had  that 
sort  of  not  very  definite '  holding  of  land '  which  is  indicated 
by  the  native  term,  and  which  was  also  applied  to  the  much 
larger  estate-holder  called  '  Zamindar '  in  Bengal. 

§  40.    Meaning  of  Zaminddri  Village. 

If  the  landlord  were  a  single  person,  the  term  indicating 
the  tenure  was  '  zamindari  khalis  '=  simple  or  sole  landlord 
tenure.  When  however  the  original  grantee  or  acquirer  of 
the  village  had  died  and  was  represented  by  a  family  who 
as  yet  remained  joint,  they  called  it  '  zamindari  mushtarka ' 
— the  joint  or  co-sharing  landlord  tenure.  It  ought  to  be 
needless  to  remark  that  the  term  zaminddri  by  itself 
conveys  no  suggestion  of  jointness  or  common-holding  in 
any  way  whatever.  But  whether  it  was  that  the  full 
phrase  '  zamindari  mushtarka,'  was  too  long,  or  whether  it 
was  that  so  few  villages  had  a  single  landlord,  and  so 
many  a  co-sharing  body,  I  cannot  say ;  but  in  practice, 
writers  came  commonly  to  use  the  word  '  zamindari  village 
tenure,'  as  if  it  meant  the  tenure  of  a  still  undivided 
joint-body. 

In  joint  tenures,  as  long  as  the  body  could  agree  together, 
they  would  remain  undivided.  In  such  cases  the  land  was 
generally  leased  out  to  tenants  ;  or  only  certain  fields  culti- 
vated by  one  or  more  of  the  landlord  body,  for  which  rent 
was  credited  to  the  community.  One  of  the  family  would 
act  as  '  manager,'  and  keep  an  account  of  the  rents  received 
and  any  other  profits,  and  would  charge  against  this  the 
Government  revenue  and  cesses,  and  the  charges  debitable 
to  the  village  as  a  whole — cost  of  alms,  of  entertainment 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENEEAL    VIEW   OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.        159 

of  strangers,  &c. — and  finally  would  distribute  the  surplus 
according  to  shares. 


§  41.    The  Pattiddri  Village. 

But  very  often — in  quite  the  majority  of  cases  indeed— 
the  family  agreed  to  divide ;  so  that  many  joint  villages 
are  found  in  a  state  of  division  or  severalty  as  regards  the 
cultivation  and  enjoyment  of  the  land.  This  may  have 
existed  only  since  a  few  years,  or  it  may  have  been  so 
from  'time  immemorial.'  Ordinarily,  when  the  family  is 
descended  from  some  single  village  'founder/  the  shares 
will  be  mainly  those  of  the  ancestral  '  tree,'  and  follow  the 
law  of  inheritance.  A  sharer  here  and  there  may  be  holding 
a  few  (or  many)  acres  more  or  less  than  his  share ;  but 
the  general  scheme  is  easily  traced  and  is  acknowledged 
by  the  co-sharers.  When  this  is  the  case  the  village  is 
said  to  be  '  pattidari,'  because  the  primary  division,  repre- 
senting the  main  branches  of  the  family  are  called  '  patti.' 
It  will  be  borne  in  mind  that  '  pattidari '  properly  means 
not  only  a  village  held  in  severalty,  but  also  held  in  shares 
which  are  wholly  (or  at  least  in  part)  ancestral,  i.e.  those  of 
law  of  inheritance.  Some  villages  will  be  found  where  the 
primary  division  is  into  '  tarf,'  and  the  tarf  is  divided  into 
pattis ;  but  where  that  is  the  case  it  may  imply  some 
ancient  union  of  two  or  more  distinct  bodies  who  settled 
together  or  some  other  cause  operating  later  in  the  history 
of  the  village.  I  know  of  villages  where  one  '  tarf '  con- 
sists wholly  of  Hindus  and  the  other  of  Muhammadan 
converts,  or  where  one  is  of  one  caste  and  the  other  of 
another.  This  is  obviously  a  special  or  exceptional  state 
of  things.  So  that  in  the  typical  village  body  descended 
from  a  common  ancestor,  the  '  Patti '  is  the  main-branch 
division.  The  '  patti '  is  sub-divided  into  '  thula  '  or  '  tola ' 
or  'thok'  (three  various  names),  and  then  into  'beriV 

1  I  am  not  sure  of  this  word.     I       'bheri,'  and  even  'bhari.'    Wilson's 
find    it  variously  written    'behri,'       Glossary  does  not  give  it,  nor  Elliott's. 


1 60  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

Below  the  '  beri '  come  the  '  khata,'  or  individual  holdings. 
This  will  be  clearer  from  a  diagram  (which  I  have  adapted 
from  that  in  the  Selections  from  the  Records  of  Government, 
North-West  Provinces  (Revenue]  for  181 8-1822).  It  will  be 
observed  that  the  fraction  held  by  each  is  here  represented 
by  the  bisiva,  or  twentieth  of  the  '  bigha/  which  (in  the 
North-West  Provinces)  is  the  usual  land-measure.  But 
sometimes  it  is  expressed  in  '  annas '  and  '  pai  ' — fractions 
of  a  rupee  regarded  as  the  unit  or  whole. 

In  order  to  count  up  to  the  smallest  of  the  sub-divisions, 
custom  has  established,  in  various  parts,  minute  fractions 
far  below  the  '  biswa '  or  the  '  anna.'  Instances  will  be 
found  detailed  in  the  chapter  on  North-West  Provinces 
tenures.  Thus  we  have  the  anna,  not  only  divided  into  pai, 
but  the  pai  into  kauri,  and  the  kauri  into  gandd,  &c. 
In  the  present  case,  the  whole  estate  consists  of  2000 
bighas  of  land  ;  accordingly  this  area  represents  the  whole, 
or  'bigha.'  Then,  a  man  who  owns  a  four-biswa  share,  owns 
four-twentieths  (one-fifth)  of  2000,  or  400  bighas,  and  pays 
one-fifth  of  the  revenue ;  so,  if  the  revenue  is  Rs.iooo,  he  will 
hold  400  bighas,  and  pay  (one-fifth  of  Rs.  1000  =  )  Rs.  200*. 
In  the  example  it  is  evident  that  the  '  pattis,'  which  are 
here  the  primary  shares,  represent  a  state  of  the  property 
when  the  family  consisted  of  two  brothers  (A  and  B)  in  one 
branch,  and  three  brothers  (C,  D,  E)  in  another  branch,  in 
parity  of  descent.  The  fathers  of  these  two  branches  were 
equal ;  for  A  and  B  have  half  (4  +  6  biswas)  between 
them,  and  C,  D,  E  (5  +  3  +  2  biswas)  the  other  half,  between 
them.  Observe  that  A  and  B  ought  to  have  five  biswas 
each ;  but,  owing  to  some  inequality  of  value — some  sale 
or  other  accidental  circumstance — one  has  four,  and  the 
other  six.  So,  too,  the  shares  of  A's  sons  have  become 
unequal.  Under  each  share  I  have  marked  the  area  (in 

1  If  we  were  counting  by  fractions  counted  by  fractions  of  a  rupee  the 

of  the  rupee,  a  man  who  held  400  shares  would  be  in  even  numbers, 

bighas  out  of  2000  and  paid  Rs.aoo  as  i  anna,  2  anna  or  |  anna,  £,  &c. 

out  of  Rs.  1000   revenue,  would  be  Such  a  fraction  as  3*  annas  would 

said  to  hold  a  '3^  anna  share'  of  only  occur  if  the  share  had  become 

the  estate.     Probably  in  an  estate  varied  by  sale,  &c. 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.          1 6 1 

bighas  and  biswas),  and  the  share  of  the  revenue  paid  in 
money. 


VILLAGE  X 


Area  2000  bighas. 
Land-Revenue  assessed  Rs.  1000. 


(might  form  a  'tarf').                               (might  form  a  '  tarf'). 
Patti  A.                 Patti  B.       Patti  C.       Patti  D.      Patti  E.       total. 

Share.          6  'biswas'  (      4  bis.     (      5  bis.     (      3  bis.     (      2  bis.     (  =     20 
Holding.  600  B.             )  400  B.       j  500  B.       j  300  B.       |  200  B.       <  =  2000 
Paying.    300  Rupees    (  200  R.       (  250  R.       (  150  R.       (  100  R.       (  =  1000 

Y 

[These  may  all   be  subdivided  in  the 
same  way  :  or  in  one  or  other  branch 
all  the  descendants  but  one  or  two 
may  be  dead,  and  the  whole  patti  be 
held  by  the  survivors.  ] 

Thok  I. 
3^  biswa  share. 
350  B. 

175  R. 

Thok  'II. 
2|  biswa  share. 
2506. 
125  R. 

1 

1                    1 
Beri  i.         Beri  2.        Beri  3.        Beri  4. 
(Each)  1  of  a  biswa.      &c.               &c.               &c. 
87  B.  10  b.          ^  —  -Y-  -^ 
R.  43  as  12.             Remain  undivided 
perhaps. 
Divided  into  (say) 
4  equal  '  Khata  ' 
or  individual  holdings. 

1                     i 
Beri  5.          Beri  6. 
i£  biswa.               &c. 
125  B. 
R.  62  as  8. 

There  may,  or  may  not,  be  the  last  division  (khata). 
Possibly  the  '  beri  '  may  be  enjoyed  by  some  sons  or  grand- 
sons jointly.  But  the  sharers  will  be  on  the  list,  with 
their  fractional  interest  recorded.  So  that  the  individual 
proprietors  are  called,  in  Revenue  language,  the '  khatedars.' 

There  are  many  villages  in  which,  as  far  as  we  can  tell, 
a  separation  of  'pattis,'  and  perhaps  some  minor  sub- 
divisions, have  existed  from  the  first  colonization,  found- 
ation, or  acquisition  of  the  village. 


§  42.    The  fihdidchdrd  Village. 

But  one  of  the  curiosities  of  tribal  history  in  India  is 
that,  owing  to  whatever  cause,  all  tribes,  clans,  or  families 
did  not  adopt  the  same  system — indeed,  I  believe  it  is  the 

VOL.  I.  M 


1 62  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

case  that  different  sections  of  the  same  tribe  adopted  dif- 
ferent methods.  Some  tribes  had  no  Rajas  or  greater  chiefs, 
and  all  the  families  were  exactly  equal  under  their  seve- 
ral heads  or  elders ;  and  on  settling  in  a  new  place  they 
adopted  a  different  method  of  allotting  the  land.  One  of 
the  first  forms  of  joint  village  to  be  discovered  (in  Benares) 
was  a  form  of  village  called  '  bhaiachara ' — i.e.  held  by  the 
custom  (achara)  of  the  brotherhood  (bhai).  There  is  no 
sort  of  question  that  these  villages  were  of  the  joint  type, 
i.  e.  they  were  held  by  castemen  of  the  higher  orders,  and  that 
they  formed  close  communities,  regarding  themselves  as 
landlords  and  superior  to  all  other  people  on  the  estate  ;  but 
still  they  did  not  adopt  any  system  of  sharing  based  on  the 
place  in  the  ancestral  'tree,'  but  started  (when  the  village 
first  was  founded)  with  an  equal  division  of  land,  often 
adopting  curious  area-measures  or  standards  for  dividing, 
which  were  not  the  ordinary  land  measures  or  '  bighas,'  but 
were  '  bhaiachara  bighas,'  measures  of  a  larger  size,  and 
arranged  so  as  to  consist  of  several  plots  of  the  different 
qualities  of  land  ;  or  to  be  small  in  the  best  soil  and  larger  in 
the  inferior.  The  other  distinguishing  feature  of  this  tenure 
was  that  the  holders  did  not  merely  undertake  the  share  of 
the  revenue  burden  which  corresponded  to  their  fractional 
interest  in  the  estate1,  but  they  distributed  so  that  the  pay- 
ment should  always  correspond  to  the  holding ;  and  in  many 
of  the  villages  (notably  in  the  Bundelkhand  districts)  there 
was  a  system  of  equalization  known  as  '  bhejbarar 2,'  which 
consisted  sometimes  in  exchange  of  holdings,  but  more 
especially  in  a  redistribution  of  the  payments,  according  to 
the  actual  holdings ;  so  that  if  one  sharer  in  the  course  of 
time  found  his  holding  diminished  or  its  productive  power 
fall  off,  he  could — or  rather,  when  things  were  ripe  for  it,  the 

1  In  a  regular  pattiddri  or  fractional  pay  one-fourth  of  the  revenue,  al- 
estate  two  men  hold  one-fourth  each,  though  this  was  out  of  all  pro- 
let  us  say :  each  pays  one-fourth  portion  to  the  real  value  of  the 
of  the  revenue  of  the  whole.  But  land. 

one  man's  one-fourth  may  become  2  The  papers  are  collected  in  Se- 

extraordinarily  profitable   by  irri-  lections  from  the  Records  of  Government, 

gation,  &c.  and  the  other  one-fourth  North-West  Provinces,  Part  VIII,  No. 

might  remain  as  it  was  and  even  34  (Report  by  H.  Rose,  Collector  of 

deteriorate.     Still  each  would  only  Banda). 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL   VIEW    OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.          163 

community  could — procure  a  readjustment  of  the  burdens 
according  to  the  actual  state  of  each  holding  and  the  rela- 
tive value  of  them. 


§  43.    Extended  use  of  the  term  Bhdidchdrd. 

But  the  term  '  bhaiachara  '  soon  got  to  be  used  not  only 
for  a  special  class  of  tenures,  but  for  all  tenures  of  co- 
sharers  when  there  was  no  ancestral  system  of  fractional 
shares,  but  when  some  other  principle  of  distribution  had 
always  been  followed,  or  where,  if  a  fractional  system  had 
once  been  followed,  it  had  fallen  into  disuse. 

In  many  cases  where  the  village  was  due  to  a  body  who 
joined  forces  to  colonize  and  settle,  they  divided  the  area  of 
which  they  became  the  landlords,  not  by  family-shares,  but 
by  the  number  of  ploughs  each  brought ;  or  simply,  land 
being  abundant,  each  man  took  as  much  land  as  he  wanted 
or  could  manage,  and  that  became  the  measure  of  his 
interest  in  the  entire  estate ;  or  a  certain  number  of  wells 
were  sunk  and  a  certain  area  was  commanded  by  each  well, 
and  then  shares  in  the  irrigation  became  the  measure  of 
interest ; — either  shares  by  inheritance  from  one  original 
well-sinker,  or  shares  depending  on  the  capital  expended  by 
several  who  joined  in  the  sinking. 

And  it  is  to  be  remembered  that  a  great  number  of  old 
villages  over  which  no  landlord  claims  had  ever  arisen 
(or  had  disappeared),  and  in  which  the  really  individual 
holders  had  no  system  of  sharing,  exist  in  Oudh  and  the 
North -West  Provinces,  and  probably  in  the  Panjab.  Such 
villages  would  have  remained  raiyatwdri  in  form  but  for 
the  revenue-system.  In  them  the  holder  speaks  of  his 
field  as  his  '  dadillahi,' — the  Divine  gift,  and  has  no  idea 
of  shares. 

All  these  forms,  owing  to  the  absence  of  any  fractional 
ancestral  share  scheme,  became  equally  confused  under  the 
common  name  of  '  bhaiachara.' 

The  same  thing  happened  with  villages  where  ancestral 
shares  once  existed,  but  had  been  lost  or  allowed  to  fall 

M    2 


164  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BKITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

into  abeyance.  A  long  course  of  oppressive  assessments, 
the  results  of  efforts  to  meet  the  burden  (the  proprietors 
earnestly  striving  not  to  lose  their  land),  long  absence  of 
some  co-sharers  1,  poverty  of  others,  the  necessity  for  sales, 
and  the  voluntary  surrender  of  unprofitable  lands, — all 
these  accidents  might  cause  the  old  shares  to  be  forgotten 
or  given  up,  and  to  substitute  a  new  scale  of  possession  out 
of  harmony  with  the  rules  of  descent.  In  some  cases,  while 
the  shares  were  lost  as  regards  the  land,  they  were  adhered 
to  in  dividing  minor  profits  of  the  estate,  or  in  dividing  out 
the  waste.  Where  this  is  the  case,  it  is  proof  positive  that 
the  village  was  once  an  ancestrally  shared  estate.  Such 
cases  are  equally  called  '  bhaiachara '  in  reports. 

The  subdivision  of  all  kinds  of  bhaiachara  estates  is  into 
'  patti/  '  thok,'  '  ben','  &c.,  as  in  the  other  form ;  and  the 
major  division  into  'tarf  is  commoner. 

The  student  will  pardon  my  repeating  once  more  that 
the  term  '  bhaiachara '  now  includes  : — 

(i)  Villages  where  some  special  form  of  division  or 

occupation  at  founding  was  adopted. 
Real   landlord     \   (2)  Villages  once  ancestrally  shared,  but  where  the 

villages 

shares  have  been  (wholly  or  partly)  lost  or 
upset. 

Properly  raiyat-     ( 

wari  villages        j   (3)  Villages  never  shared  at  all — each  man's  posses- 


sion is  the  measure  of  his  right. 


become  joint  un- 
der the  Revenue 

system. 

§  44.    Partition  of  joint  Waste  under  £hdidchdrd  method. 

Where  there  is  no  real  system  of  sharing,  or  where  shares 
have  been  completely  lost,  and  the  partition  of  the  waste 
included  in  the  estate  by  the  North- West  Revenue  System 
is  called  for,  it  will  be  distributed  in  the  same  proportion 
as  the  original  holding  bears  to  the  whole. 

1    '  Absentee    rules'    were     well  allow    it    unconditionally,    others 

known   in    our  early  Settlements,  would  fix  a  term  of  years,  or  im- 

and  the  records  constantly  specified  pose  conditions.     Often  too  a  man 

the  village  custom  as  to  what  was  would  get  back,  but  only  to  a  small 

to  be  done  if  an  absentee  returned  portion  of  his  share, 
and  claimed  his  share.    Some  would 


CHAP,  iv.]     GENERAL    VIEW   OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.          165 

For  instance,  a  man's  actual  possession  is  50  acres  out 
of  a  village  of  2500  acres,  all  told.  In  fact,  he  is  owner  of 
one-fiftieth ;  so  that  on  dividing  the  waste,  he  will  get 
one-fiftieth  of  the  area  whatever  it  is. 

Or,  if  the  acres  of  the  principal  or  original  holding  are 
valuable,  and  so  pay  a  higher  proportion  of  the  revenue- 
assessment,  it  may  be  that  the  waste  will  be  allotted  accord- 
ing to  the  proportion  of  the  total  revenue  paid ;  and  then 
if  the  man  pays  (say)  not  one-fiftieth,  but  one-twentieth  of 
the  revenue,  he  will  get  one-twentieth  of  the  waste  area1. 


§  45.    '  Perfect '  and  '  imperfect '  forms  of  Shared  Village. 

It  is  usual  in  the  Revenue  reports  and  returns  to  find 
a  further  classification  heading — '  imperfect  pattidari '  or 
'  imperfect  bhaiachara. '  These  terms,  however,  merely  call 
attention  to  a  feature  which  is  of  no  importance  whatever 
from  the  tenure  point  of  view.  They  mean  nothing  more 
than  that  when  the  estate  was  divided,  whether  according 
to  ancestral-fractional  shares  (pattidari),  or  according  to 
some  other  method  (bhaiachara),  the  co-sharers  did  not  care 
to  divide  up  the  whole,  but  left  a  part  still  joint.  This  might 
(and  commonly  did)  happen,  as  there  was  an  obvious  con- 
venience in  it. 

Suppose,  for  instance,  that  a  considerable  part  of  the 
village  is  held  by  or  let  out  to  tenants,  or  perhaps  held  by 
irremoveable,  privileged  tenants.  It  may  be  that  the  rents 
they  pay  suffice,  wholly  or  partially,  to  pay  the  revenue.  I 
have  known  many  villages  where  this  is  the  case,  especially 
in  sugar-cane  growing  villages,  which  command  a  high 
rental.  In  that  case  there  is  no  object  in  dividing ;  the 
part  that  is  separately  enjoyed  is  held  then  by  each  sharer 
virtually  revenue  free.  If  the  rental  of  the  undivided 
portion  does  not  happen  to  cover  the  revenue,  then  the 

1  This  form  of  partition  is  then  in  the  'Khewat' — a  list  of  share- 
said,  in   revenue   language,    to   be  holders  and  their  payments  made 
'  hasb    rasad    khewat,'    or    in    pro-  out  for  every  estate, 
portion  to  the  actual  interest  shown 


1 66  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

deficit  is  made  up  by  a  rateable  charge  on  the  co-sharers 
according  to  their  constitution.  There  may  be  other  rea- 
sons for  not  dividing  the  whole  estate,  but  the  example  is 
intelligible,  and  represents  an  extremely  common  case. 
This  may  be  realized  by  looking  at  their  statistics  in  the 
chapters  on  the  North- West  Provinces  and  Panjab. 


§  46.    A  better  principle  of  classification  required. 

It  is  unfortunate  that  these  old  terms  are  still  made  use 
of  in  the  Imperial  returns :  they  were  useful  enough  in 
their  day  as  office  distinctions  when  village  tenures  were 
just  beginning  to  be  understood.  But  they  are  as  ineffi- 
cient now  as  the  Linnsean  system  is  to  the  modern  botanist. 
They  distinguish  matters  that  are  of  no  importance,  and 
confuse  together  things  that  it  is  essential  to  keep  separate. 

A  more  suitable  classification  could  be  easil}'-  adopted, 
and  I  have  ventured  to  suggest  one  which  will  be  found  in 
the  chapter  on  the  North -West  Province  tenures,  and  which 
is  based  on  the  distinction  of  cases  where  (i)  the  ancestral 
shares  are  followed  wholly,  or  (2)  partly,  or  (3)  are  theoreti- 
cally allowed  and  recorded,  but  not  acted  on  in  practice,  or 
(4)  where  some  other  plan  of  sharing  is  recognized,  and  (5) 
it  might  distinguish  cases  in  which  individual  possession 
is  the  only  measure  of  right,  and  where  there  is  no  plan 
of  sharing  at  all,  and  never  was. 

§  47.    The  Proprietor's  ' Sir'  Land. 

Before  leaving  the  subject  of  the  joint  village,  I  should 
like  to  explain  the  term  '  sir.'  It  constantly  occurs  in  such 
phrases  as  '  the  proprietor  enjoys  his  sir  land  practically 
without  payment,'  or  '  the  proprietor  is  never  ousted  from 
the  occupation  of  his  sir,  except,'  &c. 

It  refers  to  the  home-farm  or  land  which  the  landlord  or 
co-sharer  holds  directly  in  his  own  management,  either 
cultivating  it  himself,  or  by  his  farm-servants  or  personal 
tenants. 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL   VIEW    OF   THE    LAND-TENURE.          167 

The  distinction  arose  out  of  the  fact  that  the  landlord's 
right  was  so  often  superimposed  on  older  rights.  A  modus 
Vivendi  had  to  be  found  ;  it  was  so,  partly  in  the  method  of 
sharing  produce,  but  chiefly  in  this,  that  while  the  landlords 
had  certain  rents  from  the  whole  estate,  they  left  the  actual 
management  of  a  great  part  to  the  old  '  tenants '  of  the 
village,  who  naturally  held  on  somewhat  easy  terms ;  and 
each  proprietor  took  for  his  own  direct  farming  and  profit 
such  area  of — usually  the  best — land  as  his  share  and  other 
circumstances  entitled  him  to.  That  was  called  his  'sir'  = 
his  '  own ' !.  Even  if  there  should  be  no  ancient  rights  on 
the  estate,  still  the  owners  may  be  non-agriculturists  and 
be  obliged  to  lease  out  the  greater  part  to  tenants,  retaining 
only  special  lands,  the  entire  produce  of  which  (or  rather 
a  larger  share  of  it)  goes  to  themselves. 

Legally  speaking,  the  term  has  become  of  importance, 
because  under  all  Revenue  systems  based  on  the  North -West 
Provinces  model,  there  are  certain  privileges  connected 
with  the  fsir.'  For  instance,  if  by  default  in  payment  of 
revenue,  or  on  refusal  to  engage,  a  co- sharer  is  put  out  of 
possession,  he  still  retains  his  sir  on  a  tenant-right.  And 
a  tenant  who  proves  that  he  has  fallen  to  that  grade,  being 
an  '  ex-proprietor,'  has  always  a  privileged  occupancy 
tenure  of  his  former  '  sir.'  So  also  (in  the  Central  Pro- 
vinces) occupancy  rights  conferred  by  law  on  certain  classes 
of  tenants  do  not  apply  to  '  sir '  lands,  and  it  becomes  of 
importance  to  define  in  the  tenant  law  exactly  what  is  to 
be  regarded  as  '  sir '  and  what  is  not 2. 

In  raiyatwdri,  or  non-landlord  villages,  there  is,  of  course, 
no  room  for  any  such  distinction.  The  '  watan '  lands  of 
the  p£tel  (where  such  a  system  prevails)  are  the  analogue 
of  the  '  sir '  in  the  landlord  village.  Though  we  are  here 
concerned  only  with  villages,  I  may  nevertheless  take  the 


1  In  the  Panjab,  where  the  pro-  culty  had  arisen  from  the  definition 
prietors   are   so   very   often   them-  of 'sir'  that  was  in  force,  and  one 
selves  of  the  agricultural  class,  we  of  the  amendments  of  the  law  in 
hear  much  less  frequently  this  term  1889  was    directed   to   correct  the 
1  sir '  land.  definition. 

2  In  the  Central  Provinces  diffi- 


1 68  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

opportunity  of  remarking  that  in  any  form  of  landlord 
estate,  the  landlord  will,  or  may,  hold  'sir'  land.  Thus 
with  the  greater  landlords  called  '  Zamindar '  in  Bengal, 
or  Taluqdar  in  Oudh,  they  had  '  sir '  lands  which  were 
sometimes  exempt  from  paying  revenue  under  the  name  of 
'  nankar,'  and  were  also  exempt  from  all  those  privileges  of 
occupancy  to  tenants  which  accrued  on  the  ordinary  lands 
of  the  estate1. 


§48.    Present  state  of  the  Joint -Villages. 

In  the  North -West  Provinces  the  sentiment  of  joint-land- 
lordship  seems  to  be  decaying.  Some  of  the  villages  were, 
as  I  said,  never  really  joint  at  all ;  they  became  so  under 
our  system  ;  hence  a  strong  principle  of  coherence  is  hardly 
to  be  looked  for.  Of  those  that  are  really  joint,  many  are 
owned  by  families  descended  from  an  ancestor  who  was 
once  ruler,  conqueror,  or  grantee ;  and  a  great  many  from 
revenue-farmers  and  auction-purchasers.  None  of  these  had 
any  attachment  to  land  as  land,  since  they  did  not  belong 
to  castes  who  themselves  cultivate  the  soil.  I  believe  I  am 
right  in  saying  that  the  individualization  of  land  and  the 
loss  of  the  joint  interest  is  proceeding  apace.  The  pan- 
cTidyats  and  lambardars  have  little  influence :  the  landholders 
apply  for  leave  to  pay  their  own  revenue  direct  to  the  local 
treasury  instead  of  through  the  headman  of  their  '  patti '  or 
their  village,  as  the  case  may  be,  '  Perfect '  partition,  which 
not  only  divides  the  land,  but  also  completely  severs  the 
revenue  responsibility,  is  allowed.  The  result  is  the  growth 
of  independent  petty  proprietors,  but  still  more  of  capitalist 
landlords,  who  buy  up  first  one  field  and  then  (availing 
themselves  of  the  right  of  pre-emption)  another.  They 
are  not  men  of  the  agricultural  class,  but  must  employ 

1  Supposing    a   '  Zamindar '    has  as  is  absolutely  under  his  landlord's 

leased  his  land  to  an  indigo  planter.  control,    i.  e.    on    the    Zamindar's 

The  tenants  hate  growing  indigo,  '  sir '  land.     Hence  the  importance 

and  the  lessee  can  therefore  only  of  distinguishing  the 'sir.' 
compel  its  growth  on    such   land 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL    VIEW    OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.         169 

tenants ;  these  naturally  are  found  in  the  old  land-owning 
classes,  whose  status  is  thus  slowly  changing. 

In  the  Panjab  the  conditions  are  more  favourable  to  the 
joint-village :  there  is  a  total  absence  of  communities 
deriving  their  origin  from  the  revenue-farmer  or  auction- 
purchaser1.  The  villages  are  almost  everywhere  due  to 
foundation  by  colonists  or  tribes  of  superior  strength  and 
character,  most  of  whom  are  agriculturists ;  and  they  seem 
to  have  retained  more  than  elsewhere  the  sense  of  union 
and  the  power  of  maintaining  their  original  status.  Go- 
verned still  by  custom,  they  have  hardly  emerged — at  least 
in  many  districts — from  the  stage  when  the  feeling  that 
land  belongs  as  much  to  the  family  as  to  the  individual  is 
predominant.  The  law  does  not  allow  of  perfect  partition, 
i.e.  dissolving  the  joint  responsibility,  except  at  Settlement 
and  under  special  conditions.  There  is  a  rather  strong  law 
of  pre-emption  which  generally  enables  any  one  in  the 
village  body  to  prevent  an  outsider  purchasing  land.  The 
customary  law  still  restricts  widows  to  a  life  tenure,  and 
prevents  them  alienating ;  while  in  many  tribes  a  childless 
male  proprietor  cannot  alienate  to  the  prejudice  of  his  next 
heirs  without  their  consent.  There  is  also  in  many  parts 
a  strong  '  clannish '  feeling  which  keeps  villages  together. 
Nevertheless,  the  power  of  free  sale  and  mortgage  is  pro- 
ducing its  results :  non-agricultural  capitalists  are  buying 
up  land,  and  estates  slowly  undergo  a  change.  Strangers 
are  introduced  ;  the  village  site  enlarges,  and  the  non- 
proprietary  classes  successfully  resist  the  payment  of  dues 
to  a  proprietary  body,  and  claim  the  right  to  sell  their 
houses  and  sites  ;  and  gradually  the  old  landlord  body  sink 
into  oblivion.  If  large  estates  accumulate  in  the  hands  of 
individuals,  they  will  again  become  joint  if  the  heirs  are 
numerous,  and  then,  as  the  property  will  be  not  in  one  vil- 
lage, the  estate  will  more  and  more  cease  to  be  synonymous 
with  the  village. 

1  The  Panjab  was  not  annexed  till  after  the  days  of  revenue  farming 
and  harsh  sale  laws. 


I/O  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 


§  49.    The  Mahal  and  Village. 

Indeed  I  ought  to  explain  that,  though  for  convenience 
I  often  speak  of  the  Revenue  Settlement  of  villages,  and 
the  assessment  of  villages,  strictly  speaking  this  is  not 
correct.  The  lump  assessment  is  on  what  is  called 
in  revenue  language  the  'Mahal,'  or  lot  of  lands  held 
under  one  title.  This  may,  and  does  very  often,  coincide 
with  a  '  village ' ;  but  partitions  and  sales  will  always  tend 
to  make  it  less  so.  Supposing,  for  example,  three  villages 
come  to  be  owned  by  a  community  of  eight  sharers,  and 
they  completely  partition  their  estate :  eight  estates  or 
'  Mahals '  may  then  arise.  Sometimes  a  part  of  one  village 
is  a  separate  estate.  And  there  are  also  peculiar  customs 
of  allotment  of  shares,  by  which  the  sharers  in  a  large 
estate  of  several  villages  may  get  their  land,  not  in  com- 
pact lots,  but  some  fields  here  and  some  there  in  different 
villages.  In  time  these  may  form  separately  assessed 
'  Mahals.' 

When  the  partition  of  an  estate  results  in  compact  lots, 
the  estate  is  said,  in  revenue  language,  to  be  '  pattibat,' 
and  when  by  scattered  areas  '  khetbat.'  There  are  other 
local  terms,  but  these  are  the  common  ones. 


§  50.   Some  further  quotations  regarding  Villages. 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  appreciate  some  of  the 
standard  descriptions  of  the  'village  community'  which 
have  been  usually  copied  from  book  to  book  without  any 
question. 

Here  is  one,  which  has  become  almost  classical l : — 

'  The  village  communities  are  little  republics,  having  nearly 
everything  they  want  within  themselves,  and  almost  inde- 
pendent of  any  foreign  relations.  They  seem  to  last  when 

1  Sir  C.  T.,  afterwards  Lord  port  of  Select  Committee  of  H.  C. 
Metcalfe.  In  a  minute  of  7th  Nov.  '^1832),  cited  in  Elphinstone's  History 
1830,  No.  84,  in  the  App.  to  the  Re-  of  India,  sth  ed.  p.  68. 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL   VIEW   OF   THE   LAND-TENURE.          171 

nothing  else  lasts.  Dynasty  after  dynasty  tumbles  down  ; 
revolution  succeeds  to  revolution  ;  Hindu,  Pathan,  Mughal, 
Maratha,  Sikh,  English,  all  are  masters  in  turn  ;  but  the  village 
communities  remain  the  same.  In  times  of  trouble  they  arm 
and  fortify  themselves.  An  hostile  army  passes  through  the 
country;  the  village  communities  collect  their  cattle  within 
their  walls  and  let  the  enemy  pass  unprovoked.  If  plunder 
and  devastation  be  directed  against  themselves,  and  the  force 
employed  be  irresistible,  they  flee  to  friendly  villages  at  a  dis- 
tance ;  but  when  the  storm  has  passed  over  they  return  and 
resume  their  occupations.  If  a  country  remain  for  a  series  of 
years  the  scene  of  continued  pillage  and  massacre  so  that  the 
villages  cannot  be  inhabited,  the  scattered  villagers  nevertheless 
return  whenever  the  power  of  peaceable  possession  revives.  A 
generation  may  pass  away,  but  the  succeeding  generation  will 
return.  The  sons  will  take  the  places  of  their  fathers  ;  the 
same  site  for  the  village,  the  same  positions  for  their  houses, 
the  same  lands  will  be  re-occupied  by  the  descendants  of  those 
who  were  driven  out  when  the  village  was  depopulated  :  and 
it  is  not  a  trifling  matter  that  will  drive  them  out,  for  they  will 
often  maintain  their  post  through  times  of  disturbance  and 
convulsion,  and  acquire  strength  sufficient  to  resist  pillage  and 
oppression  with  success.  This  union  of  the  village  communities, 
each  one  forming  a  little  state  in  itself,  has,  I  conceive,  contri- 
buted more  than  any  other  cause  to  the  preservation  of  the 
people  of  India,  through  all  the  revolutions  and  changes  which 
they  have  suffered,  and  is  in  a  high  degree  conducive  to  their 
happiness  and  to  the  enjoyment  of  a  great  portion  of  freedom 
and  independence.' 

This  passage  does  not  define,  or  even  describe  what  the 
village  is:  it  states  certain  characteristics,  and  there  is,  of 
course,  a  considerable  amount  of  truth  in  it.  But  it  should 
be  remembered  that  there  is  quite  another  side  to  the  same 
picture,  or  rather  it  should  be  said  that  the  delineation  is 
only  true  under  certain  conditions.  The  circumstances 
of  the  country  necessitate  the  aggregation  of  cultivation 
in  groups,  and  often  encourage  the  fixing  of  a  central  and 
even  defensible  site  for  residence.  But  as  to  'little  re- 
publics,'— in  a  large  number  of  villages,  in  most  provinces, 
and  at  one  time  or  another,  individual  headmen  and  farmers 


172  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

of  the  revenue  have  ruled  with  almost  undisputed  power l. 
As  to  the  villages  being  unchangeable,  their  constitution 
and  form  has  shown  a  progressive  tendency  to  decay,  and 
if  it  had  not  been  for  modern  land-revenue  systems  trying 
to  keep  it  together,  it  may  well  be  doubted  whether  it 
would  have  survived  at  all.  No  doubt  there  are  cases 
in  which  villages  have  been  re-established  by  the  de- 
scendants of  a  former  body  driven  out  by  disaster ;  cases 
have  been  recorded,  for  instance,  in  Central  India,  where 
certain  families  who  have  held  particular  lands  in  virtue 
of  hereditary  office,  and  being  strongly  attached  to  the 
dignities  therewith  associated,  have  had  a  strong  motive 
to  return,  as  well  as,  in  the  sentiment  of  the  people,  a 
strong  claim  to  do  so ;  but  the  invitation  of  the  ruler 
has  much  to  do  with  the  return :  he  desires  to  re-establish 
deserted  estates  for  the  sake  of  his  revenue  ;  and  old  land- 
holders are  the  best ;  while  an  old  headman  family  has  an 
obvious  capacity  for  inducing  cultivators  to  restore  the 
village 2.  When  villages  are  refounded,  it  is  however  j  ust 
as  often  by  totally  different  people. 

And  let  us  take  another  feature  in  the  account  quoted. 
Mughals  and  Sikhs,  we  are  told,  are  masters  in  turn,  but  the 
village  remains  the  same.  Does  it  1  The  village  changes 
as  much  as,  in  the  nature  of  things,  a  group  of  lands  or 
an  aggregate  of  houses,  can  change.  Let  us  picture  to 
ourselves  an  easily  recognizable  case.  At  first  the  village 
was  a  settlement  founded  in  the  virgin  waste.  Here  a 
leader  or  headman  started  and  directed  the  cultivation ;  each 
cultivator  brought  his  own  plough  and  oxen,  and  felt  that 
the  plot  he  cleared  would  be  his  own  ;  he  had  no  connection 
with  other  holdings  save  that  he  obeyed  the  common 
headman,  availed  himself  of  the  village  artisan's  services, 
and  had  to  share  his  grain-heap  with  them  and  with 

1  See  for  example  Mr.   (now  Sir  which  broke  up  the  village,  the  de- 
C.)  Crosthwaite's  remarks  on  certain  struction  was  not  complete,  but  a 
villages  in  the  Settlement  Report  of  the  nucleus  was  left  behind.    John  Law- 
Etdwd    district    (chapter    on   North-  rence,  when  Collector  of  the  Sirsa 
West  Provinces  Tenures).  district,  noted  villages  there  as  ex- 

2  And  it  is  sometimes  the  case  hibiting  this  characteristic, 
that   when   the    disaster    occurred 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL    VIEW   OF   THE    LAND-TEXURE.         173 

the  Raja,  and  had  to  unite  with  his  fellows  whenever 
common  defence  was  necessary.  Then  let  us  suppose  the 
Raja's  cousin  receives  a  grant  of  the  village  and  becomes 
landlord,  taking  most  of  the  waste  to  himself;  as  his 
family  multiplies,  they  form  a  joint  body  and  soon  get 
the  lion's  share  of  the  land,  the  old  'clearers'  becoming 
tenants.  Next,  the  landlord  family  quarrel,  or  otherwise 
determine  to  divide  the  land ;  in  this  state  the  village  will 
be  called  in  the  revenue  books  a  pattiddri  village.  Next, 
the  proprietors  get  into  debt,  and  sell  their  shares. 
Strangers  thus  get  in,  and  a  new  order  of  things  com- 
mences ;  for  the  purchasers  are  very  likely  of  a  non- 
agricultural  caste  and  must  employ  tenants  :  some  perhaps 
prefer  the  old  landowners,  others  take  new  men  who  offer 
better  terms.  The  remnants  of  both  the  older  family  groups 
run  a  good  chance  of  going  to  the  wall  altogether.  Lastly, 
the  body  comes  under  early  English  revenue-management, 
before  it  had  become  adapted  to  the  true  requirements  of 
the  case ;  the  village  once  more  changes  hands.  It  is  now 
sold  for  arrears  of  revenue,  and  passes  with  a  clear  title 
into  the  hands  of  an  auction-purchaser,  or  falls  under  the 
tender  mercies  of  a  revenue-farmer  who  drives  half  the 
already  heterogeneous  population  out,  to  make  room  for 
good  Kurmi,  or  Saini,  or  Arain  cultivators  (according  to 
the  province  we  are  thinking  of),  in  order  that  he  may 
clear  off  the  balance  and  fulfil  his  object  of  making  a  profit 
for  himself.  And  this  is  the  village  that  never  changes 
while  dynasties  tumble  down,  &c. ! 

Of  course  there  is  a  true  side  to  the  picture  ;  for  all 
these  changes  do  not  alter  the  facts  of  situation:  the 
methods  of  cultivation  are  the  same,  the  fields  remain- 
ed superest  ager ;  the  customs  of  ploughing  and  of  resting, 
the  dealings  with  the  money-lender,  the  daily  gossip  of  the 
women  drawing  water  at  the  well,  or  sitting  over  their 
cotton  spinning  ;  these  and  all  other  features  of  village  life 
remote  from  the  rumours  of  the  world,  will  continue,  no 
matter  who  is  managing  the  estate.  But  we  must  not 
attempt  to  make  a  general  picture  of  the  '  Indian  village ' 


I  74  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  IV. 

\yy  either  taking  a  partial  and  one-sided  view  of  things, 
or  by  throwing  together  a  variety  of  dissimilar  facts  till  we 
get  a  sort  of  undistinguishable  mixture  of  them  all.  Still 
less  must  we  make  a  hasty  generalization  from  a  few  im- 
perfectly understood  facts,  and  complacently  adapt  them  to 
the  latest  theory  (however  admissible  in  itself)  of  ancient 
institutions  or  the  development  of  ideas  of  property. 

There  are  distinct  varieties  of  villages  in  the  different 
countries  of  India,  and  they  are  none  of  them  (that  I  know 
of)  at  all  like  the  Russian  mir,  or  the  Sclavonian  house- 
community  or  the  Swiss  allmend  or  common  holding,  in 
the  concrete.  They  have,  or  had,  some  features l  which 
can  be  traced  back,  in  all  probability,  to  those  elements  in 
early  tribal  life  which  are  common  to  all  races.  But  the 
identity  of  some  forms  of  Indian  village  with  the  '  Mark '  or 
the  tribal  holdings  in  Ireland,  is  only  'identity'  in  the 
sense  in  which  the  German,  Greek,  Lithuanian  and  Latin 
tongues  could  be  called  '  identical '  with  Sanskrit  or  Zand. 


§  51.   Features  of  the  Joint  Village  misapplied. 

One  more  instance  must  be  given  of  the  '  generalized ' 
method  of  disposing  of  the  features  of  Indian  villages. 
This  will  now  be  intelligible,  because  I  have  explained 
the  revenue  terms  applied  to  the  landlord  village  of 
Northern  India  and  the  Panjab — indicating  that  the  village 
is  enjoyed  jointly,  or  has  been  wholly  or  partially  divided 
for  separate  enjoyment.  It  is  an  extract  from  a  valuable 

1  And  I  desire  not  to  underrate  Mr.  F.  Seebohm's  English  Village  Com- 

these  facts.    In  the  frontier  districts  munity    (London,    1884,    3rd    ed. ). 

of  the  Panjab,  when  the  conquering  Some    of   the   village    customs    of 

tribes    allotted    the    country    into  measuring  and  dividing  land,  the 

'  ilaqas,'    and    then    into    villages,  '  bulks,'  the  '  shots,'  the  '  lynches,' 

Kandis,  &c. ,  we  have  many  features  the  holdings  made  up  of  scattered 

which   recall    the   '  mark '   or   the  strips    (though   the   reason   is   not 

Anglo-Saxon 'vill':  and  the  reader  the  same),  pp.  7, 113,  the 'loenland'- 

of  Mr.  Joshua  Williams'  Lectures  on  as    compared   with   the    Raja's   or 

Rights  of   Common   (London,    1880),  chiefs   grant    (p.  169), — these    and 

especially  lectures  4, 5,  and  6,  might  many    others     suggest    interesting 

think  he  was  reading  a  North  Panj-  points  of  comparison, 
ab  Settlement  Report ;  and  so  with 


CHAP.  IV.]     GENERAL  VIEW   OF    THE    LAND-TENURE.          175 

standard  text- book  known  to  all  Indian  lawyers  as  Mayne's 
Hindu  Law  and  Usage. 

Thus  Mr.  Mayne  writes  l : — 

'  The  village  system  .  .  .  presents  three  marked  phases,  which 
exactly  correspond  to  the  changes  in  an  undivided  family. 
The  closest  form  of  union  is  that  which  is  known  as  the 
"  Communal  Zaminddri  village."  Under  this  system  "  the  land 
is  so  held  that  all  the  village  co-sharers  have  each  their  propor- 
tionate share  in  it  as  common  property  without  any  possession 
of  or  title  to  distinct  portions  of  it ;  and  the  measure  of  each 
proprietor's  interest  is  his  share  as  fixed  by  the  customary  law 
of  inheritance.  The  rents  paid  by  the  cultivators  are  thrown 
into  a  common  stock  with  all  other  profits  from  the  village 
lands,  and  after  deduction  of  the  expenses,  the  balance  is 
divided  among  the  proprietors  according  to  their  shares." 
(Quoted  from  Boulnois  and  Kattigan's  Punjab  Customs,  1876.) 
This  corresponds  to  the  undivided  family  in  its  purest  state. 
The  second  stage  is  called  the  pattiddri  village.  In  it  the 
holdings  are  all  in  severalty,  and  each  sharer  manages  his  own 
portion  of  land.  But  the  extent  of  the  share  is  determined  by 
ancestral  right,  and  is  capable  of  being  modified  from  time  to 
time  upon  this  principle.' 

The  third  and  final  stage  is  known  as  the  bhdidchdrd  village. 
It  agrees  with  the  pattiddri  form  inasmuch  as  each  owner  holds 
his  share  in  severalty.  But  it  differs  from  it  inasmuch  as  the 
extent  of  the  holding  is  strictly  defined  [not  at  all  strictly,  very 
often  there  is  a  strong  trace  of  the  ancestral  scheme  besides]  by 
the  amount  actually  held  in  possession.' 

This  again  reads  convincingly  ;  but  if  we  hold  the  writer 
to  the  strict  sense  of  the  vernacular  terms  used,  it  would 
not  be  far  wrong  if  we  were  to  say  that  the  real  process  of 
change  or  development  is  almost  exactly  the  reverse  of  that 
described.  If  we  look  to  the  order  of  village  development 

1  Hindu  Law  and  Usage  (Higgin-  lord  and  from  him  a  joint- body  of 

botham,   Madras)   4th    ed.    §    200.  descendants,  is  found,  and  if  allow- 

Of  course  the  whole  extract  would  ance  is  made  for  a  very  inaccurate 

lose  some  of  its  general  inapplica-  (but   perhaps   popularized)    use   of 

bility  if  by  '  the  village  system '  we  the  terms  pattiddri  and  bhdidchdrd  ; 

understand,  the  particular  form  of  but   the   author  suggests   no    such 

village  in  which  first  a  single  land-  restriction. 


1 76  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

on  the  basis  of  such  evidence  as  actually  exists,  we  find  a 
large  number  in  which  an  allotment  (liable,  in  certain 
places,  to  be  periodically  revised)  was  made  from  the  very 
first ;  not  necessarily  on  the  principle  of  ancestral  shares,  but 
sometimes  on  this  plan,  sometimes  on  one  totally  distinct, 
according  to  tribal  sentiment.  We  also  find  other  villages 
over  which  we  may  suppose  one  chief  or  head  of  a  family 
originally  ruled,  and  his  family  at  some  very  remote  period 
divided  it  on  ancestral  shares. 

It  is  quite  an  unnecessary  abuse  of  terms  to  represent 
the  '  bhaiachara '  as  a  stage  beyond  '  pattidari.'  As  far  as 
'  bhaidchdra '  is  (incorrectly)  used  to  indicate  villages 
where  the  shares  have  been  lost,  it  is  a  matter  of  taste 
whether  we  call  it  a  '  stage '  of  any  process  whatever.  To 
my  mind  the  pattidari  is  just  as  complete  an  individual- 
ization  of  holding  as  that  which  is  maintained  when  the 
theory  which  governed  the  extent  of  the  separate  lot  is 
forgotten.  But,  considering  that  '  bhaiachara '  (and  that 
correctly)  also  indicates  a  special  plan  or  method  of  division 
existing  alongside  of  the  pattidari l,  it  is  positively  incorrect 
to  say  that  it  is  a  stage  beyond  pattidari  in  a  process  of 
change  or  development.  Once  more ;  if  '  bhaiachard '  is 
given  its  widest  sense,  it  includes  many  villages  in  which,  as 
far  as  we  know,  there  never  was  any  joint  holding  at  all.  In 
fact,  if  we  put  aside  the  special  case  of  the  Panjab  frontier 
and  other  immigrant  tribal  family  settlements,  it  would  be 
quite  as  correct  (for  a  general  paragraph)  to  say,  that  the 
first  stage  is  when  a  number  of  colonists  settle  together, 
each  working  at  his  own  holding  and  claiming  it  in  severalty, 
the  only  bond  of  union  being  that  of  locality  and  a  common 
government ;  that  in  the  next  stage  a  landlord  arises — not 
merely  a  distant  ruler,  but — a  claimant  to  the  actual  vil- 
lage acres,  and  that  he  is  succeeded  by  a  body  of  descendants 
who  jointly  enjoy  the  estate  for  a  time ;  that  they  then 
divide  almost  always  on  ancestral  shares  ;  and  that,  lastly, 
the  strict  shares  are  lost  or  modified  by  circumstances. 

1  And  the   co-existence   of  these       value  and  interest,  and  one  not  to 
diverse   methods   of  allotment   arid       be  obscured  or  left  out  of  count, 
several  enjoyment,  is  of  exceeding 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  177 

And  it  would  be  proper  to  add,  that  in  many  cases 
villages  are  known  where,  though  the  feeling  of  joint  right 
to  an  entire  area  was  strongly  recognized,  some  special 
method  of  equal  allotment  was  always  and  from  the  first 
practised,  while  a  portion  of  the  area  might  or  might  not 
remain  undivided,  either  for  common  grazing,  or  to  support 
a  tenantry,  or  from  some  other  motive. 


§  52.  Forms  of  Village  in  the  different  Provinces. 

It  will  probably  be  of  use  to  the  student  if  I  now  give 
a  list  of  the  provinces  treated  of  in  this  book,  and  state 
briefly  and  in  abstract,  what  sort  of  '  village '  is  (chiefly) 
to  be  found  in  each. 

BENGAL.  In  what  is  called  '  Bengal  proper,'  the  village 
tenure  is  of  comparatively  little  importance  :  it  has  become 
overshadowed  by  the  tenure  of  great  landlords.  In  the 
Bihar  districts,  however,  there  are  clearer  traces  of  villages 
— of  the  landlord  type — and  the  headmen  have  often  be- 
come petty  '  Zamlndars.'  In  East  Bengal  there  are  peculiar 
tenures,  the  result  of  settlements  in  the  jungle  ;  and  there 
are  special  survivals  of  peculiar  villages  in  the  Santal 
parganas,  Chutiya  Nagpur,  &c.  Shifting  cultivation  in 
the  hill  tracts  is  also  common. 

ASSAM.  In  the  Sylhet  and  Cachar  districts  there  are 
some  peculiar  tenures.  In  the  Assam  valley  the  villages 
are  peculiar  and  not  of  the  landlord  type,  but  practically 
raiyativdri.  There  is  much  '  Jum '  or  shifting  cultivation 
in  the  hills  of  Central,  Northern,  and  Southern  Assam. 

NORTH-WEST  PROVINCES.  Mostly  joint  villages  ;  many 
formed  by  families  of  revenue-farmers,  &c.,  who  acquired 
the  landlord  right  at  the  beginning  of  the  century.  Many 
were  really  raiyatwdri  villages,  but  have  become  '  bhai- 
achara '  under  our  system. 

OUDH.  Many  villages  of  the  old  (raiyativdri]  type  ;  in 
many,  landlord  claims  have  grown  up  by  the  grant  of 
Rajas,  or  by  the  dismemberment  of  old  estates  of  chiefs,  &c. 

VOL.  i.  N 


1 78  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

But  over  all,  the  Taluqdar  landlords  have  grown  up  :  and 
they  have  reduced  the  villages  to  a  subordinate  position. 

THE  PANJAB.  In  the  Frontier  districts  strong  landlord 
villages  of  immigrant  conquering  tribes.  In  the  Central 
districts,  landlord  villages,  some  of  immigrant  tribes,  some 
of  associated  bodies  of  settlers,  some  resulting  from  the 
multiplication  of  families  of  single  or  associated  adventurers. 
In  the  hill  districts  real  villages  do  not  exist,  and  so  in 
the  Southern  River  districts ;  the  now  recognized  village 
forms  are  there  the  result  of  Settlement  arrangements. 

AJMER.  Joint  villages,  the  result  of  our  Settlement. 
Originally  the  old  Hindu  organization  was  complete. 

THE  CENTRAL  PROVINCES.  The  villages  would  be,  as 
a  rule,  of  the  raiyatwdri  type,  but  Government  conferred  a 
landlord  right  on  heads  of  villages,  so  that  their  descendants 
form  landlord  communities,  but  with  rights  much  limited 
by  legal  reservation  of  rights  to  the  old  cultivators. 

A  considerable  area  is  held  by  larger  estate  holders, 
who  are  the  surviving  representatives  of  the  old  Gond 
chiefs  of  the  Dravidian-Hindu  era. 

BOMBAY.  Mostly  raiyatwdri  villages : — a  few  survivals 
of  landlord  (shared)  villages  in  Guzarat.  In  the  coast 
(Konkan)  districts  a  peculiar  landlord  tenure  of  '  Khots ' 
over  groups  of  villages,  will  be  found. 

MADRAS.  Mostly  raiyatwdri  villages.  Traces  of  land- 
lord villages  (mirasi),  now  only  surviving  in  a  few  special 
privileges  or  adaptations  under  the  Raiyatwarf  Settlement 
system.  In  Malabar  and  South  Kanara  no  villages  properly 
so  called,  and  special  tenures.  So  in  the  Wainad  division 
of  Malabar,  and  in  the  Nilgin  hills. 

COOEG.     No  villages  properly  so  called,  special  tenures. 
BURMA.     Villages   raiyatwdri    in    principle,   but  of  a 
special  type. 


CHAP.  IV.]    GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENUKE.  I  79 


SECTION  III.  LAND-TENURES  ARISING  OUT  OF  OFFICIAL 
POSITIONS  OR  LAND-REVENUE  ARRANGEMENTS  AND 
STATE  GRANTS  OF  THE  REVENUE. 

§  i .  Early  organization  of  territory  for  Revenue  purposes. 

When  the  earliest  regular  kingdoms  that  we  have  any 
evidence  of,  were  established — whether  Dravidian,  or  Aryan, 
or  of  other  immigrant  tribes — there  was  always  some  organ- 
ization of  the  territory,  which  was  especially  adopted  with 
a  view  to  ensuring  the  realization  of  the  revenue.  And 
under  every  form  of  government  with  which  we  are  ac- 
quainted, a  revenue  from  land  was  the  chief  thing. 

The  village  grouping  of  cultivators  or  colonizers,  which 
we  have  just  considered  in  detail,  being  the  feature  of  the 
agricultural  constitution  of  society,  naturally  we  find  a 
State-recognized  headman  in  each  village  aided  by  an 
accountant ;  not  unnaturally  too,  we  find  the  village  go- 
vernment repeated  in  form  but  over  a  wider  area,  till  we 
come  to  the  governor  or  chief-regnant  himself.  First  above 
the  headman  of  a  single  village,  we  find  an  officer  over  a 
small  group  of  villages, called  a  naik  or  nayak :  this  prob- 
ably descended  to  the  Muhammadan  government  as  the 
'  tappa.'  A  larger  group  (Col.  Sykes  speaks  of  its  contain- 
ing eighty-four  villages J)  was  the  charge  of  a  '  desmukh.' 
This  also  was  adopted  by  the  Muhammadans,  and  the 
territorial  division  is  still  well  known  under  the  familiar 
revenue  name  of  '  pargana  '  (pergunnah) 2,  or  taluka.  Over 

1  In    his    paper    above    quoted.  cording  to  their  size)  of  tribes.     A 

Traces   of  '  Chaurassis,'   or   groups  long  account  of  Chaurassis  will  be 

of  eighty-four  villages  are  found  in  found  in  Beanies'  Elliott's  Glossary, 

various  parts,  also  of  '  bealisi '  and  s.  v.  Chaurassi. 

'  chaubisi '   ( forty-two  and  twenty-  2  The  pargana  is  in  Upper  India 

one,  the  half  and  quarter  charge  re-  almost   everywhere    preserved.     It 

spectively).    These  may  have  been  is  too  small  for  our  administrative 

the   extent   of    major    and    minor  system    and    has    therefore    given 

chiefs'   estates,  or  the  jurisdiction  way  to  the  '  tahsil ' — a  subdivision 

of    officers.      I     have     seen     sug-  of  a  district.     The  ta'lluqa  (or  in 

gestions    however    that    they  may  Hindi  form  Taluka)  division  is  still 

represent   the   areas  conquered   or  in  use  in  Bombay  and  Madras, 
occupied  by  clans  and  sections  (ac- 

N    2 


1 80  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

this  area  there  was  necessarily  also  an  accountant  called '  deV 
pandya.'  The  still  larger,  or  what  we  should  call  '  district' 
charge,  was  not  so  permanent,  nor  has  it  survived  so  well. 
Our  predecessors  do  not  seem  to  have  very  much  cared  for 
a  charge  intermediate  between  the  small  pargana  and  the 
province  of  the  Governor.  But  in  some  places,  and  at  some 
time  or  other,  there  certainly  existed  such  charges ;  and  the 
title  '  Sirdesmukh '  implies  a  supervision  of  several  des- 
muJchs  or  pargana  officers.  This  administrative  organization 
is  more  fully  described  in  the  next  chapter ;  I  only  state 
here  what  is  necessary  with  a  view  to  our  immediate 
purpose. 

§  2.    The  '  Watan '  lands. 

One  of  the  most  ancient  tenures,  directly  arising  out  of 
this  series  of  official  grades,  is  the  service-tenure,  called 
'  Watan '  in  Central  India.  From  the  fact  of  its  localization 
in  the  very  home  of  the  old  Dravidian  (Gond,  &c.)  king- 
doms, I  am  inclined  to  suggest  that  it  is  a  direct  survival 
of  that  system,  and  is  therefore  of  great  interest. 

The  Dravidian  scheme  of  revenue  seems  to  have  in- 
cluded (if  it  did  not  originally  confine  itself  to)  the  plan  of 
making  allotments  of  land  as  royal  farms,  for  the  payment  of 
officers,  and  even  for  the  more  petty  remuneration  of  village 
artisans,  and  for  the  priests.  The  produce  of  these  lands 
went  wholly  to  the  king  or  the  official  as  the  case  might 
be ;  while  special  arrangements  were  often  made  for  their 
cultivation.  I  am  not  aware  that  any  local  name  for  this 
tenure  has  survived,  a  fact  which  points  to  a  remote 
antiquity,  and  perhaps  to  some  degree  of  localization.  The 
name  '  watan,'  now  applied  to  it,  is  Arabic,  and  is  trace- 
able to  the  Muhammadan  kings  of  the  Dakhan,  before  their 
overthrow  by  the  Mughal  empire  of  Delhi.  We  know  that 
these  kings  were  wisely  careful  of  indigenous  institutions, 
and  they  evidently  preserved  the  '  ex-officio '  holding  and 
gave  it  a  name.  It  comprised  not  only  the  holding 
of  lands,  but  also  a  right  to  the  '  man  pan,'  i.  e.  various 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE. 


ISI 


dignities,  and  precedence 1  on  official  or  public  occasions. 
In  Central  India,  where  this  institution  has  long  survived, 
the  dignity  of  Patel  (headman),  or  of  Pandya  (accountant) 
with  the  'watan'  attached,  is  such,  or  perhaps  the  security 
of  the  tenure  is  regarded  as  so  complete,  that  rights  in  the 
form  of  '  watan '  are  eagerly  sought  after,  and  what  is  more, 
the  pettiest  '  watan '  originally  attached  to  some  menial 
office  is  bought  up  and  held  by  great  men 2. 

The  watan,  besides  being  heritable,  is  also  saleable; 
moreover,  as  the  whole  family  of  the  hereditary  officer 
succeeds  jointly,  all  hold  it  and  may  afterwards  divide  it. 

We  may  find  traces  of  the  '  watan/  or  something  analo- 
gous to  it,  elsewhere ;  but  I  must  not  give  more  space  to  a 
tenure  which  is  now  extremely  localized  in  Nimar,  Central 
India  and  parts  of  Bombay 3. 


1  Such  as  the  Patel  being  entitled 
to  walk  first  on  certain  ceremonial 
occasions  ;  being  the  first  to  throw 
the  sacred  cake  into  the  fire  at  the 
Huli  festival ;  having  the  right  to 
have  his  cow's  horns  first  gilded  on 
a  certain  festival,  and  so  forth. 
Col.  Sykes  gives  a  most  curious 
account  of  these  as  they  appeared 
on  the  occasion  of  a  settlement  (by 
a  '  panch '  or  arbitrator)  of  a  dis- 
pute regarding  a  Bombay  '  patelgi ' 
or  headmanship,  in  which  certain 
shares  had  been  sold,  so  that  not 
only  the  land  of  the  watan  had  to 
be  divided  between  the  claimants, 
but  also  the  different  '  precedences ' 
and  dignities.  It  was  settled  by 
allowing  one  claimant  to  be  first 
in  a  certain  number  of  ceremonial 
occasions,  and  the  other  at  a  number 
of  others;  the  'panch'  trying  to 
make  the  list  of  '  occasions  '  as  de- 
sirable to  each  as  possible,  so  that 
the  rank  might  be  equal.  I  have 
unfortunately  mislaid  my  reference. 
The  paper  I  allude  to  is  in  the 
Asiatic  Soc.  Journal,  but  later  than 
vol.  ii. 

a  In  the  Berdr  Gazetteer  Mr. 
(now  Sir  A.)  Lyall  notices  how  in 
Western  Central  India  the  '  watan  ' 
is  more  prized  than  anything  else. 
Berar  is  a  purely  Dravidian  country 
— part  of  the  ancient  Gondwana. 
Speaking  of  the  Sindkher  chief  (in 


the  south-west  corner  of  Berar),  he 
tells  us  that  the  family  had  held 
large  jagir  estates  in  the  sixteenth 
century.  In  Upper  India  he  would 
on  this  basis  have  developed  to  a 
great  '  zamindar '  or '  taluqdar ' ;  but 
in  the  Dakhan  he  was  content  to 
be  the  'de?-mukh'  of  a  dozen  par- 
ganas,  the  '  patel '  of  fifty  villages, 
and  in  his  own  town  of  Sindkher  the 
pluralist  holder  of  all  the  grants 
attached  to  menial  services —wash- 
ing, shaving,  sweeping.  &c.  The 
family  had  let  go  its  jagirs,  yet  had 
seized  every  sort  of  '  watan '  on 
which  it  could  lay  hands  (p.  101 ). 
Sir  J.  Malcolm  (ii.  p.  16)  writes  : 
'  The  rights  of  the  native  heredi- 
tary officers  of  a  village  are  much 
respected  in  Central  India ;  and 
never  did  a  country  afford  such 
proofs  of  the  imperishable  nature 
of  this  admirable  institution.  After 
the  Pindari  war  every  encourage- 
ment was  held  out  for  the  inhabit- 
ants to  return.  ...  In  several  dis- 
tricts, particularly  those  near  the 
Narbada,  many  of  the  villages  had 
been  waste  for  more  than  thirty 
years.  .  .  .  Infant  Potails  (Patel  i 
the  second  and  third  in  descent 
from  the  emigrator,  were  in  many 
cases  carried  at  the  head  of  their 
parties.' 

3  In  the  Central  Provinces  we  do 
not  find  it  till  we  come  to  Nimar, 


1 82  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

§  3.    General  tendency  of  Hindu  system. 

I  am  not  aware  that  we  can  fairly  attribute  any  other 
existing  tenures  to  the  Hindu  State  organization,  or  to  the 
development  of  the  position  of  its  land  officers,  so  long  as 
the  system  remained  in  its  pristine  vigour.  Indeed,  in 
some  parts,  as  in  the  Native  States  of  Rajputana  and  in 
the  Hill  States  of  the  Himalaya,  the  old  organization  sur- 
vives to  this  day,  and  though  the  present  Rajas  and  subor- 
dinate chiefs,  called  Rana,  Thakur,  &c.,  claim  to  be  the 
owners  of  the  soil,  this  is  a  much  later  claim,  which  all 
the  more  recent  Oriental  governments  put  forward.  Even 
this  is  perhaps  more  a  theoretical  than  a  practical  claim ; 
except  in  so  far  as  it  results  in  the  State  owning  (and 
drawing  profit  from)  all  waste  land  not  held  or  cultivated 
by  any  one,  and  securing  a  certain  fee  on  the  rare  occasions 
of  a  transfer  of  land.  Otherwise  there  has  been  no  great 
tendency  to  modify  the  tenures.  The  traveller  in  the  hills 
can  still  see  the  villagers  paying  revenue  in  an  actual  grain- 
share,  and  notice  in  the  larger  villages  the  Raja's  '  kothi,'  a 
great  square  building  which  forms  a  local  head -quarters. 
Here  the  grain  from  the  neighbourhood  is  stored,  and  here 
too  (when  needed)  the  '  kardar '  or  other  local  official  holds 
a  rude  kind  of  court  for  disposal  of  public  business. 

The  introduction  of  Hindu  officials  when  they  came  as 
foreigners,  in  some  of  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  States  and  in 
Orissa,  produced  some  confusion,  and  originated  landlord 
tenures  in  the  end ;  but  it  would  be  hardly  correct  to  refer 
to  these  cases  as  directly  illustrating  tenures  arising  out 
of  revenue  administrative  arrangements. 

§  4.  The  Muhammadan  Empire. — At  first  changes  are 

slight. 

The  first  influence  on  tenures  caused  by  the  accession  to 
power  of  the  Mughals,  was  by  their  reducing  or  conquering 

which   had   been    under  the   Mu-      that  the  Marathas  destroyed  it  in 
hammadan  rule.    May  it  have  been       Nagpur  ? 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  183 

the  Rajas  of  the  small  states  which  then  were  the  great 
feature  of  the  country.  As  we  shall  state  presently,  the 
treatment  of  these  States  was  a  noteworthy  feature  in  the 
Mughal  rule.  They  conquered  the  Rajas,  but  only  took 
from  them  the  land-revenue,  leaving  the  local  taxes,  and 
customs  duties,  and  the  administration  of  justice,  as  they 
were  before  —  these  latter  being  the  very  attributes  of 
sovereignty  which  a  modern  government  would  have 
thought  it  its  first  duty  to  undertake  and  regulate. 

But  in  fact  the  Mughals  closely  conformed  to  the  old 
Hindu  system.  Their  own  ideas  of  right  over  conquered 
peoples,  and  of  taking  '  Khiraj '  or  tribute  and  capitation 
tax  from  them,  were  modified,  or  perhaps  naturally  fell 
in  with  the  system  of  the  land- re  venue  payment  already 
in  force  1.  Names  were  changed,  but  the  administrative 
divisions  of  the  country,  and  the  official  charges,  were  vir- 
tually retained. 

§  5.    Changes  begin  with  the  decay  of  the  Empire. 

Except  then  for  the  change  that  was  inaugurated  (and 
that  without  intention  or  foreseeing  the  result)  by  reducing 
the  Rajas,  the  influence  of  the  Muhammadan  rule  on  tenures, 
may  be  said  to  have  been  chiefly  felt  in  the  changes  that 
occurred  in  revenue-management,  when  the  empire  fell  into 
decay.  Perhaps  I  ought  not  to  say  this  without  remem- 
bering also  the  influence  of  the  change  made  when  a  money- 
revenue  was  substituted  for  a  grain-share  ;  and  that  was  not 
in  the  decline  of  Empire,  but  when  it  was  at  its  best.  During 
the  latter  half  of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  Emperor  Akbar 
made  a  revenue-settlement,  under  which  (at  first  optionally) 
a  money-payment  was  substituted  for  the  grain-share.  No 
doubt  this  was  the  beginning  of  a  great  change  ;  still  it  was 
one  which  only  indirectly  affected  land-tenures.  It  pre- 

1  The   'Khiraj'   (vide  chapter  on  or  other  of  the  Mughal  emperors 

the  Land-Revenue  System)  naturally  in  a  fit  of  zeal,  attempted  to  impose 

became  the  land-revenue.    As  to  the  it  on  the  Hindus,  and  were  much 

'  jaziya '  or  capitation  tax,  we  only  hated  in  consequence, 
occasionally  hear  of  it,  when  one 


1 84  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.      [CHAP.  iv. 

pared  the  way  for  what  followed,  and  for  gradual  changes 
in  the  relation  of  landlord  and  tenant,  and  many  other 
modern  features  of  land-tenure.  The  land-tenures  were  really 
directly  affected  when  the  Mughal  government  began  to 
decline.  Then  it  was  that  viceroys  like  those  of  Oudh, 
Bengal,  and  the  Dakhan  (Hyderabad)  threw  off  their  alle- 
giance and  became  independent  kings.  Then  too  it  was  that 
the  extravagant  claims  of  the  ruler  to  be  universal  owner 
of  land  were  first  heard. 

The  independent  kingdoms  did  not  have  a  very  prosperous 
course.  Before  long,  decay  and  corruption  began  to  invade 
every  department  of  the  State.  Under  such  a  state  of 
things  honesty  was  hardly  to  be  looked  for  in  the  local 
revenue  collectors  ;  and  the  land-revenue  fell  off.  No  doubt 
the  Central  government — as  from  time  to  time  it  fell  into 
the  hands  of  a  more  vigorous  ruler — made  desperate  efforts 
to  reassert  a  proper  control  over  the  district  collectors,  but 
in  vain.  The  device,  to  save  trouble  and  secure  at  least 
a  certain  revenue,  was  to  employ  local  agents  over  greater 
or  less  areas  of  country,  and  to  contract  for  the  revenues  of 
those  areas.  At  first  such  agents  were  carefully  appointed, 
and  with  much  form  ;  lists  were  made  out  of  the  villages  in 
their  charge  ;  and  they  were  bound  to  account  for  all  they 
collected ;  except  that  they  were  allowed  certain  lands 
revenue-free,  certain  items  might  be  deducted  for  special 
charges  (as  office  expenses,  alms,  and  police),  and  a  certain 
share,  usually  one-tenth  of  the  total  revenue,  as  their  own 
remuneration — denominated  nankar,  that  whereby  they 
made  (kar)  their  bread  (nan). 

But  as  time  went  on,  these  agents  were  less  and  less  con- 
trolled ;  and  they  soon  became  mere  contractors  for  fixed 
total  sums ;  and  the  local  officers  had  no  power  whatever 
over  them,  and  finally  disappeared  before  them.  No  one 
in  fact  knew  (or  cared)  what  was  actually  wrung  out  of  the 
villages,  so  long  as  the  contract  sum  was  paid  into  the 
treasury.  Nor  was  this  sum  a  fixed  one.  Whether  or  not 
the  strict  ideal  of  Hindu  or  Muhammadan  law  was  that  the 
Revenue  Settlement,  once  made,  ought  to  be  unalterable,  it 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  185 

is  quite  certain  that  in  practice  it  never  was  so  ;  but  instead 
of  a  careful  re-survey  of  extended  cultivation  and  a  re- 
valuation of  lands,  the  rough  expedient  was  adopted  of 
adding  '  cesses  '  (abwab)  to  the  sum  demanded  from  the 
agents,  and  so  raising  the  total.  These  cesses  were  called  by 
various  names  indicating  the  pretext  under  which  they 
were  levied  l.  The  agents  of  course  had  in  their  turn,  to 
make  good  the  additional  demand  from  the  villages,  and 
took  the  opportunity  of  adding  a  number  of  further  cesses 
for  their  private  benefit,  on  the  strength  of  the  example 
thus  set  them. 

It  should  not  be  supposed,  however,  that  this  system  of 
farming  the  land-revenue  was  altogether,  or  in  all  cases, 
due  to  the  decay  of  the  Government  system.  There  is 
one  important  fact  to  be  considered.  The  Muhammadan 
government  succeeded  by  conquest  to  a  number  of  Hindu 
states,  such  as  I  have  described,  where  Rajas  and  minor 
chiefs  already  were  receiving  the  revenue  (grain-share) 
and  governing  the  country.  These  Rajas  in  some  cases 
had  been  slain  in  battle  ;  in  others  had  fled  to  the  hills 
and  there  established  new  estates  in  the  comparative 
safety  of  the  distant  and  unoccupied  country.  In  other 
cases  their  domains  broke  up,  and  the  members  of  the 
ruling  families  seized  on  particular  villages  and  became 
landlords,  submitting  to  pay  revenue  to  the  Muhammadan 
treasury.  But  a  number  of  the  old  chiefs,  in  certain 
provinces  at  any  rate,  though  not  able  to  hold  their 
own,  were  quite  strong  enough  to  give  trouble,  and  to 
reappear  and  head  a  rebellion  on  the  appearance  of  the  least 
opportunity.  Hence  it  was  matter  of  policy  to  conciliate 
them  by  giving  titles,  &c.,  and  still  more  by  leaving  them 
in  all  their  dignity,  and  with  the  power  of  administering 
justice  locally,  provided  they  would  consent  to  pass  on  a 
large  share  of  the  land-revenue  they  collected,  to  the  Imperial 
treasury.  Such  local  magnates  were  well  acquainted  with 
the  resources  of  the  country,  and  had  often  a  strong  quasi- 
feudal  hold  on  the  people.  True  they  would  not  like 

1  For  details  the  chapter  on  Bengal  tenures  must  be  referred  to. 


1 86  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

parting  with  so  much  revenue  ;  but  provided  the  Imperial 
treasury  only  demanded  a  fixed  sum,  they  could  soon  find 
means  to  make  the  villages  pay  more — in  the  process,  be  it 
observed,  drawing  nearer  to  the  land,  and  becoming  more 
and  more  like  real  landlords,  more  in  actual  managing 
contact  with  the  villages. 

The  change  from  revenue-manager  to  landlord  was  ac- 
complished in  about  a  century  or  rather  more  ;  and  it  soon 
came  to  be  as  noticeable  in  the  case  of  the  former  officials, 
and  speculators  who  were  allowed  in  many  cases  to  con- 
tract for  the  revenue,  as  it  was  in  the  case  of  the  old  Rajas 
or  chiefs. 

§  6.    Extent  of  the  Revenue-farming  system. 

The  system  we  are  speaking  of  was  rampant  in  Bengal, 
and  was  adopted  in  the  northern  districts  of  Madras  ;  it  also 
extended  to  Oudh,  which  had  been  what  I  may  call  a  strong- 
hold of  the  Hindu  State  organization  ;  it  was  very  common 
in  the  North -West  Provinces,  though  subsequent  historical 
circumstances  prevented  its  final  development  in  these  dis- 
tricts. It  never  extended  to  South  or  Central  Madras 
(where  the  Muhammadan  rule  was  never  fairly  established), 
nor  to  the  Dakhan  and  Bombay,  because  there  the  Muham- 
madan kings  never  adopted  it ;  and  though  their  rule  was 
overthrown  in  the  end,  by  the  Delhi  emperors,  the  latter 
were  in  turn  overthrown  by  the  Marathas  before  their  influ- 
ence was  much  felt.  As  to  the  Marathas  themselves,  their 
revenue  ideal  never  encouraged  farming  at  all,  if  it  could  be 
helped ;  and  only  ex  necessitate  the  governors  farmed  single 
villages  or  small  groups  of  land,  as  in  the  Nagpur  State. 
It  never  extended  to  the  Panjab,  because  the  Mughal  rule 
passed  away  from  that  province  before  its  ultimate  decline  ; 
and  local  circumstances  never  would  have  favoured  the 
system. 

§  7.    The  Zaminddr  in  Bengal. 

It  is  perhaps  an  important  coincidence  that  the  system 
of  revenue-contracting  by  Rajas  or  others,  who  alike 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  187 

received  the  name  of  '  Zamfndar  Y  should  have  been  speci- 
ally developed  in  Bengal,  the  very  province  where  our  own 
revenue  experience  was  to  be  gained,  and  where  our  first 
lessons  had  to  be  learned. 

In  Bengal  the  farm-system  seems  to  have  been  like  a 
plant  which,  originally  introduced  for  some  special  purpose, 
has  taken  root,  and  can  never  afterwards  be  got  rid  of, — 
overrunning  everything  else.  By  the  year  1765  the 
system  had  so  far  borne  fruit  that  the  Zamindars  had 
really  become  very  like  landlords.  It  is  to  be  remembered 
that  Lord  Cornwallis,  no  less  than  the  preceding  adminis- 
trators of  the  first  twenty  years  of  British  rule,  had  come 
to  India  with  no  other  id^a  of  land-holding  but  that  of 
'  landlord  and  tenant,'  as  they  had  known  it  at  home.  Even 
if  the  Zamindars  had  been  less  like  landlords  than  they 
really  were,  it  was  almost  inevitable  that  a  system  should 
have  shaped  itself  in  the  minds  of  our  legislators,  by 
which  some  one  person  would  be  recognized  as  landlord. 
So  strong  was  the  effect  of  prevalent  ideas,  that  years 
afterwards,  when  the  tenures  of  village  bodies  in  the 
North -West  Provinces,  and  their  peculiar  constitution, 
were  discovered,  our  public  officers  could  with  difficulty 
realize  this  state  of  things  ;  and  they  kept  on  writing  as 
if  some  one  person  in  the  village  must  be  the  proprietor. 
It  is  easy  for  us,  who  have  now  been  made  familiar  with 
early  tenures,  primitive  institutions  and  ideas  of  property, 
and  the  like,  to  form  hasty  judgments  of  Lord  Cornwallis's 
measures.  But  such  knowledge  did  not  exist  in  his  days  ; 
and  if  it  had,  I  must  repeat  that  the  Zaminddrs1  groivth 
had  in  the  course  of  events,  and  in  fact,  gone  too  far  to 

1  The  term  '  Zamindar '  means  or  symmetry.  Hence  the  word 
simply  '  holder '  (dar)  of  '  land '  has  got  to  apply  to  a  number  of 
(zamin),  and  in  its  primary  and  different  things.  No  doubt  a  large 
generalized  meaning  indicates  any-  number  of  the  local  meanings  in- 
one  who  holds  land — a  member  of  elude  some  idea  of  a  managing  or 
the  cultivating  or  landowning  class  landlord  control  over  land  ;  but 
at  large.  But  as  applied  officially  that  is  all  that  can  be  said.  I 
by  the  Muhammadan  rulers,  it  was  have  endeavoured  to  simplify  mat- 
essentially  a  vague  term  and  prob-  ters  a  little,  by  always  writing  the 
ably  was  meant  to  be  so.  Oriental  capital  Z  when  I  refer  to  a  '  Zamin- 
governments  rarely  define  rights,  dar '  in  the  Bengal  sense, 
and  care  nothing  for  consistency 


1 88  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

make  any  plan  which  ignored  their  rights,  feasible.  For, 
on  various  grounds,  the  Zamfndars  had  been  distrusted, 
and  repeated  efforts  had  been  made  to  get  rid  of  them,  and 
such  efforts  invariably  failed.  Exactly  the  same  thing 
happened  in  Oudh.  The  king  had  made  many  of  the  old 
Rajas  (and  some  others)  into  revenue-agents,  under  the 
local  name  of  '  Taluqdar.'  When  (more  than  sixty  years 
after  the  Bengal  Settlement)  our  administrators  tried  to 
deal  with  the  villages  direct,  and  ignore  the  Taluqdars, 
they  found  it  could  not  be  done1.  The  events  of  the 
Mutiny  compelled  the  acknowledgment  of  the  Taluqdars 
as  owners. 

Thus  the  Mughal  revenue-system  is  the  direct  cause  of 
the  (unforeseen)  growth  of  the  Zamindar  landlord  of 
Bengal  and  the  Taluqdar  landlord  of  Oudh.  Indirectly, 
also,  it  has  resulted  in  all  those  special  tenures  under  the 
landlords,  which  have  been  recognized  in  both  provinces, 
with  a  view  of  doing  justice  to  all  parties.  And  this  is  not 
the  only  result ;  for  all  the  long  controversy  about  land- 
lords' rights  and  tenants'  rights,  which  have  so  long 
engaged  attention  in  Bengal  and  elsewhere,  have  really 
originated  in  the  same  causes  2. 

1  These  facts  should  be  borne  in  instantaneous    change  ;    it    merely 

mind  when  reading  such   general  fixed  and  defined  a  change  which 

criticisms  as  those  of  M.  de  Lave-  had  been  gradually  brought  about 

leye,  where  he  says  (p.  117) '  L'here-  during  more  than  a  century.    What 

dite  de  la  terre  fut  etablie  en  faveur  it  did  do  was  suddenly  to  render 

des  Zamindars  et  des  Taluqdars  par  possible  all  sorts  of  difficult  ques- 

les  Anglais  :  et  cet  article  de  loi  opera  tioiis  about  tenant  right  under  the 

ainsi    instantanement    une    trans-  Zamindar,  which  could  only  come 

formation  dans  1'ordre  social   que  to   notice  when   rights  received  a 

ne  s'est  accomplie  en  Europe  que  sharp  legal  definition, 
par  une  evolution  lente  de  plusieurs  2  In   the   North- West   Provinces 

siecles.'      Without     being     hyper-  when   persons  were  found   in   the 

critical,  it  may  be  pointed  out  that  position    of   Zamindars   or   Taluq- 

the   law  by  which  the  Zamindar  dars   over   a    number    of   villages, 

was  recognized  in  the  legal  position  they  were,  if  their  claims  could  not 

of  landlord,  was  made  in  1793,  and  be  got  over,  settled  with  but  subject 

that  by  which  the  Taluqdars  were  to   the  temporary  settlement   and 

recognized  was  some  sixty-five  years  tenant  laws.    But  the  policy  was  to 

later  ( 1 858  "> ,  under  a  totally  different  set  them  aside  wherever  possible  and 

state   of  things — at   a   time  when  deal  direct  with  the  village  bodies, 

the   Government  policy  was   dead  Many  Taluqdari    claims   were   got 

against  landlords, — and  was  forced  rid  of  (some  writers  maintain,  with 

on  them  by  the  stern  logic  of  facts.  considerable  injustice)  by  granting 

The  law  in  either  case  effected  no  a  cash  allowance  of  ten  per  cent,  on 


CHAP,  iv.]     GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  189 


§  8.  Revenue-free  Grants  and  Assignments. 

Whether  the  Muhammadan  government  consciously 
imitated  the  Hindu  system  of  appointing  certain  chiefs 
to  manage  special  territories — especially  frontier  and 
mountain- tracts — I  cannot  determine  ;  but  at  a  very  early 
stage  they  adopted  the  plan  of  granting  to  court-favourites, 
to  ministers  of  state,  and  to  military  officers,  the  right 
to  collect  the  revenue  of  a  certain  area  of  country,  and 
to  take  the  amount  collected,  either  to  support  their 
state  and  dignity,  or — in  the  case  of  military  chiefs — to 
equip  a  body  of  troops,  to  be  available  for  the  royal 
service. 

The  Mughal  empire  recognized  a  definite  portion  of  its 
dominions  as  that  which  was  directly  managed  by  the 
emperor's  officers,  and  another  area  as  that  available  for  the 
assignment  of  the  revenue  spoken  of.  And  when  certain 
offices  or  titles  were  conferred,  a  fixed  grant  went  with  them 
as  an  appanage.  Such  grants  were  called  'jagir1.'  They 
were  at  first  always  for  life,  and  resumable  with  the  office. 
Nearly  all  later  governments  have  adopted  the  'jagir,'  but 
chiefly  to  support  troops,  or  to  reward  a  service  of  some 
kind.  They  are  still  granted  by  our  own  Government,  but 
as  a  reward  for  services  in  the  past,  and  not  with  the 
obligation  of  military  service.  In  time  it  was  thought 
below  the  dignity  of  the  ruler  to  resume,  and  so  the  grant 
became  permanent  and  hereditary.  Possibly  this  stage 
was  hastened  by  the  fact  that  the  governments — both 
Hindu  and  Muhammadan — had  always  been  accustomed 
to  grant  smaller  holdings  of  land,  free  of  revenue,  to  pious 

the  revenue.     No  doubt  the  policy  the    districts    of    the    North- West 

of  the  day  had  much  to  do  with  Provinces    (Benares  Division)   had 

making  Settlement  officers  keen  to  been    permanently    settled    under 

detect    the    survival    of    right    in  the   Bengal   law :    and   here  there 

the  village  bodies ;  but  apart  from  are    Zamindari    estates,    but   with 

that,  the  villages  were  universally  rights    of   the    lower  grades   fully 

stronger  and  better  preserved  than  recorded  and  protected  by  the  Tenant 

those  of  Bengal :  and  consequently  law. 

Zamindars     and    Taluqdars    were  '  Contracted  from  '  jiii-gir '  =  place 

much  less  firmly  rooted.     Some  of  holding. 


1 90  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

persons,  to  support  temples,  mosques,  schools,  or  bridges 
and  tanks,  and  these  were  called  '  'mam/  or  '  mua'fi,'  and 
were  usually  hereditary  and  permanent  (as  long  as  the 
object  was  fulfilled).  As  the  'inam  was  permanent,  so  the 
jdgir  grew  to  be  in  many  cases.  Possibly,  also,  it  was  the 
decline  of  power  which  caused  jagirs  to  be  irregularly 
granted,  and  thus  to  become  permanent.  When  a  dis- 
organized government  desires  to  reward  a  worthy  servant 
(or  an  unworthy),  it  generally  has  its  treasury  empty,  and 
the  easiest  plan  (though  true  policy  would  suggest  a  cash 
pension  for  life  or  lives)  would  be  to  give  a  man  a  grant  by 
way  of  assignment,  and  allow  him  to  collect  what  revenue 
he  could  off  the  area. 

A  great  number  of  assignments  of  revenue  in  this  way 
grew  into  landlord-tenures,  very  much  as  the  'Zammddri' 
estates  did.  This  was  much  facilitated  by  the  fact  that  the 
grantee  was  allowed,  and  indeed  expected,  in  many  cases, 
to  conduct  the  revenue-administration  in  his  own  way, 
and  of  course  he  had  (or  assumed)  the  full  right  to  all 
unoccupied  or  waste  land  in  the  jdgir,  and  had  many  oppor- 
tunities of  ousting  refractory  land-holders — buying  up 
their  lands,  taking  them  as  security  for  arrears  of  revenue, 
and  so  forth.  '  Jagirs '  were  sometimes  granted  with  the 
express  object  of  the  grantee  settling  the  waste  ;  and  then, 
naturally,  he  would  be  looked  on  as  the  landlord  of  the 
whole. 

§  9.    Ghdtwdl. 

I  can  hardly  exclude  from  notice  here,  the  tenures 
which  arise  in  some  parts  of  India,  where  officers  or  chiefs 
were  granted  the  revenues  of  certain  hill-districts  com- 
manding the  passes  into  the  plains,  on  condition  of 
'  keeping  the  marches,'  repressing  robbers,  &c.  The  ghat- 
wali  tenures,  arising  from  arrangements  of  this  kind,  will 
be  found  described  under  the  head  of  Bengal  tenures. 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  1 9 1 

§  10.   G'irdsiya  (Gmssiah). 

I  should  also  mention  under  this  head,  a  curious  tenure1 
of  Central  India,  which  arose  on  the  overthrow  and  disper- 
sion of  the  Rajput  local  chiefs  by  the  Muhammadan  and 
by  the  Maratha  powers.  Deprived  of  their  regular  estates, 
these  persons  prowled  about  with  small  bands  of  followers 
and  harassed  the  villagers.  In  time,  the  village  bodies  or 
the  Government  officers  were  glad  to  purchase  immunity 
from  attack,  by  agreeing  to  pay  over  to  the  chiefs  a  certain 
fraction  of  the  revenue,  called  '  giras '  (lit.  a  mouthful), 
which  was  regularly  entered  in  the  revenue  accounts.  In 
some  cases  this  was  commuted  for  a  small  grant  of  land ; 
and  we  find  '  grassia '  tenures  recognized  in  some  places, 
and  still  surviving.  It  is  analogous  to  the  '  chaharam ' 
right  acquired  by  the  Sikh  adventurers  in  the  Ambala 
district  of  the  Panjab. 


SECTION  IV.     THE   MODIFICATION  OF   TENURES   BY  THE 

SUPEEIMPOSITION   OF   NEW   INTERESTS   IN   THE   SOIL   BY 
CONQUEST,   &C. 

§  i.    View  of  the  Subject. 

It  is  a  noteworthy  feature  of  most  Indian  provinces  that 
they  have  been  the  theatre  of  repeated  tribal  immigrations, 
and  of  military  conquests  in  later  times;  besides  undergoing 
a  great  many  minor  changes  in  the  case  of  petty  states 
breaking  up,  and  changing  hands,  and  particular  indivi- 
duals rising  to  local  power.  The  course  of  history  is  like 
a  continually  shifting  panorama  or  procession.  First,  the 
Aryan  races  overcome,  or  enter  into  relations  with,  Dravi- 
dians  and  Kols  that  were  before  them.  Then  Scythian  and 
other  immigrants  gain  the  mastery,  and  great  kingdoms 
professing  the  Buddhist  faith,  for  a  long  time  prevail  over 

1  See  Malcolm,  Memoir  of  Central  India,  vol.  i.  p.  508  (original  edition  of 
1824). 


1 92  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  I v, 

a  great  part  of  the  country.  The  Brahmanic  Hindus  again 
assert  themselves,  and  the  Buddhist  states  disappear.  Then 
come  the  Muhammadan  conquests;  and  when  a  strong 
Muhammadan  rule  was  established — a  system  of  adminis- 
tration based  on  the  old  Hindu  ideal — it  lasted  for  a  century, 
and  then  began  to  fall  into  decline,  after  many  local  wars 
and  disruptions  of  territorial  rule.  The  Marathas  of  West 
India  then  rise  to  power,  and  introduce  many  ideas  of  their 
own.  In  the  north,  the  Sikh  confederacies  overthrow  the 
rule  of  Pathans  from  the  frontier,  and  finally  are  united 
under  a  central  government,  once  more  of  the  old  Hindu 
type,  but  with  many  of  the  features,  and  much  of  the 
nomenclature,  of  the  Mughal  revenue-system  retained. 

Lastly,  the  British  power  supervenes ;  and  while  its 
appearance  arrests  in  one  direction  the  further  change 
of  landed  interests,  and  the  loss  of  rights  of  all  classes, 
in  another  direction  it  inaugurates  a  new  change,  by  its 
own  policy  of  recognizing  rights  in  a  certain  category 
and  then  more  or  less  logically  deducing  consequences  from 
this  recognition.  By  calling  some  men  landlords  and 
others  tenants,  and  then  enacting  laws  on  this  basis,  the 
position  and  prospects  of  more  than  one  class  have  been 
affected.  No  one  can  doubt  that  the  change  by  which  a  local 
Raja  became,  first,  an  estate-agent  or  revenue-farmer,  and 
then  a  landlord  of  many  acres,  was  great ;  but  it  was  hardly 
greater  than  the  changes  which  followed  logically  from 
the  simple  definition  by  legislative  enactment,  of  the  title 
of  the  '  Zamindar,'  although  the  definition  was  undertaken 
not  with  any  intention  to  produce  a  change,  but  rather 
with  the  idea  of  preserving  rights  in  statu  quo. 

§  2.    Nature  of  the  changes. — The  Muhammadan  rule. 

I  have  already  remarked  on  the  comparatively  small 
ostensible  changes  that  resulted  from  the  Mughal  empire. 
It  was  wholly  a  case  of  creating  fresh  interests  in  the  land 
over  the  heads  of  the  pre-existing  ones.  The  '  Zamindar ' 
in  Bengal  and  the  '  Taluqdar '  in  Oudh  have  been  so  much 


CHAP.  IV.]        GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  193 

discussed,  that  the  consequences  of  their  growth  have 
come  to  appear  greater,  and  the  change  made  by  the 
Muhammadan  system  more  sweeping,  than,  relatively,  it 
really  was. 

§  3.    The  Mardthd  Conquest. 

The  Maratha  power  arose  with  Sivaji  in  the  latter  half 
of  the  seventeenth  century.  These  rulers  were  thrifty : 
they  did  not  make  many  State  grants  of  land,  but 
allowed  existing  revenue-free  lands  or  'watan'  holdings, 
sometimes  imposing  a  'jodi'  or  quit-rent  on  them,  which 
was  heavy  enough.  When  their  power  was  well  esta- 
blished, they  recognized  the  advantage  of  dealing  direct 
with  the  villagers  through  their  hereditary  headmen,  and 
rarely  employed  middlemen  and  farmers,  who,  they  knew, 
would  always  manage  to  intercept  a  good  part  of  the 
receipts.  No  doubt,  individual  cultivators  were  ejected 
and  changed,  but  the  general  customs  of  land-holding  were, 
perhaps,  less  affected  by  Mardtha  domination  than  by  any 
other.  The  truth  of  this  is  proved  by  the  exceptions  ;  for 
there  were  districts  where  the  Marathd,  rule  was  never 
more  than  that  of  a  temporary  plunderer,  and  where  it 
was  perpetually  in  contest  with  powerful  neighbours.  In 
such  districts  it  was  necessary  to  farm  the  revenues  of 
certain  villages,  and  then  the  '  malguzar '  (or  the  '  khot '  of 
the  Konkan),  as  is  always  the  case,  grew  or  worked 
himself  into  the  position  of  proprietor  of  the  village, 
crushing  down  the  rights  of  the  original  landholders.  There 
are  districts  in  Bombay  where  the  '  khoti '  (landlord)  tenure 
is  to  this  day  a  regularly  recognized  one,  being  really 
nothing  but  a  sort  of  managing  right  over  certain  areas, 
which  has  now  become  fixed  in  the  families  of  khots  or 
persons  originally  put  in  to  farm  the  revenues. 

Throughout  the  Central  Provinces,  where  village  revenue- 
farmers  were  employed,  their  families  grew  into  the  pro- 
prietary position,  and  were,  whether  rightly  or  otherwise, 
ultimately  recognized  as  proprietors  of  the  villages  at  our 
Revenue  Settlement. 

VOL.  i.  o 


1 94  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

§  4.    The  Sikh  Conquest. 

The  Sikh  Government  cared  nothing  for  the  land-tenure, 
and  only  for  its  revenues.  Where  the  village  community, 
so  universal  in  the  Panjab,  was  strong,  it  paid  up  the 
demand,  and  its  customs  were  intrinsicallj7  unchanged. 
Nothing  is  commoner  in  Settlement  Reports  than  to  find 
allusions  to  the  confusion  introduced  by  the  grinding  Sikh 
rule  into  the  land-tenures.  This  is  true,  however,  rather 
of  the  holders  of  the  land  than  of  tenures.  No  doubt,  in 
many  districts  and  throughout  the  village  estates,  one  man 
was  ousted  and  another  put  in,  without  any  regard  to 
title,  and  only  for  the  sake  of  getting  the  revenue,  in  the 
most  arbitrary  way.  Afterwards,  perhaps,  the  old  ousted 
proprietors  would  come  back,  and  get  on  to  their  land 
again  as  privileged  tenants,  or  would  be  allowed  some 
small  rental  or  malikana  in  recognition  of  their  lost 
position :  and  thus  many  cases  of  '  sub-proprietary  rights ' 
under  a  superimposed  new  proprietary  layer,  arose;  but 
I  am  not  aware  that  any  new  form  of  land-tenure  owes  its 
origin  to  the  Sikh  dominion — anything  like  the  growth 
of  the  Zamindari  or  Taluqdari  tenure  under  the  Mughal 
system. 

When  the  Sikh  rule  became  centralised  under  Ranjit 
Singh,  all  the  smaller  chiefs,  as  a  rule,  were  absorbed, 
and  became  the  proprietary  holders  of  villages  merely, 
or  were  regarded  as  'jdgirdars '  (for  the  Sikh  system 
recognized  the  'jagir').  Some  few  States  survived  under 
the  suzerainty  of  the  Maharaja.  This  does  not  apply 
to  the  cis-Sutlej  States,  where  the  smaller  Rajas  retained 
their  independence  under  British  protection.  At  first  a 
number  of  these  exercised  almost  sovereign  powers, 
but  they  were  afterwards  reduced  to  the  condition  of 
jagirdars. 

In  the  cis-Sutlej  territory  (Ambala  district)  a  curious 
survival  from  the  early  Sikh  incursions  is  noticeable.  A 
number  of  the  marauding  clans  passed  over  the  dis- 
trict, and  would  have  succeeded  in  establishing  either  a 


CHAP,  iv.j       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  195 

general  rule  or  a  landlord  right  over  individual  villages. 
But  the  communities  were  strong  ;  and  they  often  suc- 
ceeded in  making  a  bargain,  giving  one-fourth  of  the 
share  of  the  ruler  to  the  marauders.  Sometimes  two  or 
more  chiefs  would  contend  together  for  a  village  and 
obtain  the  ' fourth  '  share  between  them.  When  the  district 
became  British,  the  growth  of  these  overlord  rights,  which 
might  in  time  have  become  proprietary,  was  arrested.  But 
the  right  of  '  Chaharam,'  or  the  fourth,  was  so  well  esta- 
blished, that  the  Government  recognized  the  families  as 
'jagirdars'  entitled  to  one-fourth  the  revenue.  The  prin- 
ciple of  joint  succession  affected  these  tenures  in  the  usual 
way.  The  revenue  fourth  became  divided  among  a  number 
of  shareholders ;  and  Government  had  to  make  rules  as 
to  when  the  share  should  pass  to  collateral  heirs  and 
when  lapse.  And,  apart  from  the  joint  succession,  the 
revenue  was  often  shared  among  the  members  of  the  clan 
according  to  their  grade.  Thus  the  original  'jagirdar'  was 
the  leader  or  chief  of  the  '  misl '  or  fighting  corporation ; 
and  every  member  of  the  misl  (misldar)  was  entitled  to 
some  share  in  the  profits.  In  jagirdari  villages,  a  '  sirkarda ' 
collects  the  rents  or  dues  of  the  jagirdar,  and  distributes 
them  among  the  graduated  ranks  of  the  body,  first  to 
the  chief,  and  next  to  the  '  zaildars/  or  subordinate  chiefs, 
whose  families  form  so  many  '  pattis '  receiving  each  the 
proper  fractional  part  of  the  zail  share ;  below  them,  the 
'  rank  and  file '  (the  taba'dar)  are  entitled  to  some  still 
smaller  fraction  of  the  revenue. 


§  5.    Smaller  Conquests. 

I  have  taken  notice,  it  will  be  observed,  only  of  the 
main  conquests  marked  in  the  history  of  India.  Smaller 
local  incursions,  like  those  of  the  Pindaris  in  Central  India, 
and  the  Rohelas  (or  Rohillas)  in  Rohilkhand.  produced  only 
local  effects,  and  they  were  chiefly  destructive,  either  de- 
populating villages  or  changing  the  owners.  No  doubt 
as  a  consequence  of  these  disasters,  many  villages  fell  into 

02 


196  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

the  hands  of  capitalists  and  revenue-managers,  who  became 
in  time  the  landlords  ;  but  such  changes  affected  rather 
the  individual  than  the  form  of  tenure. 


§  6.    Result  of  the  changes. 

It  will  now,  I  think,  be  apparent,  that  while  the  customs 
of  village  landholding  were  originally  simple,  the  effect  of 
the  different  forms  of  rule  has  been  partly  to  obliterate  old 
tenures  and  create  new  ones,  and  partly  to  introduce 
confusion  among  the  persons  entitled  to  the  tenure  right, 
by  successively  displacing  the  older  proprietary  bodies 
and  allowing  later  and  more  powerful  successors  to  lord 
it  over  them.  In  either  case  the  result  has  been  to  leave 
a  series  of  proprietary  strata,  in  which  the  upper  ones 
have  become,  de  facto^  the  proprietors,  but  the  lower  ones 
each  in  his  turn,  have  certain  claims,  which  ought  not 
to  be  ignored.  When  all  the  facts  are  taken  into  con- 
sideration, it  will  appear  that  the  attempt  to  provide 
legally  for  the  proper  position  of  these  various  shades 
of  proprietary  right  in  our  modern  Indian  law,  is  no 
easy  task. 

In  some  cases  no  overlord  has  grown  up,  and  we  have 
only  the  direct  occupant  to  deal  with,  and  the  interest 
he  has  in  his  own  field  or  holding  is  defined  by  law  without 
much  difficulty.  It  has  been  practically  and  simply  laid 
down  by  the  Revenue  Code,  in  Bombay ;  and  in  British 
Burma  it  has  also  received  definition,  though  a  somewhat 
complicated  and  technical  one. 

It  is  in  countries  (like  Bengal,  Oudh,  and  the  Central 
Provinces)  where  we  have  to  deal  with  a  series  of  con- 
current interests,  that  the  greatest  difficulty  arises.  And 
it  is  easy  to  see  that  the  different  parties  may  have 
preserved  very  different  degrees  of  right.  In  some  cases 
the  now  dominant  proprietor  may  have  clearly  distanced 
all  rivals  ;  the  people  under  him  have  sunk,  past  revival, 
into  being  tenants.  But  in  others,  the  claims  of  the  present 
and  former  proprietor  may  be  very  evenly  balanced,  and 


CHAP,  iv.j       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENUEE.  197 

it  may  not  be  easy  to  say  who  is  really  best  entitled ; 
or  again,  granted  a  clear  predominance  of  one,  there  still 
may  be  so  much  to  be  said  for  the  other,  that  some  practical 
form  of  recognition  is  equitably  a  necessity,  though  under 
what  name,  may  be  doubtful. 


§  7.   How  the  concurrent  interests  subsist. 

It  will  be  observed  that  this  concurrent  existence  of 
several  interests  in  the  soil,  is  rendered  possible  by  the 
fact  that  property  or  interest  in  land  is  more  concerned 
with  the  produce  and  with  dividing  it,  than  anything 
else.  Suppose,  for  instance,  an  old  group  of  village  culti- 
vators with  several  rights :  each  takes  the  produce  of 
his  own  fields,  after  allowing  the  village  menials  and 
officers  their  customary  share,  and  after  the  State  officer 
has  taken  the  king's  share.  Suppose  now  a  chief  obtains 
a  grant  of  the  village  or  annexes  it.  He  simply  takes  the 
Raja's  share  and  whatever  else  he  can  impose.  His  family 
after  him  do  the  same.  Next,  the  Sikh  Government  (let 
us  say)  succeeds  and  imposes  its  revenue,  taking  a  share 
alike  for  the  landlord  family  and  the  old  cultivators.  In 
process  of  time  the  Sikh  governor  grants  an  interest 
in  the  village  to  a  capitalist  who  proposes  to  spend  money 
in  irrigating  the  village.  He  takes  his  share  theoretically 
out  of  the  State  share,  but  as  the  produce  is  now  largely 
increased  by  the  water,  the  actual  amount  taken  by  the 
grantee  is  an  extra.  Lastly,  some  pious  person  establishes 
a  shrine,  and  the  governor  grants  him  a  '  mu'af  i '  of 
some  fractional  share  of  the  State  Revenue.  He  then  goes 
to  the  villagers  and  all  concerned,  and  arranges  with  them 
how  his  share  is  to  be  collected.  In  the  course  of  time 
the  '  mu'afidar,'  if  not  checked,  will  begin  to  claim  and 
to  cultivate  the  waste,  to  oust  indigent  or  lazy  villagers, 
and  to  grow  into  landlord  of  the  whole.  The  case  just 
given  is  a  real  one,  observed  in  the  neighbourhood  of  the 
Jihlam  River  in  the  Panjab. 


198  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BE1TISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 


§  8.    Grades  of  interest  in  the  soil  under  British  law. — 
State-Landlord  tenure. 

When  British  rule  began,  it  was  recognized  alike  by  the 
authorities  on  the  spot  and  by  the  Home  Government, 
that  to  grant  or  recognize  a  secure  title  in  land  was  the 
best  way  to  protect  rights  and  at  the  same  time  to  secure 
the  Government  revenue.  It  was  in  pursuance  of  this  policy 
that  the  Bengal  '  Zamindars,'  of  whom  I  have  so  often 
spoken,  were  recognized  as  proprietors  or  landlords.  There 
was  no  doubt  about  their  being  distinctly  in  the  uppermost 
grade  of  interest ;  and  in  the  Regulations  but  little  was 
said  as  to  what  was  to  be  the  name  and  nature  of  the 
rights  below  them, 

A  certain  number  of  these  rights  indeed  provided  for 
themselves.  Some  of  the  stronger  holders  had  managed 
to  get  from  the  State  officers  certain  titles  (locally  known 
as  taluqs)  which  entitled  them  to  separate  themselves  from 
the  Zamindari  and  become  proprietors  themselves :  and 
in  our  early  Bengal  Settlement  proceedings,  a  considerable 
number  of  persons  succeeded  in  getting  the  Collector  to 
record  them  as  'independent'  of  the  'Zamindars.'  But 
nothing  definite  was  settled  about  any  other  class. 


§  9.    Taluqddri  or  Double  Tenure. 

In  other  provinces  it  was  in  many  cases  found  to  be 
more  questionable  who  (among  several  possible  claimants) 
should  be  deemed  the  '  actual  proprietor,'  to  be  recognized 
as  such  by  law,  and  to  be  responsible  for  the  land-revenue 
payment.  When  once  the  village  constitution  prevalent 
in  the  North -West  Provinces  was  understood,  the  policy 
of  Government  set  strongly  in  the  direction  of  recognizing 
the  village  co-sharers.  As  already  mentioned  in  a  note, 
when  some  overlord  appeared,  if  the  claim  was  so  strong 
as  to  amount  to  the  proprietorship,  it  was  recognized ; 
but  in  many  cases  the  overlordship  was  held  to  be 


CHAP,  iv.]       GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  199 

sufficiently  provided  for  by  a  cash  allowance,  and  the 
villagers  were  treated  as  owners,  and  with  them  the 
Settlement  was  made.  These  cases  are  the  '  double '  or 
'taluqdari'  tenures  of  the  North -West  Provinces  reports. 
The  term  implies  that  both  parties  have  retained  something 
of  the  landlord  character,  and  that  the  proprietary  benefit 
is  divided  between  them.  Most  commonly  the  one  gets 
a  cash  percentage  on  the  revenue,  and  the  other  the 
management  and  other  profits  of  the  land.  This  tenure 
is  confined  to  Upper  India.  It  must  not  be  confused  with 
the  tenure  of  the  Taluqdari  landlords  in  Oudh l.  These 
latter  are  sole  landlord  tenures,  and  the  rights  under  them 
may  be,  some  of  them,  '  sub -proprietary,'  as  the  phrase 
is,  or  else  in  the  form  of  tenant  rights.  The  landlord  is 
the  person  with  whom  the  Revenue  Settlement  is  made, 
and  in  cases  where  the  others  are  protected,  it  is  by  a  '  sub- 
settlement  '  or  by  record  of  their  rights. 

The  Oudh  Taluqdar,  in  fact,  is  a  landlord  very  much 
like  the  Bengal  Zamindar,  only  that  the  extent  of  his 
interest  and  the  amount  of  his  profits  vary  in  different 
estates,  according  to  the  greater  or  less  degree  in  which  the 
rights  of  the  villagers  (or  others)  have  been  preserved  or 
have  grown  up ;  and  it  might  be  the  case  that  most  of 
the  villages  had  strong  rights,  or  it  might  be  that  the 
villages  were  much  broken  down  and  had  no  claims  to 
any  higher  position  than  that  of  tenant,  perhaps  having, 
occupancy  rights  claimable  in  one  plot  or  another.  In  one 
case  the  Taluqdar  would  be  little  more  than  the  holder 
of  a  rent  charge  on  the  estate ;  in  the  other  he  would 
be  a  nearly  unfettered  proprietor.  As  a  matter  of  fact, 
the  '  sub- settlement '  villages  are  not  numerous,  but  other 
(lesser)  rights  are  ;  and  the  Taluqdar's  position  is  something 
between  the  two  extremes. 

1  Of  course  as  regards  any  par-  qua  that  village — an  instance  of  the 

ticular  village  which  had  retained  taluqdari  or  double  tenure.     But  I 

strong  rights  under  a  Taluqdar,  so  am  speaking  of  the  Taluqdar's  title 

that  the  latter's  interest  was  a  mere  in  the  abstract, 
rent-charge,  the  tenure   would   be 


2OO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

§  10.    Instances  from  the  Panjdb — The  'aid  mdlik. 

In  the  Panjab  again,  where  the  overlord's  right  was  found 
to  be  weak,  or  very  ill-founded  in  origin,  it  was  invariably 
set  aside  by  the  grant  of  a  percentage  on  the  revenue,  while 
the  villages  '  hold  the  Settlement '  with  Government  direct, 
only  paying  a  somewhat  higher  rate  to  provide  for  the 
superior's  allowance.  But  in  not  a  few  cases— in  villages 
near  the  frontier  and  in  the  south  for  example— there  is  an 
individual  or  a  family  having  the  superior  right  over  the 
village,  which  has  not  extinguished  the  right  of  the  body 
below.  In  such  cases  the  one  party  is  called  the  '  'ala 
malik,'  and  the  other  '  adna  malik,'  in  revenue  language. 
According  to  circumstances,  the  former  may  have  little  but 
a  rent-charge  or  a  share  in  the  produce,  while  the  other 
body  have  the  water  rights,  and  the  management,  and  the 
waste,  &c. ;  or  else  the  '  'ala  malik '  body  may  have  the 
right  to  the  waste  besides  other  privileges. 

Again,  in  some  villages,  where  the  present  proprietary 
bodies  are  sufficiently  well  established  to  be  the  sole 
holders  of  the  Settlement,  certain  ancient  cultivators,  or 
persons  themselves  once,  in  bygone  times,  the  superiors, 
may  nevertheless  have  such  claims  that  a  tenant-right  is 
hardly  enough  for  them.  In  that  case  they  are  called 
'  malik  maqbuza,'  i.  e.  sub-proprietor  or  '  proprietor  of  the 
holding ' ;  implying  that  while  this  class  does  not  manage 
the  estate  as  a  whole,  or  share  in  the  waste  or  the  profits, 
still,  as  regards  their  individual  fields  or  holdings,  they  are 
proprietors ;  they  pay  nothing  but  the  State  revenue,  and  of 
course  possess  a  heritable  and  alienable  right  over  which  the 
proprietary  body  (of  the  village)  have  no  control  whatever. 
In  this  instance  we  do  not  treat  the  case  as  one  of  double 
tenure,  though  obviously  it  is  a  sort  of  transition  between 
the  double  tenure  and  the  mere  landlord  and  tenant  tenure. 

§  n.    Meaning  of  'Settlement'  and  'Sub-settlement.' 

The  person  who  is  the  'actual  proprietor,'  whether  he  has 
or  has  not  under  him  some  subordinate  proprietors  of  one 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2OI 

kind  or  another,  is  the  person  whom  Government  looks  to 
as  responsible  for  the  land-revenue  assessed  on  the  estate ; 
because  he  is  the  person  who  enjoys  the  bulk  of  the  profits 
which  remain  after  it  is  paid.  So  that  when  there  was 
more  than  one  interested  party,  and  it  became  a  question 
for  decision  who  is  the  '  actual  proprietor,'  the  decision  of 
that  also  disposed  of  the  question,  with  whom  shall  the 
Settlement  be  made — who  shall  '  hold  the  Settlement '  (as 
the  revenue  phrase  is). 

When  it  was  determined  that  a  given  individual  or  body 
was  to  hold  the  Settlement  and  be  the  actual  or  principal 
proprietor,  it  might  be  necessary  to  protect  the  rights  of  a 
grade  below,  by  making  what  is  called  a  '  sub-settlement,' 
or  in  the  older  books  a  '  mofussil  (mufassal)  settlement.' 
This  proceeding  not  only  established  the  inferior's  rights 
by  record,  but  fixed  the  amount  he  was  to  pay  to  the 
superior,  so  that  there  was  no  question  of  the  latter  treating 
him  as  tenant  and  trying  to  enhance  the  rent  or  eject 
him. 

§  12.    Grades  of  Proprietary  Right. 

We  see  then  that,  as  evolved  from  the  train  of  historical 
circumstances,  the  '  right  of  the  proprietor  '  is  only  in  some 
cases  a  simple  thing.  There  are  in  fact  grades  of  proprietary 
right,  a  series  of  persons,  each  with  some  of  the  character- 
istics of  landowner,  as  Western  nations  understand  the 
term.  And  consequent  on  this  superposition  of  proprietary 
interest,  all  proprietary  tenures  can  be  brought  under  one 
of  four  classes  : — 

I.  The  Government  itself  may  be  the  direct  owner :  as  of 
waste  land  which  it  does  not  sell  out-and-out ;  of  a  village 
which  has  been  forfeited  for  crime,  or  has  lapsed  for  want 
of  heirs,  &c.,  or  has  been  sold  for  arrears  of  revenue  and 
bought  in l — here  the  cultivators  become  tenants  properly 
so  called.  This  latter  class  of  estates  is  mostly  found  in 
Bengal,  and  but  rarely  in  Upper  India,  the  system  there 

1  Land  so  held  is  said  in  revenue  language  to  be  held  'khas'  or  '  kham,' 
or  to  be  a  '  khas  estate.' 


202  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

being  unfavourable  to   the  retention   of  such  estates  as 
a  rule. 

Of  course  all  public  forests,  large  areas  of  available  waste, 
and  other  public  property,  may  be  brought  under  this  class ; 
but  I  ain  speaking  of  cultivated  and  appropriated  lands, 
which  would  otherwise  be  in  the  hands  of  some  other 
owner. 

II.  The   Government    recognizes    no    proprietary  right 
between  itself  and  the  actual  holder  of  the  land  (i.e.  it 
creates  or  allows  no  proprietary  right  in  a  village  or  other 
larger  area  over  the  heads  of  the  actual  landholders).    This 
is  the  simple  form  of  raiyatwari  holding  under  the  Bombay 
and  Madras  systems,  and  in  Burma,  Assam,  &c. 

III.  Government    recognizes    one    grade   of    proprietor 
between  itself  and  the  actual  landholder.     It  settles  for  its 
revenue  with  this  proprietor  and  secures  the  rights  of  the 
others. 

IV.  Government  recognizes  two  grades  of  '  proprietor ' 
between  the  landholders  and  itself.     This  is  the  taluqdari 
tenure1.     In  the  Panjab  and  North -Western  Provinces  the 
Settlements  get  rid  of  this  where  possible  by  dealing  direct 
with  the  villages,  and  granting  to  the  person  possessing  the 
taluqdari,  or  superior  right,  a  cash   allowance  ;   but  the 
tenure  exists  in  Upper  India. 

§  13.    Remarks  on  these  Classes. 

The  full  understanding  of  these  forms  of  tenure  cannot 
be  attained  till  progress  has  been  made  in  the  study  of  the 
local  development  of  the  system  in  each  province ;  but  I 
hope  that  what  is  here  said  will  serve  to  introduce,  as  it 
were,  the  terms  which  will  be  constantly  in  use  in  the 
sequel. 

The  first  of  these  proprietary  tenures  is  only  occasional, 
and  presents  no  difficulty  in  understanding  it. 

The  second  we  shall  meet  with  in  Madras  and  Bombay, 
where  it  is  the  natural  tenure  resulting  from  the  old  or  non- 

1  There  may  possibly  be  more  cases  the  analogy  is  exactly  the 
than  two  grades  :  but  in  such  (rare)  same. 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2O3 

landlord  village,  the  constitution  pf  which  had  never  been 
seriously  interfered  with  by  the  Maratha  and  other  con- 
querors, except  in  some  special  cases,  where  a  landlord 
having  grown  up,  a  single  or  double  proprietary  tenure 
arose  in  consequence1. 

The  third  of  the  classes  finds  its  most  perfect  exemplifica- 
tion in  the  Zamindar  of  the  Bengal  permanent  Settlement2, 
and  in  the  malguzar  or  village  proprietor  of  the  Central 
Provinces,  in  both  of  which  cases  we  find  a  new  proprietor 
— the  result  of  the  revenue  system,  recognized  over  the 
original  village-holding.  The  village  communities  of  the 
North -West  Provinces  and  the  Panjab  are  brought  under 
this  class,  perhaps  more  theoretically  than  practically. 
Each  landholder  who  has  his  share  secured  to  him  by  record, 
or  actually  divided  out  to  him  in  severalty  (as  is  so  often 
the  case  in  these  communities),  is  really  owner  of  the  share 
and  pays  the  revenue  on  it,  as  independently  as  does  the 
'registered  occupant'  of  a  separately  numbered  lot  or  holding 
under  the  Bombay  system ;  but  the  form  is  not  the  same  : 
the  Government  does  not  settle  with  the  individual  sharer 
for  any  revenue,  but  agrees  with  the  whole  body  through 
its  representative,  for  a  lump  sum,  and  regards  the  whole 
body  jointly  as  proprietor.  The  several  holders  are  only 
bound  to  pay  the  share  which  custom  or  personal  law 
directs ;  but  that  is  a  matter  of  internal  concern  to  the 
village,  not  to  the  Government.  As  regards  Government, 
and  the  liability  for  revenue,  the  village  body  is  the  (ideal) 
proprietor  intermediate  between  the  individual  landholders 
or  sharers  and  the  State. 

1  Wherever  there  is  only  one  always  instinctively  think  of  some 
class  of  separate  field  or  farm  one  who  has  gained  or  been  granted, 
holders  paying  revenue  to  Govern-  or  has  conquered  or  usurped  the 
ment  direct,  they  are  never  called  right  over  some  earlier  body  of  cul- 
'  landlords '  of  their  fields.  They  tivators.  A  '  Jumma  raiyat '  of 
are  always  spoken  of  as  '  occupants '  Coorg  would  hardly  be  called  '  land- 
— or  something  similar — probably  lord'  of  his  fields,  although  his 
owing  to  the  lingering  idea  of  Go-  tenure  is  a  favoured  one,  and,  as 
vernment  being  in  some  sense  the  its  name  implies,  is  his  '  birth- 
superior  lord,  and  they  the '  tenants'  right.' 

in  a  sense ;  but  probably,  owing  to  the  *  And  in  the  Zamindari  portions 

natural  associations  which  cling  to  of  Madras, 
the  word  '  landlord '  in  India ;  we 


204 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 


The  fourth  form  is  found  in  cases  where  the  overlord's 
right  has  not  developed  so  far  as  to  make  him  sole  landlord 
and  all  others  mere  tenants.  In  that  case  we  have  to  count 
both  the  superior  and  the  secondary  interest  as  terms  in 
the  scale,  so  that  we  get  (i)  the  taluqdar,  (2)  the  village 
proprietary  body  or  the  individual  landholder ;  or,  in  cases 
where  there  is  an  '  'ala  malik,'  over  the  village  body  (adna 
malik),  we  should  count  up  (i)  the  ala  malik,  (2)  the  inferior 
proprietary  body  (as  a  body],  (3)  the  individual  co-sharers. 


§  14.    Diagram  of  Proprietorship. 

It  will  perhaps  aid  in  fixing  these  facts  in  the  memory 
if  I  give  a  diagram  showing  the  series  of  proprietary  interests 
at  one  glance. 


Government 

Between 

the  only 

Government 

One  Grade. 

Two  Grades. 

owner. 

and  the  soil  0. 

Government 

No  one  over 

One   landlord  over 

T.  An    overlord  —  Taluq- 

is itself 

the    actual 

the   soil  cultiva- 

dar   or    Raja,    whose 

the  direct 

occupant, 

tor    or    '  tenant  ' 

right    may   be    repre- 

owner. 

who  may  or 

occupant. 

sented  by  a  mere  rent 

may  not  be 

Examples.  — 

charge,  or  may  be  more 

Examples  :  — 

called  'pro- 

Bengal Zamindar. 

considerable 

Waste  lands 

prietor  '    eo 

Oudh       Taluqdar 

2.  The  landlord,  indivi- 

(not leased, 

nomine. 

(in  some  cases). 

dual,  or  joint  body  of 

&c.) 

Joint   body    own- 

village sharers. 

Khas        es- 

Example :  — 

ing  a  village  (as 

3.  The  actual   occupant 

tates. 

All  Raiyat- 

represented  by  their 

or    co-sharer    in    the 

Escheats. 

wari       vil- 

' lambardar'). 

body. 

Forfeitures. 

lages        in 

An    auction    pur- 

Example —  Taluqdari  te- 

/ 

Madras, 

chaser  at  a  sale 

nures  in  N.  W.  P.  and 

Bombay, 

for  arrears  of  re- 

Panjab only  consisting 

and  in 

venue. 

in  aioper  cent,  interest. 

Burma, 

All    persons  once 

Taluqdari     in     Oudh, 

Assam,  &c. 

grantees,  revenue 

where  there  is—  (i'.  a 

farmers  who  have 

Taluqdar  ;     (2)  a   vil- 

become   de   facto 

lage  birtiya  or  grantee 

owners   and   are 

landlord,  subordinate, 

so  recognized  at 

but  protected  by  sub- 

Settlement. 

settlement  ;  the  actual 

village  soil  occupants. 

The  'Khas' 

or      tenure 

The    Raiyat- 

The'zamindari'  or 

The  Taluqdari  or  double 

by  Govern- 

wari tenure. 

landlord  tenure. 

tenure. 

ment. 

CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  205 


§  15.    Grades  other  than  Proprietary. — Difficulty  of 
classing  them. 

I  have  hitherto  dealt  with  cases  where  an  incoming 
conqueror,  usurping  grantee,  or  revenue  agent,  has  become 
the  superior  landlord,  and  where  the  people,  who  but  for 
him  would  themselves  have  been  in  the  landlord  or  first 
rank,  have  been  reduced  but  still  have  retained  rights  which 
in  their  nature  are  considered  to  be  '  proprietary.' 

But  it  is  in  the  nature  of  things  that  the  process  of  growth 
of  what  I  may  now  call  the  upper  layer,  has  been  more 
or  less  complete,  and  may  have  reduced  the  rights  below  to 
something  so  indefinite,  that  it  is  matter  of  great  doubt  how 
to  class  or  define  them. 

In  Bengal  the  rights  that  remained  after  all  proprietary 
rights  were  made  independent  of  the  Zamindar,  were  not 
recognised  as  sub-proprietary  or  by  any  similar  term.  At 
the  same  time  it  is  not  easy  to  call  them  '  tenant-rights.' 
They  have  been  called  '  tenures '  for  convenience.  No 
attempt  has  been  made  to  define  what  is  a  '  tenant '  right 
and  what  a  '  tenure '  right,  though  the  modern  tenant  law 
draws  the  distinction  and  allows  very  important  privileges 
to  the  'tenure'  over  and  above  what  it  allows  to  the 
'  raiyat '  or  tenant. 

In  other  provinces,  after  such  rights  have  been  allowed 
as  are  fairly  called  '  sub-proprietary,'  or  those  of  '  inferior 
proprietor,'  all  others  are  frankly  treated  as  tenant-right  in 
some  grade  or  degree,  and  are  protected  under  the  law  of 
landlord  and  tenant. 

Every  provincial  law  will  be  found  to  have  its  own 
series  of  tenants  as  defined  for  the  purposes  of  the  law ;  each 
series  has  certain  greater  and  lesser  privileges,  as  we  go  to 
the  top  of  the  scale  (where  the  occupancy-tenant  is  hardly 
inferior  to  an  owner)  or  to  the  bottom,  where  he  is  almost 
(or  quite)  a  tenant  dependent  on  contract  with  a  landowner, 
or  is  a  tenant  of  a  tenant,  which  again  is  a  mere  matter 
of  contract. 


206  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

We  must,  in  short,  in  India,  everywhere  be  prepared  to 
find  '  tenants '  so  called  in  one  place  who  are  undistinguish- 
able  from  those  recorded  as  '  inferior  proprietors '  in  another. 
The  want  of  theoretic  uniformity  is  however  of  no  conse- 
quence, as  long  as  practical  security  of  enjoyment  is  given. 
So  also  we  must  be  prepared  to  find  '  tenants  '  whose  posi- 
tion owes  absolutely  nothing  to  any  contract  with  the  land- 
lord, or  owes  it  to  such  contract,  solely  in  its  present  shape. 
Hence  the  law  has  taken  large  powers  to  limit  the  landlord's 
power  over  the  tenancy. 

It  should  also  be  borne  in  mind  that,  in  nearly  every  case 
(in  some  cases  more  markedly  so  than  others),  the  landlord 
owes  his  position  to  the  grant  or  to  the  recognition  and  adop- 
tion of  the  British  Government.  The  Government  in  fact 
virtually  limited  its  own  demands  and  interests,  and  thus 
created  valuable  estates  in  land  with  a  permanence  and 
security  that  never  really  existed  before.  Being  in  that 
position,  the  Government  had  every  right  to  say,  '  we  shall 
not  give  all  the  benefit  to  one  party ;  we  shall  distribute 
the  interest  in  the  land  so  that  some  of  its  value  shall  go 
to  the  landlord  class  and  some  to  the  soil-holders,  whom,  for 
want  of  a  better  name,  we  call  tenants.' 

The  reader  who  is  tempted  to  regard  as  very  great  the 
privileges  allowed  under  such  law  as  the  Central  Provinces 
Tenant  Act  (for  example)  should  always,  as  a  corrective, 
recall  to  mind  the  fact  just  stated. 


SECTION  V.     THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT. 

Let  us  now  devote  a  brief  attention  to  the  classes  of  right 
which  have  been  provided  for  as  tenant  rights  or  interests. 
And  let  me  once  more  repeat  that  the  continual  changes 
that  the  succession  of  conquests  and  governments,  and  the 
successive  grants,  usurpations,  and  other  acquisitions  of 
interest  they  have  given  rise  to,  have  left  different  classes  of 
rights  in  different  stages  of  decay  or  preservation.  The 


CHAP,  iv.]        GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  207 

first  result  is  that,  as  already  remarked,  not  a  few  of  these 
'  tenancies  '  are  totally  independent  of  any  contract  or  grant 
of  the  present  overlord  or  landlord. 

§  i.    Cases  of  Natural  Tenant  Right. 

And  the  commonest  instances  of  a  '  natural '  tenant  right 
of  this  kind  are  the  following  : — (i)  We  may  be  certain  that 
once  the  'resident  tenants,'  whose  home  has  been  in  the 
village  for  generations,  were  once  individual  soil-owners, 
perhaps  first-clearers,'  with  the  right  which  we  have  so 
often  alluded  to  as  asserted  by  Manu.  Perhaps  even  they 
are  members  of  a  family  that  once  flourished  as  village 
landlords,  but  have  fallen  into  poverty  and  decay,  and  been 
obliged  to  handle  the  plough  and  accept  the  tenant  position. 
But  (2)  there  may  be  resident  tenants  who  were  always 
inferiors  in  the  village,  humble  dependants  (e.g.)  of  the 
original  founders,  who  were  privileged  as  helping  in  the 
first  work  of  colonization ;  or  they  may  have,  for  many  years, 
been  made  to  pay  exactly  as  if  they  were  owners,  by  the 
governor  of  the  province.  In  the  Panjab,  under  Sikh 
government,  it  was  almost  universally  the  case  that  the 
tenants  were  made  to  bear  just  the  same  burdens  as  the 
landlords;  the  governor  in  fact  drew  no  distinction. 

§  2.    Tenants  in  Bengal. 

There  can  be  no  doubt  that  when  the  Zamindars  were 
legally  recognized,  and  such  persons  as  could  show  a  right 
to  hold  independently  of  the  Zamindar  were  acknowledged, 
all  the  other  cultivators  became  raiyats  or  tenants  ;  and  in- 
evitably, in  the  minds  of  English  officers,  and  in  the  law- 
courts,  this  suggested  a  right  to  enhance  the  payments  of 
the  tenants  and  to  eject  them  if  they  would  not  pay. 

No  doubt  the  intention  was  to  protect  tenants,  but  the 
framers  of  the  law  did  not  know  how  to  do  it:  it  was 
thought  that  to  prohibit  the  levy  of  extra  cesses  was  an 
effective  mode  of  protection  ;  and  it  was  supposed  that,  by 
making  it  legally  binding  on  the  landlords  to  grant  pattas 


208  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

or  written  leases,  there  would  be  an  end  to  uncertainty  and 
extortion.  No  doubt  a  few  influential  persons,  who  could 
secure  a  fixed  rent  and  permanent  tenure,  possessed  such 
documents :  but  the  common  tenantry  refused  to  take  leases  ; 
in  some  cases,  doubtless,  because  they  feared  that,  by  such 
acceptance,  they  might  be  held  to  admit  an  inferior  position  ; 
but  chiefly  because  they  would  bind  themselves  absolutely 
to  pay  without  a  chance  of  throwing  up  the  land  in  a  bad 
year,  or  to  pay  an  amount  which  they  knew  the  landlord 
would  enter  in  his  own  terms — and  these  they  could  neither 
read  nor  understand.  No  other  protection  was  provided: 
the  law  was  silent  as  to  any  rule  or  limit  of  enhancement ; 
it  defined  a  small  class  of  persons  whose  tenure  was  already 
known  by  Persian  names  implying  fixity  of  possession 
and  a  permanent  rate  of  rent,  and  that  was  all. 

But  in  Bengal,  as  elsewhere,  if  we  regard  the  entire  scale 
of  rights  below  the  landlord,  we  shall  find,  at  one  end  of 
the  series,  the  small  class  just  alluded  to,  and  at  the 
other  end  of  the  series,  the  real  tenants,  people  who  were 
cultivating  the  landlord's  private  lands,  or  who  had  been 
located  by  him  on  his  own  waste.  It  might  be  rea- 
sonably said  that  no  special  protection  was  needed  for 
these :  land  was  then  abundant,  and  owners  were  only  too 
anxious  to  get  and  to  keep  tenants,  at  any  rate  those  who 
paid  full  rents l.  Had  any  serious  oppression  been  attempted, 
tenants  of  this  class  would  have  resisted  and  gone  off  to 
the  next  estate,  where  the  owner  would  probably  have 
welcomed  them.  But  between  these  first  and  last  members 
of  the  scale,  there  is  the  large  class  of  permanent  resident 
cultivators  to  whom  it  is  no  light  matter  to  break  up  home, 
leave  the  acres  they  have  held  for  generations  and  move  on 
to  another  estate.  They  are  distinguished  in  our  earlier 
revenue  books  by  the  (Persian)  term  '  khud-kasht.'  That 
all  were  equal  in  point  of  right  is  not  to  be  supposed,  though 
very  many  of  them  must  have  been,  or  have  represented, 
the  original  soil-owners — that  is  a  matter  of  detail :  one  thing 

1  It  is  said  that,  at  the  date  of  the  two-thirds  of  Bengal  was  uncul- 
Permanent  Settlement,  one-half  to  tivated. 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2OQ 

was  quite  clear, — they  were  in  possession  absolutely  indepen- 
dently of  any  contract  with  the  Zaminddr.  The  law  could 
not,  however,  lay  down  that  they  never  were  to  have  their 
rates  enhanced,  though  phrases  verging  on  that  may  be 
quoted  from  official  opinions  and  minutes  ;  for  it  is  to  be 
remembered  that,  even  if  they  had  remained  as  proprietors, 
the  State  could,  and  would,  have  periodically  revised  their 
payments,  and  therefore  it  could  not  be  supposed  that  the 
Zamindar  was  denied  a  similar  power  when  the  cultivator's 
payments  were  handed  over  to  him.  But  some  rule  of 
enhancement  was  clearly  needed  ;  and  unfortunately  no 
definite  idea  was  entertained  as  to  what  should  be  done. 
Meanwhile,  the  necessities  of  punctual  revenue-collection 
and  the  inevitable  result  of  the  introduction  of  the  Euro- 
pean idea  of  '  landlord '  and  l  tenant,'  both  worked  directly 
against  the  old  '  khud-kasht '  tenant,  though  of  course  not 
designedly. 

§  3.    Effect  of  Revenue-realization  Laivs. 

The  Government  had  always  said  that  if  the  Zammdars 
did  not  or  could  not  pay  up  the  revenue,  it  must  look 
to  the  estate  to  do  so,  and  that  the  estate  would  be 
sold  at  once,  if  any  arrears  accumulated.  And,  as  will 
appear  fully  in  the  sequel  regarding  Bengal  history, 
circumstances  brought  about  a  vast  number  of  sales 
for  arrears  of  revenue  during  the  first  ten  years *. 
These  sales,  of  course,  necessitated  the  purchaser  being 
given  the  estate  free  of  '  incumbrances '  created  by  the 
defaulter ;  if  it  were  not  so,  all  sorts  of  fraud  would  have 
been  perpetrated  ;  a  careless  man  would  have  raised  all  the 
cash  he  could  on  his  estate,  and  then  defaulted  and  let  it 
go.  But  not  only  definite  incumbrances  such  as  mortgages 

1  The  revenue  at  first  is  admitted  ter's    Annals    of  Rural   Bengal.     As 

by  good  judges  to  have  been  heavy,  time  went  on,  matters  rapidly  im- 

with  reference  to  the  circumstances,  proved,  and  sales  became  less  and 

and  especially  -with  reference  to  a  less  frequent.    The  revenue  is  now, 

recent  famine  (1772),  of  which  such  as    I    have    stated    before,    extra- 

a  graphic  accoiint  is  given  in  Hun-  ordinarily  light. 

VOL.  I.  P 


2IO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

had  to  be  avoided,  but  also  existing  contracts  about  the 
rental ;  and  little  by  little  the  position  of  the  old  resident 
cultivators  was  forgotten,  and  the  right  of  the  purchaser  to 
enhance  even  their  rents  came  to  be  acknowledged. 


§  4.    And  of  Laws  to  facilitate  Rent-collection. 

At  the  same  time  also  the  Zamindars  complained  of  diffi- 
culties in  realizing  their  rents  ;  and  Regulations  (notably 
those  of  1799  and  1812),  which  have  become  locally  famous, 
were  framed  to  help  the  landlord,  fairly  as  it  was  thought, 
and  without  injuring  the  tenant ;  but  as  they  threw  on  the 
tenant  the  burden  of  proving  that  the  rent  demanded  by 
the  landlord  was  not  the  proper  rent,  the  effect  was,  as  has 
been  said,  to  commence  proceedings  with  a  '  knock-down ' 
blow  to  the  tenant. 


§  5.    The  Zamindars  begin  to  farm  their  Estates. 

Then,  too,  arose  further  complications — the  Zamindars 
took  to  creating  renting-interests  over  fractional  parts  of 
their  estates  :  in  other  words,  as  soon  as  they  became  well 
enough  off,  they  divested  themselves  of  the  trouble  of 
directly  managing  and  collecting  their  own  rents,  by  accept- 
ing a  proportion  of  the  rent-total,  and  living  on  that, 
leaving  to  a  farmer  or  lessee  the  duty  of  collecting  the 
whole  and  running  up  the  rent-roll  to  what  he  could  for 
his  own  benefit.  The  rental  of  an  estate  was,  say,  Rs.  50,000 
at  a  certain  date,  that  being  the  total  the  Zamindar  had 
himself  fixed.  The  Zamindar  then  created  a  tenure  called 
a  '  patni,'  and  in  effect  said  to  the  holder  of  the  patni,  '  Pay 
me  Rs.  30,000  and  realise  the  balance  (and  whatever  else  you 
can  raise)  for  yourself.'  This  directly  stimulated  the  fur- 
ther raising  of  rents 1,  till  at  last  the  position  of  the  tenants 

1  And  when  the    contractor    or  proving  lands)  that  he  again  could 

patnidar  had  so  run  up  the  rental  afford  to  retire,  he  would  sub-let  his 

(partly,  be  it  observed,  by  bona  fide  farm  to  another  man  (and  he  in 

and  large  extensions  of  cultivation  turn  to  another  in  succession). 
of  the  abounding  waste,  or  by  im- 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2  I  I 

grew  so  bad  that,  after  long  discussions,  the  drafting  of 
a  tenant  law  was  seriously  taken  in  hand  in  1859.  ^ne  sub- 
ject has  thenceforth  continuously  been  kept  in  view,  till 
the  Act  of  1885  has  furnished  a  (perhaps  not  final  but) 
greatly  improved  modus  vivendi. 

Thus,  under  the  one  head  we  have  so  far  been  attending 
to,  arose  a  fine  crop  of  troubles  and  legislative  anxieties 
out  of  that  benevolent  blunder,  the  Permanent  Settlement. 
This  sketch  of  the  history  of  the  tenant  troubles  in  Bengal 
was  worth  giving  at  such  length,  because  it  illustrates 
throughout  the  ways  in  which  indirectly,  and  in  some 
degree  insensibly,  complications  of  tenure  arise  out  of  mea- 
sures that  in  themselves  seem  necessary  or  unobjectionable. 

Let  us  now  turn  to  the  provinces  later  acquired. 

§  6.    Other  Provinces — Definition  of  Tenant  right. 

In  all  provinces,  according  to  the  varying  circumstances 
of  each,  the  law  has  found  it  necessary  to  classify  tenants 
according  to  the  facts  of  their  origin  and  position.  The 
mistake  made  in  Bengal  was  not  repeated.  Each  class,  as 
defined,  is  respectively  secured  in  certain  privileges,  which 
are  naturally  greater  according  as  the  class  is  higher  (more 
nearly  approaching  to  a  proprietary  interest),  or  lower 
(approaching  more  nearly  to  a  contract-tenancy).  The  first 
and  most  important  thing  is  to  define  the  circumstances 
which  make  a  tenant  of  this  class  or  that.  Usually,  when 
the  proof  of  the  facts  would  involve  going  back  to  a  remote 
date,  but  it  is  found  that  certain  conditions  have  been 
maintained  for  a  long  time — say  twenty  years — the  law  (as 
now  in  Bengal)  will  aid  the  tenant  by  raising  a  presump- 
tion that  what  has  subsisted  for  twenty  years  is  the 
ancient  status,  and  will  accordingly  throw  the  burden  of 
proving  the  contrary,  on  the  landlord.  It  is  then  possible 
to  define  the  circumstances  which  give  rise  to  each  class  of 
occupancy  right.  In  the  Panjdb  all  the  privileged  classes 
of  tenants  are  thus  defined  with  reference  to  certain  easily 
understood  facts  of  tenure. 

P  2 


212  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  iv. 

§  7.    Where  definition  is  more  difficult. 

But  in  Bengal  and  the  North -West  Provinces,  the  history 
of  the  resident  tenants  was  so  obscure,  that  it  was  impos- 
sible to  say  definitely  what  were  the  facts  of  the  tenure,  so 
as  to  place  any  tenant  in  this  class  or  in  that.  The  Gor- 
dian  knot  was  therefore  cut  rather  than  untied,  and  pro- 
vision was  made  that  any  tenant  who  has  continuously 
occupied  land  in  the  village  for  twelve  years,  is  an  occu- 
pancy-tenant1. This  well-known  '  twelve  years'  rule  '  was 
invented  in  1859,  and  certainly  under  such  conditions  as 
those  prevailing  in  Bengal,  it  was  a  fair  rule ;  for  while  it 
secured  all  persons  justly  entitled,  it  could  only  occasionally 
have  benefitted  persons  not  entitled  ;  and  if  it  did  so,  it  was 
hardly  to  be  regretted,  when  we  reflect  what  a  long  period 
of  suffering  tenants  had  gone  through  before  the  question  of 
their  rights  was  understood.  But  the  rule  was  not  invented 
in  Bengal ;  it  was  proposed  for  the  North- West  Provinces, 
and  was  originally  a  compromise  between  the  opponents  of 
tenant  right  and  those  who  wished  to  give  an  occupancy 
right  to  all  resident  village  cultivators,  and  who  further 
would  have  called  all  tenants  settled  for  three  years 
'  resident.' 

§  8.    Nature  of  the  Privilege. 

The  '  occupancy-right '  has,  of  course,  various  forms  and 
conditions  in  the  different  laws ;  but,  speaking  generally, 
all  laws  give  a  protection  against  enhancement  without  order 
of  a  Court — on  specific  grounds  ;  and  protection  against  eject- 
ment without  a  decree.  Either  provision  would  be  useless 
without  the  other.  It  would  be  of  no  use  to  say  a  tenant 
cannot  be  ejected,  if  at  the  same  time  his  rent  could  be  so 
raised  as  to  make  his  position  unprofiable  ;  it  would  be  of 

1  At  first  certain  restrictions  were  tenant  from  one  holding  to  another, 
placed  on  the  rule:  the  tenant  without  incurring  the  odium  of  eject- 
must  have  held  the  same  fields  for  ing  him  altogether.  Some  of  the 
twelve  years,  and  this  is  still  the  laws  have  abandoned  this  distinc- 
law  in  the  North-West  Provinces.  tion,  and  made  it  suffice  to  hold  any 
The  fear  is  that  the  landlord  might  land  in  the  village, 
defeat  the  law,  by  shifting  the 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENEEAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2 1  3 

no  use  to  limit  enhancement,  if  the  landlord  could  give  the 
tenant  notice  to  quit.  And  all  tenant  laws  further  regulate 
such  matters  as  distraint  for  arrears  of  rent ;  date  for  pay- 
ing rents ;  the  division  of  payments  into  seasonable  instal- 
ments ;  and  the  grant  of  receipts  for  rent  paid.  Provision 
is  also  made  for  the  division  of  the  crop,  in  provinces  where 
rents  are  still  paid  largely  in  kind  (e.  g.  the  Panjd,b). 

A  very  important  matter  also  is  the  subject  of  improve- 
ments— what  they  are,  and  who  is  to  make  them,  and  what 
compensation,  if  any,  is  to  be  paid  on  ejectment  of  a  tenant 
who  has  '  an  improvement '  to  his  credit. 

§  9.   Controversy  as  to  the  general  Twelve-years'  Rule. 

Notwithstanding  the  necessity  for  some  protection  to 
tenants  in  the  shape  of  occupancy  rights,  the  question, 
especially  the  general  application  of  a  twelve  years'  rule, 
evoked  a  sharp  controversy.  It  raged  in  Bengal,  and 
was  renewed  when  it  was  found  that  the  ordinary  twelve 
years'  rule  was  not  sufficient ;  it  raged  in  the  Panjab  in  con- 
sequence of  the  adoption  of  North- West  Province  forms  in 
recording  rights,  the  record  of  tenants  of  twelve  years' 
standing  as  '  maurusi '  or  hereditary  tenants  \  and  the 
attempts  later  made,  to  modify  this  record. 

The  tenant  rights  controversy  in  the  Central  Provinces 
was  on  somewhat  different  matters. 


&  10.    The  Case  stated  on  both  sides. 

a 

There  have  been  able  officials  ranged  on  either  side ; 
since  on  either,  a  plausible  argument  may  be  advanced, 
both  as  to  the  facts  and  as  to  the  policy.  Those  who 
favoured  the  landlords'  view  would  urge  that  it  was  unfair 
to  the  Zamindars  and  other  proprietors  now  saddled  with  the 
responsibility,  strict  and  unbending,  for  the  revenue  that 

1  The   occupancy-tenant  is   com-       '  muzar'a    mustaqil '    (fixed  or  per- 
monly  spoken  of  as  '  maurusi  kasht-       manent  cultivator), 
kar ' :  but  in  legal  parlance  he   is 


214  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

was  to  be  paid  in  good  years  and  bad  alike,  to  tie  their 
hands,  and  to  refuse  them  the  full  benefit  of  their  lands 
by  creating  an  artificial  right  in  their  tenantry  ;  such 
a  rule  would  be  to  virtually  deprive  the  landlord  of  the 
best  share  of  his  proprietary  rights.  If  it  was  wise  of 
Government  to  recognize  the  proprietary  right  at  all,  it 
must  be  wise  also  to  recognize  the  full  legal  and  logical 
consequences  of  that  right.  True  it  might  be,  that  in  old 
days  tenants  were  never  turned  out,  but  that  was  the  result 
of  circumstances,  not  of  right ;  and  if  the  circumstances 
have  changed,  why  not  let  the  practice  of  dealing  with 
tenants  alter  too?  The  proprietors  are  the  people  we 
designed  to  secure,  in  order  to  make  them  the  fathers  of 
their  people,  to  whom  we  looked  for  the  improvement  of 
the  country  at  large,  and  for  the  consequent  increase  of  the 
general  wealth.  Why  should  we  doubt  that  they  will  act 
fairly  in  their  new  position?  Let  any  tenant  who  can 
prove  definitely  a  certain  claim,  have  it  by  all  means ;  but 
do  not  give  rights  en  masse,  in  the  hope  of  including  all 
real  cases,  while  also  granting  them  to  many  not  at  all 
equitably  entitled. 

On  the  other  side  the  advocate  of  the  tenant  would  reply : 
The  new  landlords  confessedly  owe  their  position  to  the  gift 
of  Government ;  why  should  they  get  all  ?  why  should  not 
the  benefits  conferred  be  equally  divided  between  the 
raiyats  on  the  soil  and  the  '  proprietors '  ?  The  raiyats  are 
the  real  bread-winners  and  revenue-makers,  more  quiet  and 
peaceable,  less  liable  to  political  emotions,  and  more  inter- 
ested in  the  stability  of  things  as  they  are.  Many  of  the 
tenants  we  know  to  have  been  reduced  to  that  condition 
from  an  originally  superior  status.  And  if  it  is  not  so,  the 
landlord  ought  to  be  able  to  show  definitely  that  he  origin- 
ated the  tenancy,  and  had  not  let  it  run  unquestioned  for  a 
long  period — twelve  years — which  in  the  case  of  '  adverse 
possession,'  under  the  Law  of  Limitation,  was  the  term  which 
would  give  a  title.  And  even  if  the  tenant  had  no  such 
original  position,  as  far  as  his  history  can  be  traced,  still 
the  custom  of  the  country  is  all  in  favour  of  a  fixed  holding. 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENEKAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENUEE.  215 

In  old  days,  if  a  powerful  man  ousted  a  cultivator,  it  was  by 
his  mere  power,  not  by  any  inherent  right,  or  that  the  public 
opinion  supported  him  in  so  doing.  But  as  a  matter  of 
fact  no  cultivator  ever  was  ousted ;  he  was  too  valuable. 
In  the  rare  cases  in  which  he  was  ejected,  it  was  either 
because  he  failed  to  pay  or  to  cultivate  properly  (which  is 
still  allowed  as  a  ground  for  ejection),  or  else  it  was  to 
make  room  for  some  favoured  individual,  which  of  course 
was  an  act  of  pure  oppression  :  why  should  not  the  law 
still  protect  the  tenant  from  such  evictions  ? 

The  question  is  in  truth  not  one  which  can  be  theoreti- 
cally determined,  because  the  idea  of  landlord  and  tenant, 
as  we  conceive  the  terms,  and  the  consequences  which  flow 
from  it,  have  no  natural  counterpart  in  Indian  custom. 

We  have  a  double  difficulty  to  deal  with : — the  vast 
number  of  '  tenants,'  who  have  a  valid  claim  to  be  con- 
sidered, because  their  position  (however  difficult  to  define 
and  formally  prove),  does  not  depend  on  contract,  and 
also  the  case  of  tenants  whose  origin  is  not  doubtful, 
but  whose  position  has  been  seriously  affected  by  the  new 
order  of  things — a  competition  for  land  instead  of  a  com- 
petition to  get  tenants  and  keep  them.  All  we  can  do  is  to 
make  the  best  practical  rules  for  securing  a  fair  protection 
to  all  parties. 

The  principle  of  the  twelve  years'  rule  was  adopted, 
reasonably  enough  as  regards  the  Zamindari  estates  that 
were  settled  under  the  old  Bengal  system,  and  probably 
equally  so  as  regards  the  North -Western  Provinces,  where 
village  communities  of  landlord  families  had  grown  up. 

In  the  Central  Provinces  Act  X1  was  put  in  force,  under 
certain  special  conditions,  but  is  now  replaced  by  a  special 
law.  In  the  Panjab  and  in  Oudh  it  was  never  adopted. 
There,  it  was  sufficient  to  provide  for  the  special  case  of 
those  tenants  who  had  a  '  natural '  or  customary  right  to  be 
considered  permanent. 

1  This  Act  is  now  generally  re-  the  twelve  years'  rule  has  been  re- 
pealed, and  only  remains  in  force  tained  in  the  Acts  which  super- 
in  a  few  districts  of  Bengal ;  but  seded  it  in  the  different  provinces. 


2l6  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

§  ii.    Tenancies  in  Raiyatwdri  Provinces. 

In  the  provinces  where  the  Government  deals  directly 
with  the  occupants  of  the  land,  tenant  right  has  given  no 
trouble.  But  of  course  tenancies  exist.  A  man  may  con- 
tract to  cultivate  land  as  a  tenant-at-will  or  he  may  have 
something  of  a  hereditary  claim  to  till  the  land,  as  much 
under  a  raiyatwari  system  as  any  other.  But  the  question 
of  subordinate  rights  never  becomes  as  difficult  of  solution 
in  such  countries,  as  it  does  in  those  where  the  recognized 
proprietor  is  a  middleman  between  the  cultivator  and  the 
State. 


SECTION  VI.    THE  NATURE  OF  '  PROPERTY  IN  LAND.' 

§  i.  Introductory. 

When  the  tenures  of  land  in  India  first  began  to  be 
studied,  it  was  not  so  much  because  of  their  great  historic 
and  social  interest,  but  because  of  the  more  prosaic  but 
practical  reason,  that  without  understanding  the  way  in 
which  the  people  held  land  (and  felt  it  ought  to  be  held),  it 
was  impossible  to  determine  who  should  be  responsible  for 
the  payment  of  the  Government  land-revenue,  and  con- 
sequently should,  as  '  proprietor,'  benefit  by  the  remainder 
— and  a  large  and  valuable  remainder  it  would  become — 
when  once  the  Government  demand  was  properly  limited. 
It  is  hardly  surprising  therefore,  that  at  the  commencement 
of  the  enquiries,  a  large  part  of  the  early  reports  and 
minutes  was  occupied  with  two  questions,  which  were  con- 
nected together,  or  rather,  one  of  which  arose  out  of  the 
other.  The  first  question  was,  whether  Government  was  or 
had  become,  in  the  course  of  historical  changes,  the  actual 
owner  or  universal  landlord  of  all  land,  or  whether  there 
was,  in  India,  any  real  private  properly  in  the  land.  The 
second  was  whether  Government  took  its  land-revenue  as 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  2  1  7 

a  rent  for  the  use  and  occupation  of  land,  or  as  a  sort  of 
tax  which  represented  a  share  in  the  produce  converted 
into  money. 

There  can  be  no  doubt  that  in  the  latter  part  of  the 
eighteenth  century,  when  British  administration  began,  the 
different  native  rulers  who  preceded  us,  had  asserted 
rights  as  the  universal  landowners.  That  being  the  case, 
our  Government  succeeded,  legally,  to  the  same  claim  and 
title. 

If  it  were  determined  that  Government  might  be  justly 
regarded  as  owner  of  the  land,  then  of  course  what  it  took 
from  the  actual  cultivator  might  be  regarded  as  rent;  and 
Government  was  further  entitled  to  take  the  whole  of  the 
remaining  produce  of  land,  after  allowing  the  cultivator 
the  costs  of  cultivation  and  the  profits  of  his  capital.  If 
not,  it  was  rather  a  question  of  words  whether  the  Govern- 
ment revenue  was  a  rent  or  a  tax. 

It  will,  then,  be  proper  for  us  to  consider  (i)  What, 
according  to  the  ancient  authorities,  Hindu  and  Muham- 
madan,  were  the  established  ideas  regarding  the  right  to 
land  as  vested  in  the  State  and  the  private  individual 
respectively.  (2)  What  the  actual  custom  and  practice 
were.  (3)  What  practical  solution  was  adopted  by  the 
British  Government.  (4)  And  what  is  the  consequent  true 
view  of  the  modern  land-revenue  ? 


§  2.  'Proprietary  Right.' 

The  first  thing  that  will  strike  the  student  is  the  use  of 
the  term  '  proprietary  right '  in  these  pages  and  in  Indian 
Revenue  books  generally.  It  does  not  occur  in  text-books 
on  English  law  or  jurisprudence.  I  presume  that  the  use 
of  such  a  phrase  is  due  to  the  feeling  that  we  rarely 
acknowledge  anything  like  a  complete  unfettered  right 
vested  in  any  one  person.  The  interest  in  the  soil  has 
come  to  be  virtually  shared  between  two  or  even  more 
grades,  the  cause  of  which  we  just  now  discussed.  It  is 
true  that,  in  many  cases,  only  one  person  is  called  '  land- 


2l8  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

lord '  or  '  actual  proprietor,'  but  his  right  is  limited l ;  the 
rest  of  the  right,  so  to  speak,  is  in  the  hands  of  the  other 
grades,  even  though  they  are  called  '  tenants,'  or  by  some 
vague  title  such  as  '  tenure-holders.'  In  many  cases,  as 
we  have  seen,  this  division  of  right  is  accentuated  by 
the  use  of  terms  like  '  sub-proprietor  '  or  '  proprietor  of  his 
holding.'  '  The  proprietary  right '  seems  then  a  natural 
expression  for  the  interest  held  by  a  landlord,  when  that 
interest  is  not  the  entire  '  bundle  of  rights '  (which  in  the 
aggregate  make  up  an  absolute  or  complete  estate)  but 
only  some  of  them,  the  remainder  being  enjoyed  by  other 
persons. 

§  3.  Existence  of  Property  in  Land  in  India. 

The  older  writers  often  raised  a  discussion  on  this  sub- 
ject ;  some  maintaining  that  the  law  and  custom  of  the 
various  countries  of  India  always  acknowledged  a  real 
ownership  in  land  vested  in  private  persons  ;  others  main- 
taining the  contrary. 

But  such  a  discussion,  except  for  the  information  that  is 
elicited  in  the  course  of  it,  cannot  be  a  fruitful  one,  because 
there  is  no  natural  or  universal  standard  of  what  '  property 
in  land '  is. 

In  English  law,  for  example,  there  is  no  such  thing  as  an 
absolute  ownership  of  the  soil  vested  in  any  private  person. 
Dr.  Field  remarks  2,  '  As  a  matter  of  fact  no  one  ever  did 
or  can  own  land  in  any  country,  i.e.  in  the  sense  of  absolute 
ownership — such  ownership  as  a  man  may  have  in  move- 
able  property,  as  e.g.  in  a  cow  or  a  sheep  which  may  be 
stolen,  killed  and  eaten,  or  in  a  table  or  a  chair  which  may 
be  broken  up  and  burned  at  the  pleasure  of  its  owner.' 
And  the  author  refers  to  Williams  (On  the  Law  of  Real 

1  For  instance,  in  the  case  of  the  in   the   great   Rent   Case    of   1865, 
Bengal  Zamindar,  whose  origin  we  '  The   Regulations   teem  with   pro- 
have  sketched    (and   shall    discuss  visions    quite    incompatible    with 
more  in  detail  in  the  chapters  on  any  notion  of  the  Zamindar  being 
Bengal),  he  is   called  'landlord';  absolute  proprietor.' 
but,    as    one    of    the    High    Court  a  Field,  p.  509. 
Judges  remarked  in  his  judgment 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENTJKE.  2  19 

Property,  pp.  i,  20),  'who  after  remarking  on  the  erroneous 
notions  too  generally  entertained  ....  on  the  subject  of 
property  in  land,  goes  on  to  say — "  The  thing  that  the 
student  has  to  do  is  to  get  rid  of  the  idea  of  absolute 
ownership.  Such  an  idea  is  quite  unknown  to  the  English 
law :  no  man  is,  in  law,  absolute  owner  of  lands ;  he  can 
only  hold  an  estate  in  them."  ' 

Estate  properly  means  the  interest  owned  by  an  indi- 
vidual (as  '  estate  for  life,'  '  estate  in  fee  simple,'  &c.).  But 
in  popular  phrase  '  estate'  is  applied  to  the  land  itself,  and 
it  is  so  used  in  the  Regulations  (XLVIII  of  1793,  XIX  of 
1795,  &c.). 

Sir  George  Campbell  (Essay  on  'Indian  Land  Tenures, 
Cobden  Club  Papers),  well'sums  up  the  subject  as  follows  :— 

'  The  long-disputed  question,  whether  private  property  in 
land  existed  in  India  before  the  British  rule,  is  one  which  can 
never  be  satisfactorily  settled,  because  it  is,  like  many  disputed 
matters,  principally  a  question  of  the  meaning  to  be  applied  to 
words.  Those  who  deny  the  existence  of  property  mean  pro- 
perty in  one  sense  ;  those  who  affirm  its  existence  mean  pro- 
perty in  another  sense.  We  are  too  apt  to  forget  that  property 
in  land  as  a  transferable  marketable  commodity,  absolutely 
owned  and  passing  from  hand  to  hand  like  any  chattel,  is  not 
an  ancient  institution,  but  a  modern  development,  reached  only 
in  a  few  very  advanced  countries.  In  the  greater  part  of  the 
world  the  right  of  cultivating  particular  portions  of  the  earth 
is  rather  a  privilege  than  a  property, — a  privilege  first  of  the 
whole  people,  then  of  a  particular  tribe  or  a  particular  village 
community,  and  finally  of  particular  individuals  of  the  com- 
munity. 

'  In  this  last  stage  land  is  partitioned  off  to  these  individuals 
as  a  matter  of  mutual  convenience,  but  not  as  unconditional 
property  ;  it  long  remains  subject  to  certain  conditions  and  to 
reversionary  interests  of  the  community,  which  prevent  its  un- 
controlled alienation,  and  attach  to  it  certain  common  rights 
and  common  burdens.' 


220  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

§  4.  Absence  of  any  standard  idea  of  'Property.' 

If  the  old  Indian  writers,  and  any  universal  opinion  of 
the  people,  had  formulated  private  rights  in  land  in  any 
particular  way,  it  would  be  easy  to  determine  the  fact  and 
definitely  state  the  principle,  by  examining  the  prevailing 
practice,  the  declarations  of  the  books,  or  the  forms  of 
ancient  title-deeds.  But  an  examination  of  those  sources  of 
information  does  not  enable  us  to  gather  any  generally 
accepted  theory  of  property  in  land.  Even  the  Muham- 
madan  law-books,  which  are  of  a  comparatively  late  date, 
and  written  after  the  Roman  law  was  known,  do  not  define 
— they  speak  of  '  ownership '  (MilMyat,  and  the  owner 
Mdlik),  but  do  not  say  what  constitutes  ownership. 

In  Elphinstone's  History  of  India  it  is  remarked 1, { Pro- 
perty in  land  seems  to  consist  in  the  exclusive  use  and 
absolute  disposal  of  the  powers  of  the  soil  in  perpetuity ; 
together  with  the  right  to  alter  or  destroy  the  soil  when 
such  an  operation  is  possible.  These  privileges  combined 
form  an  abstract  idea  of  property  which  does  not  represent 
any  substance  distinct  from  these  elements.  Where  they 
are  found  united  there  is  property,  and  nowhere  else.' 

It  must  be  remarked  that  this  is  really  the  Roman  ideal 
— the  usus,  usufruct-us,  abusus  et  vindicatio — rather  than  an 
Eastern  formula  ;  and  it  may  certainly  be  denied  that  any 
such  abstract  ideas  ever  prevailed  in  India.  But  at  the 
same  time  we  must  be  prepared  to  find  particular  claims  to 
land  expressed  with  great  force.  In  the  chapter  on  Malabar 
(Madras  Tenures  in  vol.  iii),  I  shall  notice  an  ancient  deed 
which  seems  to  sell  or  grant  every  kind  of  right  from  the 
centre  of  the  earth  to  the  sky  above  :  but  it  is  doubtful  how 
far  this  is  oriental  verbiage,  or  what  is  really  meant  by  it, 
for  in  that  country  we  find  the  produce  shared,  as  else- 
where. 

1  Cowell's  ed.  p.  79-80.     Baillie  in  the  land  which  is  owing  to  the 

(Muhammadan  Law  of  tlie,  Land-Tax,  productive  power  of  the  soil,  with- 

p.  20)  says  that  the  holder  of  land  out  which  the  cultivator  would  not 

who  pays  to  the  ruler  the  '  khiraj  be  able  to  meet  his  liability  (to  the 

muwazifa '  or  tribute  in  the  form  of  tribute).     See  also  Phillips,  p.  47. 
a  share  in  the  produce,  has  a  right 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  221 

§  5.  Two  principal  ideas  of  landed  right. 

All  we  can  assert  as  undeniable  is,  that  both  Hindu  and 
Muhammadan  authorities  have  always  recognized  a  strong 
right  in  land  of  some  kind. 

(1)  From  very  early  times  a  right  was  asserted  in  favour 
of  the  person  who  first  cleared  the  land — had  undertaken 
the  great  work  of  removing  the  dense  jungle  and  contending 
against   tropical   nature,   till    the   land  was  won  for  the 
plough. 

Probably  also  the  fact  that  land  so  long  as  it  is  covered 
with  jungle,  in  some  cases,  or  without  water  in  other  cases, 
is  valueless,  caused  the  productive  power  of  the  soil — or 
the  produce  of  soil — to  be  regarded  as  the  real  subject  of 
ownership.  This  is  illustrated  by  the  minute  attention 
everywhere  paid  to  sharing  the  produce;  and  also  by  the 
great  importance,  in  special  districts,  of  rights  in  water. 
No  one  cared  how  much  land  a  man  chose  to  plough  up ; 
but  let  him  try,  contrary  to  established  custom,  to  seize 
a  share  in  the  water  of  a  tank,  or  a  mountain  torrent,  to 
water  the  field,  and  he  would  be  instantly  resisted.  I 
have  already  noticed  how  the  possibility  of  the  land  bear- 
ing a  series  of  concurrent  interests,  depends  on  the  fact 
that  the  several  parties  only  determine  how  the  produce 
is  to  be  divided,  and  leave  every  other  question  in  abeyance. 

I  make  these  remarks  in  connection  with  the  '  right  of 
the  first  clearer,'  because  it  seems  that  this  right 
ultimately  depends  on  the  fact  that  this  man  has  made  the 
land  productive  (and  he  has  therefore  a  special  interest): 
he  has  converted  land  from  being  worthless  to  being  a 
'  property,'  in  the  sense  that  produce  can  now  be  enjoyed. 

(2)  I  have  already  alluded  to  the  strong  claims  put  for- 
ward   by    the    high-caste    families    and    descendants    of 
conquering    or    colonizing    chiefs.      But    here    again    we 
are  left  to  put  our  own  interpretation  on  the  terms  as 
suggesting  any  theory  of  ownership. 

The  nearest  approach  to  a  soil-claim  that  I  know,  is 
quoted  by  Colonel  Tod  in  regard  of  the  conquering  Rajput 


222  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

owners  of  Mewar  (Udaipur  State  in  Rajputana)1.  The 
author  indeed  connects  this  with  the  principle  of  the  '  first 
clearer '  when  he  says :  '  He  has  nature  and  Manu  in  sup- 
port of  his  claim,  and  can  quote  the  text  .  .  .  that  cultivated 
land  is  the  property  of  him  who  cut  away  the  wood,  or  who 
cleared  and  tilled  it.  ...  In  accordance  with  this  principle  * 
(the  italics  are  mine)  '  is  the  ancient  adage,  not  of  Mewar 
only,  but  of  all  Rajputana : — 

"Bhogra  dhani  Kajhu 

Bhiimra  dhani  majhhu  " 

'  (The  share  (revenue  share  of  the  grain)  is  the  wealth  of  the 
Kaja,  the  soil  (bhum)  is  my  wealth.) ' 

But  the  author  also  tells  us  that  in  this  case  the  soil-right 
is  that  of  the  conqueror  and  the  superior  family,  and  is 
spoken  of  as  Being  his  'bapota'  or  patrimonial  inherit- 
ance. I  therefore  doubt  whether  the  Rajputs  (as  landlords) 
laid  so  much  stress  upon  the  first  clearing,  as  upon  another 
equally  widespread  idea,  that  land  conquered  and  inherited 
by  the  next  generation,  is  a  very  firm  possession. 

§  6.    Prevalence  of  certain  terms  for  inherited  Land. 

And  I  have  once  more  to  call  prominent  attention  to 
the  fact  that  all  over  India  we  find  the  same  thing.  The 
conqueror's  descendants,  whose  title  is  might — '  the  portion 
won  by  my  sword  and  rny  bow ' — is  spoken  of  by  some 
term  implying  '  inheritance  '  or  '  birthright.'  For  some 
reason,  which  I  cannot  explain,  the  convenient  Arabic  terms 
for '  heir,'  or '  inheritance,'  have  been  frequently  adopted  even 
by  Hindu  castes.  Thus  we  have  already  had  occasion  to 
notice  that  in  Madras  the  vague  rights  of  the  superior 
(landlord)  classes  or  villages  are  called  '  mirasi '  rights,  and 
the  claimants  '  mirasdar.' a  The  Muhammadan  Government 
in  Western  India  called  the  claims  of  the  old  Maratha  con- 

1  Tod,  vol.  i.  p.  424.  warisi,  the  right  of  an  heir ;  wirasat, 

2  Miras  is  obviously,  even   to  a  the  inheritance  or  '  estate,'  &c.     In 
reader  ignorant  of  Arabic,   derived  Madras  there  were  native  terms,  as 
from  the  root  '  wirs,'  inheritance,  '  Kani-atchi,'  for  birthright,  &c. 
from  which  come  also  waris  (heir)  ; 


CHAP,  iv.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  223 

quering  families  '  mirasi '  claims.  In  the  Simla  states  the 
leading  families  call  these  holdings  '  wirasat '  (not  mUkfyat, 
the  Muhammadan  law  term,  for  ownership).  And  in  the 
Kangra  district  the  landholders  call  their  land  their  '  warisi.' 
The  old  chiefs  of  Malabar  (the  military  caste)  in  the  re- 
mote past  seized  on  estates  of  limited  size,  of  which  they 
are  now  recognized  as  owners,  and  they  call  these  estates 
their  '  Janmam,'  a  term  perhaps  (but  doubtfully)  implying 
birthright.  So  the  Coorg  or  superior  caste  landowners  call 
their  land  'jamma'  lands,  which  is  the  same  word  in  a 
localized  form. 

I  notice  that  the  strong  village  communities  of  the  Panj- 
ab  proper  have  not  familiarized  themselves  with  the  word 
'  wirasat '  for  landed  estates,  but  most  commonly  speak  of 
their  '  mal '  and  '  milkiyat ' — their  idea  is,  however,  j  ust  the 
same. 

In  Ajmer  we  shall  find  '  allodial '  holdings  called  '  bhii- 
miyd '  tenures.  Here  once  more  we  have  a  term  referring 
to  the  soil ;  but  all  its  features  are  just  like  those  of  the 
Rajput  '  patrimony.'  Princes  are  said  to  be  glad  to  acquire 
'  bhiimiya '  rights,  because  they  are  so  safe.  The  prince 
may  be  deposed  from  his  throne,  and  his  State  rights  may 
disappear,  and  he  be  driven  into  exile  and  into  private  life. 
If  afterwards  he  reappears  in  his  former  kingdom,  he  will 
not  attempt  so  hopeless  a  task  as  to  reclaim  his  State  rights, 
but  as  holder  of  a  bhumiya  plot  of  ground,  public  sentiment 
will  probably  restore  it  to  him  at  once  J. 

The  Rajput  landholder,  says  Colonel  Tod,  '  compares  his 
right  to  the  "  akhai  dhuba  " — the  ineradicable  dhub  grass 
which  no  vicissitudes  can  destroy.' 

§  7.    These  two  principles  alone  form  the  basis  of  property. 

I  have  examined  a  great  number  of  authorities,  and  with 
some  confidence  it  may  be  stated  that  the  outcome  of  all  is 
that,  whatever  may  have  been  the  ideas  entertained  regard- 
ing the  nature  of  property — and  it  is  most  probable  that 

1  Tod,  vol.  i.  p.  426. 


224  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

no  speculation  was  ever  entered  into  on  the  subject — 
two  grounds  or  bases  of  claim  to  hold  land  and  enjoy  its 
produce,  and  generally  to  alienate  it,  certainly  to  inherit  it, 
were  universal:  (i)  The  right — held  by  any  class — con- 
sequent on  first  clearing  and  reclaiming  the  waste  ;  (2)  the 
right  claimed  by  the  military  and  superior  caste  or  ruling 
races,  in  virtue  of  birthright  or  inheritance,  which  really 
meant  that  the  land  had  been  obtained  by  conquest,  grant, 
or  some  form  of  superior  might,  and  that  the  descendants 
who  inherited  it  regarded  it  as  their  '  birthright.' 


§  8.    Further  details. 

There  are  other  matters,  however,  to  be  considered  in 
connection  with  '  property.'  I  have  already  had  occasion 
to  say  something  about  the  stages  of  property  in  the  history 
of  human  development,  and  here  we  must  notice,  in  more 
detail,  the  idea  that  property  resides  in  the  family  rather 
than  the  individual. 

§  9.    The  joint  succession. — Primogeniture. 

Though  Manu  speaks  of  an  '  owner '  in  the  abstract,  he 
elsewhere  fully  recognizes  the  principle  of  family  right  and 
joint  succession.  Indeed  the  Muhammadan  law,  though  it 
determines  different  fractions  for  different  classes  of  heirs, 
is  in  principle  a  law  of  joint-succession.  And  in  India  it 
will  be  found  that  many  agricultural  tribes,  who  are  Mu- 
hammadan by  faith,  follow  a  customary  succession  which  is 
just  the  same  as  in  the  (nominally  or  really)  Hindu  tribes. 
While  we  are  on  the  subject  of  succession,  it  may  be  men- 
tioned that  the  law  and  custom  of  primogeniture  only  apply 
to  certain  things.  In  a  Raja's  domain  the  right  to  the 
'  gaddi,'  or  royal  seat,  and  the  appanages  of  authority,  are 
indivisible,  and  go  to  the  eldest  only.  But  in  ordinary 
families  all  property  is  divided,  and  only  in  some  instances 
do  we  trace  an  idea  of  primogeniture  in  the  local  custom  of 
'jethansi,'  by  which  the  eldest  son  gets  a  slightly  larger 


CHAP.  IV.]      GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  225 

share,  or  some  extra  articles  at  a  division  of  the  family 
goods.  Indeed,  in  families  which  are  not  noble,  but  yet 
are  above  the  common  rank,  it  is  often  difficult  to  say 
whether  primogeniture  obtains.  It  is  a  matter  of  family 
custom.  We  shall  see  cases  where  families  have  divided 
and  then  have  agreed  to  divide  no  further. 

It  is  obvious  that  this  joint-succession  is  the  cause  of 
many  peculiarities  in  land  custom.  Nor  is  it  without 
effect  in  the  case  of  individual  or  raiyatwdri  holdings ; 
for  when  a  raiyat  dies,  his  sons  jointly  succeed;  only  that 
if  the  estate  or  holding  is  small,  it  commonly  happens 
that  some  of  the  sons  of  their  own  choice,  go  away  and 
seek  service  or  other  means  of  livelihood.  In  many  cases 
Nature  herself  puts  a  limit  to  subdivision  1. 

The  question,  whether  primogeniture  and  indivisibility  is 
or  is  not  accepted,  often  has  an  important  effect  on  the  land- 
tenants.  For  instance,  suppose  an  indivisible  Kajaship. 
If  the  family  is  dispersed  and  the  Raja  slain  in  battle,  the 
overlordship  may  simply  disappear,  and  the  village  tenures 
below  remain  unaffected.  But  where  the  chief's  estate  is 
divided,  then  the  several  members  seize  on  one  or  two  or 
more  villages  each,  and  are  sure  to  become  landlords, 
obliterating  the  rights  below,  and  founding  landlord  com- 
munities. We  have  seen  how  many  joint  villages  owe  their 
origin  to  this  circumstance,  and  a  brief  allusion  will  here 
suffice. 

§  10.    Female  succession. 

In  agricultural  castes,  daughters  and  other  females  do 
not  usually  get  a  share  in  land,  or  sometimes  only  till 
marriage.  This  is  a  sure  mark  that  property  is  in  the 
1  family '  stage :  it  means  that  the  daughter  on  marriage 
goes  into  another  family,  and  that  if  she  got  a  share,  she 

1  And  if  a  village  body  or  a  family  into  debt  and  sell  their  land.    Many 

persists     in     subdividing     beyond  of  them  then  become  mere  tenants 

rational  limits,  the  body  is  sure  to  under  the  purchaser,  who  by  virtue 

fall  into  hopeless  poverty  and  decay,  of    his    sale-title   reaggregates    the 

when  in  all  probability  they  get  various  shares  he  has  bought  up. 

VOL.  I.  Q 


226  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  iv. 

would  take  it  away  with  her.  Widows  are  allowed  a 
life-tenure,  but  cannot  devise  the  land  or  alienate  it  with- 
out '  necessity.'  What  constitutes  '  necessity '  is  a  question 
for  each  case  as  it  arises l.  In  the  Panjab  so  strong  is  the 
feeling  that  land  belongs  to  the  family,  that  a  childless  male 
proprietor  is,  in  many  tribes,  not  allowed  to  alienate  any 
ancestral  land  without  necessity,  nor  can  he  will  it  away ; 
his  power  to  disappoint  natural  heirs  by  adopting  a  son,  is, 
in  some  tribes,  limited  by  custom 2. 


§  ii.    Authorities  on  the  subject  of  property  in  land. 

We  may  now  proceed  to  consider  the  statements  of 
ancient  writers  on  the  subject  of  property  in  land. 

It  will  be  interesting  to  quote  both  from  Hindu  and 
Muhammadan  authors.  But  it  will  be  found  that,  in  spite  of 
the  weight  of  law-books  and  commentaries,  we  shall  end,  in 
India,  with  finding  that,  as  already  stated,  the  King  or  the 
State  claimed  to  be  the  only  owner  or  landlord  of  all  land. 
At  least  that  certainly  had  come  to  pass  by  the  end  of 
the  eighteenth  century. 


§  12.    Hindu  authorities. 

If  we  date  the  Institutes  of  Manu  about  the  fifth  century 
B.C.3,  and  also  assume  that  what  is  said  about  landed 
interests  is  hardly  a  new  idea  of  the  author,  enunciated 
for  the  first  time,  but  more  or  less  represents  accepted 
ideas  on  the  subject,  it  will  be  obvious  that  a  right  (of 
whatever  nature)  in  the  land  is  a  very  ancient  idea.  It 
is  also  represented  as  attaching  to  the  individual,  or  rather 
to  the  family,  of  which  the  individual  was  only  the  head, 
the  manager,  or  the  representative. 

'  And  there  are  of  course  many  adoption  is  very  different  from  the 

judicial  rulings  or  precedents  as  to  law  of  the  Hindu  text-books, 

what  is    '  necessity '   and  what   is  3  Burnell  would  have  placed  it 

not.  later.     See  Hunter's  India,  pp.  113, 

2  In  the  Panjab  the  custom  of  114. 


CHAP,  iv.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  227 

In  Manu  we  read 1 : — '  The  sages  declare  a  field  to  belong 
to  him  who  first  cleared  away  the  timber  [Kulluka  Bhatta's 
gloss  on  this  is,  '  who  cleared  and  tilled  it '],  and  a  deer  to 
him  who  first  wounded  it.'  This  right,  as  before  remarked, 
is  still  constantly  asserted.  In  the  Panjab,  tenants  who 
never  heard  of  Manu  or  any  other  Hindu  law-book,  and 
who  admit  that  they  have  no  direct  landlord  claim,  will 
urge  a  right  to  occupy  on  the  ground  of  '  buta  shigafi ' — 
having  broken  up  the  land  and  cleared  away  the  jungle. 

It  is,  however,  curious  to  note  that  Manu's  standpoint  is 
that  of  a  very  settled  state  of  things.  He  knows  abso- 
lutely nothing2  about  a  landlord  or  a  joint  body  claiming 
the  whole  of  a  village  lands  in  a  ring-fence,  as  their 
'inheritance.'  His  standpoint  is  a  settled  government 
under  a  Raja,  who  takes  his  revenue  share  from  every 
village.  Villages  are  known  groups  of  land.  Each  has 
its  headman.  This  officer  is  allowed  a  certain  remunera- 
tion ;  several  villages  are  united  into  a  superior  charge,  and 
a  number  of  these  again  into  a  larger  charge  or  district 3. 

In  Chap.  VIII  (v.  237)  we  read  of  the  case  of  one  man 
sowing  seed  in  a  field  '  which  is  owned  by  another.'  In 
the  same  (v.  239)  we  hear  of  the  'owner  of  a  field'  en- 
closing it  with  a  thorny  hedge,  over  which  a  '  camel  could 
not  look/  and  'through  which  a  dog  or  a  boar  may 
not  thrust  his  nose.'  Again  (v.  245-63)  we  have  detailed 
rules  for  settling  and  laying  out  the  boundaries  of  estates 
or  holdings ;  and  in  v.  264  a  punishment  is  provided  for 
taking  wrongful  possession  of  a  field  or  a  garden.  There  is 
also  reference  to  the  formalities  of  sale  (among  them  the 
sale  by  pouring  out  water,  which  is  noticeable  among  the 
ancient  deeds  collected  in  Logan's  Manual  of  Malabdr). 

1  Chap.  ix.,v.  44  etsq.,  and  confer  who  from  first  to  last  discharge 

De  Laveleye,  p.  53.  their  duties'  (Manu,  viii.  35^  Re- 

a  I  have  elsewhere  alluded  to  this  garding  the  last  officials  and  their 

subject,  and  to  M.  de  Laveleye's  remuneration,  see  vii.  115-119.  I 

suggestions  thereon.  have  spoken  in  Chapter  III  of  the 

3  The  king  is  no  conquering  lord,  king's  revenue  share  (vii.  129,  130). 

driving  the  '  aborigines '  into  the  The  king  is  to  draw  moderate  taxes 

hills  or  making  serfs  of  them.  '  He  from  his  realm,  '  as  the  calf  and 

is  created  as  the  protector  of  all  the  bee  take  their  food,  little  by 

those  classes  and  orders  of  men  little.' 

Q  a 


228  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

The  reader  can  draw  his  own  conclusions  as  to  the  state 
of  feeling  on  the  subject  of  interests  in  land  involved  in 
these  references. 

The  king  is,  no  doubt,  invited  to  fine  the  cultivator 
who  neglects  to  sow  the  field ;  but  that  is  because  the 

O  * 

revenue  is  endangered ;  it  need  not  detract  from  the 
notion  of  right  in  the  soil.  Colonel  Wilks  also  argues 
that  this  text  refers  to  the  cultivator  or  tenant,  not  to  the 
owner 1. 

It  seems  to  me  extremely  probable  that  in  Manu's  time 
the  conquering  race  of  Aryans  had  been  long  established. 
The  ruling  tribes  were  in  possession  as  Rajas,  chiefs,  and 
'  lords  of  ten  villages,  twenty  villages,  and  a  hundred  vil- 
lages,' and  content  with  their  overlordship  and  the  revenue ; 
while  the  actual  settlers  were  either  the  '  rank  and  file ' 
of  the  immigrant  race,  their  lower  caste  (Vaisyas),  or  mixed 
castes  (Sudras).  Possibly  all  original  cultivators  who  were 
not  peaceably  let  alone,  had  been  driven  out,  or  reduced  to 
'  serfdom.'  In  the  Southern  kingdoms  we  have  ample 
evidence  of  lands  cultivated  for  the  nobles  by  slaves,  and  it 
is  quite  possible  that  this  may  have  been  generally  the  case. 
But  the  field-owners  contemplated  by  Manu  are  clearly 
either  Aryans  or  others  established  in  possession  as  freemen. 


§  13.    Muhamniadan  Authorities. 

The  original  theory  of  the  Muslim  was  that  conquered 
races  were  to  be  offered  the  option  between  adopting  '  the 
creed,'  or  death,  or  slavery.  But,  as  has  been  j  ustly  remarked, 
this  theory  very  soon  gave  way  to  the  more  practicable 
one,  that  conquered  races,  if  they  submitted  and  agreed  to 
pay  tribute  (khiraj),  were  to  be  let  alone.  '  Respect  tribu- 
taries,' said  the  prophet ;  '  for  they  are  entitled  to  the 

1  See    Wilks'    History    of  Mysore  when  he  wrote,  'It  is  a  nice  question 

(reprint),  p.  79, 80.    Sterling,  in  his  whether    under    the     old     Hindu 

account  of  Orissa  (Asiatic  Researches,  system  the  actual  occupants  of  the 

vol.  xv) ,  must  have  been  thinking  of  soil  were  considered  to  possess  any 

the  state  of  things  produced  by  sue-  subordinate  title  of  ownership'  (i.  e. 

cessive  conquests  in  that  country  to  the  Kajas,  chiefs,  &c.). 


CHAP,  iv.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.          229 

same  rights  and  subject  to  the  same  laws  as  the 
Moslems1.' 

The  author  of  the  Hiddyd  (a  text-book  of  Muhammadan 
law)  lays  it  down  that  if  a  prince  conquers  a  country,  he  is 
at  liberty  either  to  divide  the  land  among  his  soldiers,  or 
to  leave  it  in  the  possession  of  the  inhabitants,  on  their 
agreeing  to  pay  capitation  (jaziya)  and  land-taxes  ;  in  the 
latter  case,  the  right  of  property  remains  with  the  in- 
habitants. 

Colonel  Briggs2  quotes  Abul  Hassan  Ahmad  bin  Muham- 
mad— a  Hanifi  doctor  of  the  fourth  century  of  the  Hijra — 
who  states  the  same  doctrine ;  and  he  quotes  from  the 
Sirdj-ul-Wahdj  to  the  effect  that,  if  the  ruler  allows  the 
land  to  remain  with  the  conquered  people,  on  their  paying 
tribute,  '  the  land  is  the  property  of  the  inhabitants ;  and, 
since  it  is  their  property,  it  is  lawful  for  them  to  sell  it  or 
dispose  of  it  as  they  choose/  Other  authorities  to  the  same 
effect  might  be  quoted 3.  The  author  of  the  Hiddyd  also 
has  adopted  the  same  rule  as  the  law  of  Manu  asserts,  viz. 
that  land  is  the  property  of  him  who  first  clears  it ;  and 
Colonel  Vans  Kennedy  says  that  '  all  Muhammadan 
jurists  agree  that  the  person  who  first  appropriates  and 
cultivates  waste  land  becomes  ipso  facto  the  lord  of  the 
soil4.' 

There  is  no  doubt,  however,  that  the  prince  remained 
entitled  to  the  unoccupied  land  ;  and  the  only  difference 
among  the  doctors  seems  to  be  as  to  whether  an  intending 
cultivator  need  ask  leave  to  begin  his  work.  The  prince 

1  See  Col.  Vans  Kennedy  on  the  conquest  does   not   interfere  with 
Muhammadan  Law,  Journal  Asiatic  private  rights,  is  quite  a   modern 
Society,  vol.  ii.  p.  105.     The  infidels  development    (see   Broom,  Consiitu- 
who    submitted    and   paid   tribute  tional   Law   (ed.   i866\  p.    21,    and 
were  called  '  Zimmi,'  in  distinction  Campbell  v.  Hale,  State  Trials,  vol.  xx, 
to  the  '  harbi,"  those  who  were  in  322.     Col.  Briggs  has  collected,  at 
arms.  p.   128,  other  authorities,  showing 

2  Briggs,  p.  109.  that  by  Muhammadan  law,  khiraj- 
s  It  is  noteworthy  that  while  this       paying  land  is  the  property  of  the 

reasonable  doctrine  is  that  of  the  person    who    pays    the    tax,   even 

earlier    authorities,    all    the    later  though  he  is  conquered.     See  also 

kings  and  nawabs  of  the  country  Patton's  Asiatic  Monarchies,  p.  339. 
claimed  larger  rights,  as  we  shall          4  Paper  quoted  above,  p.  108,  and 

presently    see.      The    doctrine     of  Briggs,  p.  112. 
European   international  law,   that 


230  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  IV. 

can,   however,   certainly  make   a  gift   (or   grant)   of  the 
waste  1. 

§  14.    Later  Claims  of  the  Ruling  Power. 

Though  the  early  doctrine — both  Hindu  and  Muham- 
rnadan — is  beyond  doubt,  it  is  quite  certain  that,  as  time 
went  on,  the  local  princes  and  governments  with  whom  we 
came  in  contact,  or  who  had  immediately  preceded  us,  had 
come  to  claim,  not  only  the  waste,  but  a  right  of  ownership 
in  all  land  whatever,  and  treated  the  'raiyats'  as  their 
tenants,  except  in  the  case  of  such  claims  as  those  of  holders 
of  watan,  or  other  special  cases2.  In  the  first  place,  it 
should  be  remembered  that  most  of  the  later  governments 
were  either  powers  which  had  recently  thrown  off  al- 
legiance to  the  Mughal  government,  or  other  chiefs,  like  the 
Peshwa  of  the  Marathds  and  the  Maharaja  of  the  Sikhs, 
who  were  recent  conquerors,  and  therefore  had  extravagant 
claims.  Moreover,  history  shows  that  the  native  rulers 
in  later  times  all  adopted  more  or  less  oppressive  revenue 
assessments,  and  this  tended  to  make  land  a  burden,  so  that 
private  rights  were  hardly  asserted. 

Then,  too,  the  right  of  the  State  to  waste  or  unoccupied 
land  was  never  doubted,  and  this  would  be  an  element  in 
forwarding  a  general  claim  to  the  soil. 

It  is  noteworthy  that  in  1668  (A.D.)  the  Emperor  Aurang- 
zeb's  orders  show  that  a  private  right  was  then  recognized. 
And  as  late  as  1715,  when  the  Company  applied  for  a  grant 
of  the  '  taluqdari'  of  thirty- eight  villages  near  their  Bengal 
factory,  they  were  told  they  would  have  to  purchase  the 
rights  of  the  owners  3.  And,  when  Mr.  Shore  put  rather  a 
leading  question  to  Ghulam  Hassan,  the  historian  (author 
of  the  Sayyar  fniuta,dkhir'i'n),  assuming  the  right  of  the 
ruler,  and  asking  whether,  therefore,  he  ought  to  pay  for 

1  Idem.     The  Institutes  of  Timur-  acknowledged :  and  special  grants 
lane,  as  quoted  by  Col.  Briggs,  are  to  under  title-deeds  which  it  would  be 
the  same  effect.  beneath  the  dignity  of  a  ruler  to 

2  As  for  instance  grants  to  pious  ignore  or  to  revoke, 
persons  and  religious  uses,  in  which  3  Briggs,  pp.  128,  134. 
a  permanent  right  was  everywhere 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  23! 

land  he  required  to  take  possession  of,  the  author  replied, 
'  The  emperor  is  proprietor  of  the  revenue ;  he  is  not  pro- 
prietor of  the  soil.' 

I  cannot  acquit  our  own  authorities  of  some  exaggeration 
at  the  time  of  the  Permanent  Settlement.  For  instance, 
Mr.  James  Grant,  who  had  resided  at  the  court  of  the 
Nizam,  in  1785,  wrote:  'It  would  be  a  most  dangerous 
innovation  (diametrically  opposite  to  the  letter  and  spirit 
of  all  Oriental  legislation,  ancient  and  modern,  devised  by 
conquerors)  to  admit,  either  in  theory  or  in  practice,  the 
doctrine  of  private  individual  landed  property  by  inherit- 
ance,— free  or  feudal  tenures  extending  beyond  one  life.' 
The  ancient  authorities  do  not  support  Mr.  Grant  at  all. 

And  so  in  the  preamble-  to  Madras  Kegulation  XXXI  of 
1802  (since  repealed),  it  is  said  that  the  property  in  land 
belonged  to  the  Government  by  '  ancient  usage.' 

Certainly,  however,  the  governments  of  that  time  did, 
and  the  native  governments  of  the  present  day  do,  make  a 
claim  to  be -landlords  of  all  land — but  they  should  rather 
base  such  a  claim  on  conquest  and  the  disorders  of  later 
times,  than  on  any  of  these  ancient  authorities.  Putting 
aside  the  obvious  mistake  about  'ancient  usage,'  it  is 
hardly  possible  that  Mr.  James  Grant,  and  Colonel  Munro, 
and  many  others,  could  have  been  mistaken  about  the  fact 
that  in  their  time  all  governments  did  claim  to  be  land- 
owners ;  and,  as  I  said,  it  is  quite  certain  that  the  Nizam 
and  other  rulers  make  the  same  claim  now. 

Regulation  XXV,  of  1802,  of  the  Madras  Code — which  did 
not  commit  itself  to  any  theory — correctly  stated  that  the 
Government  had  the  '  implied  right  and  the  actual  exercise 
of  the  proprietary  possession  of  all  land  whatever.'  And 
with  reference  to  Regulation  XXXI  of  1802  (above  quoted), 
it  should  be  noted  that  the  legislature  only  professed  to 
assert  this  general  right  as  a  locus  standi,  from  which  it 
proceeded  to  confer  a  title  on  the  Zamindars. 

Colonel  Briggs,  who  is  very  averse  to  admitting  the 
growth  of  the  rulers'  claims,  is  unable  to  make  out  anything 
in  the  Nizam's  dominions,  except  that  watan  lands  were 


232  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP  BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  IV. 

saleable  (i.e.  were  private  property)1,  and  that  the  weight 
of  taxation  on  ordinary  lands  prevented  '  the  existence  of 
real  property'  in  them. 

Mr.  Elphinstone  (Governor  of  Bombay)  thought  that  all 
land  belonged  to  the  Maratha  government,  when  it  did  not 
belong  to  '  mirasdars,'  or  to  government  grantees  (and  the 
mirasdars  were  either  scions  of  Maratha  families  or  suc- 
cessors to  their  rights) ;  and  he  noted  that  '  Baji  Rao  (the 
Peshwa),  when  he  had  occasion  for  Mirdsi  land,  paid  the 
price  for  it.' 

Colonel  Malleson  says:  'It  has  been  stated,  and,  I 
believe,  truly,  that  throughout  Holkar's  dominions  no 
private  individual  possesses  permanent  heritable  or  alien- 
able rights  in  land ;  every  cultivator  is  a  tenant  at  will  of 
the  Maharaja.' 

This  is,  perhaps,  rather  strongly  worded ;  but  certainly 
a  similar  claim  is  made  by  the  semi- dependent  Rajas  of 
Chamba,  Kashmir,  and  those  of  the  Simla  Hill  States. 
They  respect  occupancy-rights  of  old  cultivators,  and  cer- 
tainly admit  the  heritable  nature  of  the  right ;  but  they  do 
not  allow  of  alienation,  without  permission  and  payment  of 
a  fee,  or  '  nazarana,'  to  the  chief  3. 

1  Briggs,  p.  75.     And  the  rulers  The  following  were  the  Kana  of 

very  often  respected  special  rights  Baghat's  rights  : — 

of  this  kind.  (i)  His  revenue  or  grain-share. 

a  Native  States  of  India,  p.  197  note.  (2)  Offerings  on  a  marriage  in  the 

8  By  the  courtesy  of  Mr.  W.  Cold-  chiefs  family. 

stream,  C.  S.  Superintendent  of  the  (3)  An     'offering'     of     100-200 

Hill  States,  I  have  seen  a  number  butas  or  cobs  of  Indian  corn,  when 

of  interesting  papers  bearing  on  the  the  harvest  is  ready, 

rights  of  the  State  of  Baghat  near  (4)  "When   the  landholder    has    a 

Simla,  from  the  records  of  the  Super-  marriage  in  his  family  he  gives  the 

intendent's  office.     In  a  letter  (No.  chief  a  goat,  and  the  chief  returns  a 

219,  28  Feb.  1866)  I  find  it  stated  sword  (talwar)  as  a  present  to  the 

that  '  the  chiefs  are  the  only  pro-  bridegroom. 

prietors,' the  occupiers  of  land  are  (5)  Certain   days    of  'begar'   or 

only  cultivators  but  mostly  heredi-  unpaid  labour  on  State  buildings  or 

tary.     The  chiefs  have  certain  lands  roads,  but  the  chief  gives  flour  for 

of  their  own  which  they  call '  land,'  the  day's  bread, 

and   cultivate   by  their  own  farm  (6)  A  '  nazar '  or  fee  from  every 

servants.  raiyat  who  asks  for  waste  to  cultivate. 


CHAP,  iv.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  233 

§  15.    Causes  of  the  later  State  Claims. 

While,  however,  it  is  conceded  that  the  real  '  ancient f 
usage,  or  theory,  of  both  the  Hindus  and  Muhammadans, 
expressly  discouraged  the  idea  that  the  ruler  was  absolute 
owner,  or  owner  at  all,  of  all  land,  and  certainly  acknow- 
ledged private  rights,  there  were  in  the  books  the  germs 
of  principles  which  easily  recrudesced  into  new  claims ; 
and  there  was  always  the  feeling  of  the  conqueror,  the  suc- 
cessful adventurer,  and  the  ruler  who  has  asserted  and 
gained  independence,  that  his  will  is  the  only  law,  that 
he  has  conquered,  and  everything  is  his,  to  dispose  of  as 
he  will. 

The  doctrine,  for  instance,  that  the  Muslim  conqueror 
only  took  tribute  as  an  act  of  favour,  and  might  have 
destroyed  the  conquered,  or  have  dealt  with  the  land  in 
any  way  he  pleased,  and  actually  did  so  deal  with  all 
waste  land,  was  very  apt  to  make  conquerors  forget  the 
dicta  which  should  have  moderated  their  pretensions.  The 
very  idea  that  the  tribute,  or  khiraj  was  a  mild  substitute  for 
slavery  or  death — however  it  may  have  been  softened  by 
the  comments  of  jurists — was  only  too  likely  to  recur  to  the 
mind  of  a  conqueror  disposed,  for  his  own  profit,  to  exag- 
gerate his  claims. 

The  author  of  the  Hiddyd  (Book  ix.  chap.  7),  speaking  of 
the  limit  of  the  khiraj  being  one  half  the  produce,  says : 
'  But  the  taking  of  one  half  is  no  more  than  strict  justice, 
and  is  not  tyrannical,  because,  as  it  is  lawful  to  take  the 
whole  of  the  persons  and  property  of  infidels,  and  to  dis- 
tribute them  among  the  faithful,  it  follows  that  taking  one 
half  their  income  is  lawful  d  fortiori!  The  later  ruler,  in 
the  chronic  emptiness  of  his  treasury,  was  apt  to  act  on  this 
reflection,  and  arbitrarily  increase  the  demand  on  the  land 
to  such  an  extent  that  no  valuable  property  in  it  remained. 

Indeed  it  is  not  easy  to  dispose  of  the  reasoning.  If  the 
law  is  that  a  king  acquires  everything  by  conquest,  surely 
he  may  claim  the  land,  allowing  only  a  liberal  user — even  a 
hereditary  user  of  it — to  the  people  ;  and  the  amount  of  his 


234  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP,  iv, 

demand    for  revenue   is  a  matter  for  his  will   and   con- 
science only. 

That  such  a  claim  was  made  by  all  the  later  sovereigns, 
is  perhaps  natural :  and  under  the  circumstances,  we  cannot 
wonder  that  the  British  authorities  on  succeeding  to  their 
place,  were  not  perfectly  consistent  in  their  declarations, 
nor  very  well  satisfied  as  to  what  they  ought  to  do.  In 
strict  right,  they  succeeded  to  the  position  of  the  out- 
going ruler ;  and  if  they  found  that  this  position — logical 
indeed,  but  morally  ill-advised — had  been  taken  up  contrary 
to  the  earlier  legal  authorities,  it  was  certainly  a  nice  ques- 
tion, what  was  the  proper  claim  for  the  British  Govern- 
ment to  assert. 


§  1 6.    Claims  how  far  adopted  by  the  British  Government. 

I  think,  on  the  whole,  what  was  meant  by  the  various 
declarations  in  the  Regulations  and  elsewhere,  was  this  ; 
that  the  Government  claimed  to  succeed  to  the  de  facto 
position  of  the  preceding  ruler,  only  so  far  as  to  use  the 
position  (not  to  its  full  logical  extent  but)  as  a  locus  standi, 
for  re-distributing,  conferring,  and  recognizing  rights  on 
a  new  basis. 

And  the  outcome  of  the  action  taken  by  the  Government 
was  this — that  it  at  once  recognized  certain  rights  in  private 
individuals,  and  only  retained  such  rights  for  itself  as  were 
necessary. 

The  power  to  make  this  distribution  was  no  doubt  based 
on  the  de  facto  power  of  the  Government  to  dispose  of  all 
land. 

I  may  exhibit  the  main  features  of  the  disposition  of 
landed  rights  made  by  Government  under  five  heads. 

(1)  Government  used  its  own  eminent  claim  as  a  starting 

point  from  which  to  recognize  or  confer  definite  titles 
in  the  land,  in  favour  of  persons  or  communities  that 
it  deemed  entitled. 

(2)  It  retained  the  unquestionable  right  of  the  State  to 

all  waste   lands  ;  exhibiting  however  the  greatest 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENUKE.  235 

tenderness  to  all  possible  rights  either  of  property 
or  of  user,  that  might  exist  in  such  lands  when  pro- 
posed to  be  sold  or  granted  away.  This  right  it 
exercised  for  the  public  benefit,  either  leasing  or 
selling  land  to  cultivators  or  to  capitalists  for  special 
treatment ;  thus  encouraging  the  introduction  of  tea, 
coffee,  cinchona,  and  other  valuable  staples.  Or  it 
used  the  right  as  the  basis  for  constituting  State 
Forests  for  the  public  benefit,  or  for  establishing 
Government  buildings,  farms,  grazing-grounds,  and 
the  like. 

(3)  It  retained  useful  subsidiary  rights — such  as  minerals. 

or  the  right  to  water  in  lakes  and  streams.  In  some 
cases  it  has  granted  these  away,  but  all  later  laws 
reserve  such  rights. 

(4)  It  retained  the  right  of  escheat ;    and  of  course  to 

dispose  of  estates  forfeited  for  crime,  rebellion,  &c. 

(5)  It  reserved  the   right   necessary  for  the  security  of 

its  income  (a  right  which  was  never  theoretically 
doubtful  from  the  earliest  times),  of  regarding  all 
land  as  in  a  manner  hypothecated  as  security  for 
the  land-revenue.  This  hypothecation  necessarily 
implies  or  includes  a  right  of  sale  in  case  the  revenue 
is  in  arrears. 

§  17.    Remarks  on  these  Heads. — Head  I. 

Each  of  these  five  heads  requires  a  few  words  of  com- 
ment. 

The  first  is  exemplified  by  the  declaration  made  in  confer- 
ring the  proprietary  title  on  the  Zamindars  in  Bengal,  and 
on  other  classes  declared  entitled,  in  the  several  Regula- 
tions and  Acts  of  the  Legislature,  which  we  shall  study  as  we 
come  to  each  of  the  provincial  systems  in  turn. 

The  Government  conferred  no  absolute  or  unlimited 
estate  on  any  one  person  or  community  :  the  landlord  or 
the  proprietor  was  the  person  or  community  that  had  the 
first  or  superior  position  and  the  major  part  of  the  rights. 


236  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

But  others  might  share  it ;  either  expressly  as  when  they  were 
called  '  sub-proprietors ' ;  or  practically,  where,  as  '  tenure- 
holders  '  or '  occupancy-tenants '  their  interests  were  secured 
by  special  provisions. 


§  1 8.    Right  in  the  Waste. — Head  II. 

There  never  has  been  any  doubt  that  in  theory,  the 
'  waste ' — that  is,  land  not  occupied  by  any  owner  or 
allotted  to  anyone — was  at  the  disposal  of  the  ruler  to  do 
what  he  liked  with ;  in  short,  was  the  property  of  the 
State. 

In  ancient  times,  such  as  those  referred  to  in  Manu,  the 
king  certainly  granted  such  lands  to  the  cultivators.  No 
doubt  it  is  contemplated  that  the  villagers  should  have  a 
right  to  use  the  grazing,  and  to  practise  wood-cutting  in  the 
waste  adjoining  their  cultivated  holdings  ;  and  probably  no 
king  would  think  of  making  grants  of  land  in  such  a  way 
as  to  put  any  village  to  real  inconvenience  in  this  respect. 

In  the  old  kingdoms  of  Oudh  we  find  the  king  levying 
his  tolls  on  wood-cutting,  at  least  on  outsiders,  and  grant- 
ing clearing-leases. 

The  Muhammadan  law  authorities  (already  quoted)  de- 
clared the  waste  to  belong  to  the  ruler,  and  the  right  has 
always  been  exercised  by  making  grants  *. 

Land  is  not  'waste,'  if  it  has  been  occupied,  even 
though  left  uncultivated.  When,  for  example,  a  noble 
family  acquired  the  '  zamindari '  right  in  a  village  in  Oudh, 
or  a  family  founded  a  village  in  the  Panjab,  they  understood 
themselves  as  entitled  to  a  certain  area  within  certain 
boundaries  (however  defined),  whether  the  area  was  under 
the  plough  or  not.  When  the  British  Government  con- 

1  In  early  days,  when  waste  was  subject  of  the  right  to  waste  is  dis- 

very    abundant,    the    rulers    were  cussed  in  the  '  Kanara  Forest  Case ' 

far  too  anxious  to  see  it  cultivated,  (Indian  Law  Reports :  Bombay  series, 

and  so  increase   their  revenue,  to  vol.  iii,  p.  583),   especially  in  Mr. 

make  any  objection  to   its    being  Justice  West's  elaborate  judgment, 

broken  up,  or  to  make  any  regula-  The   subject   is   also   gone    into  in 

tions  about  asking  leave  to  take  it.  detail  in  my  Manual  of  Forest  Juris- 

But  that  proves  nothing.  The  whole  prudence. 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENEEAL  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-TENURE.  237 

ferred  estates  on  Zamindars  or  any  other  sort  of  proprietor, 
it  of  course  contemplated  that  an  area  of  waste  for  expan- 
sion should  (wherever  nature  permitted  it)  form  part  of  the 
estate ;  because  by  such  means  the  estate  would  grow  in 
value,  and  the  revenue  burden  become  lighter  and  lighter. 
For  this  reason,  the  waste  that  adjoined  the  villages  in  the 
North -West  Provinces,  was  fairly  adjudged  to  belong  to  the 
estate 1,  while  excess  waste  not  occupied,  was  always  treated 
as  belonging  to  Government.  In  Regulation  III  of  1828 
the  right  of  the  State  is  expressly  declared2.  In  after 
times,  in  Bengal,  attempts  were  made  to  recover  or 
'  resume '  excess  waste  ;  but  as  there  were  no  surveys  show- 
ing boundaries  of  estates,  the  resumption  was  often  a  diffi- 
cult task,  and  was  only  successful  in  certain  localities. 
In  the  Panjab  and  the  Central  Provinces,  where  there  were 
large  areas  of  waste,  a  certain  proportion  was  included  in 
the  villages  at  the  survey  which  preceded  Settlement,  and 
the  rest  marked  off  for  Government. 

In  Malabar,  unfortunately,  the  claims  of  the  'janmam' 
holders  had  so  long  been  allowed,  that  it  is  to  be  feared  all 
the  forest  land  has,  by  prescription,  become  the  estate- 
holder's,  and  is  not  now  likely  to  be  recovered  3. 

In  raiyatwdri  villages,  while  certain  provision  is  made 
for  user,  i.e.  grazing  rights  and  wood-cutting,  the  waste 
'  numbers '  are  all  recorded  as  belonging  to  Government, 
and  may  be  available  for  cultivation,  to  applicants,  or  may 
be  retained,  according  to  circumstances. 

Whenever  Government  desires  to  allot  waste,  or  convert 
it  to  any  use,  there  is  an  Act  (XXIII  of  1863)  which  enables 
a  notice  to  be  given,  and  claims  to  any  right  to  be  settled. 
This  Act  clearly  proceeds  on  the  principle  of  the  State 
right ;  so  do  the  Forest  Acts,  which  contemplate  '  waste ' 

1  Except,  of  course,  large  tracts  of      sive  tracts  of  country being 

forests  and  waste  in  the  Hills  or  in  still  waste  belong  to  the  State.' 

the  Jhansi  district,  which  were  left  s  In  North  Kanara,  where  similar 

as  Government  waste.  claims   on   the   part   of  the  estate 

a  The  preamble   speaks  of  Com-  holders  were  attempted,  the  Go vern- 

missioners  appointed  '  to  maintain  ment  successfully  resisted  them  in 

and  enforce   the   public   rights   in  the  case   already  alluded  to   in   a 

different  districts  in  which  exten-  previous  note. 


238  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

lands  being  taken  up  for  forest  purposes  subject  to  a  '  forest 
Settlement,'  i.  e.  a  determination  and  separation  of  the  rights 
of  private  persons  and  those  of  the  State 1. 

§  19.     Waste  Land  Rules. 

In  all  provinces  '  Rules  for  the  lease  of  waste  lands '  are 
in  force.  The  policy  has  from  time  to  time  varied,  and  the 
rules  have  been  amended.  At  one  time  the  idea  was  to  sell 
the  land  out  and  out,  with  no  revenue  claims;  then  the 
policy  changed ;  and  seeing  the  great  and  rapid  growth  in 
the  value  of  land,  it  began  to  be  felt  that  to  sacrifice  the 
State  rights  so  readily  was  a  mistake.  The  policy  now  is 
rather  to  lease  the  land  for  a  term  of  years,  and  only  to  allow 
the  conversion  of  the  title  to  one  of  ownership  (and  that 
subject  to  paying  land-revenue)  when  the  lessee  has  shown 
that  he  is  in  earnest  and  has  really  made  proper  use  of  the 
grant. 

The  rules  sometimes  draw  a  distinction  between  the  lease 
of  small  areas  for  the  purposes  of  ordinary  cultivation,  and 
the  grant  of  larger  areas  to  capitalists,  for  the  purposes  of 
commercial  cultivation  of  tea,  coffee,  chinchona,  or  other 
staples  on  the  large  scale. 

The  chapter  on  Bengal  Tenures  will  afford  some  illustra- 
tions of  this  subject. 

§  20.    Subsidiary  Rights. — Head  III. 

The  reservation  of  a  right  to  mines,  minerals,  and  earth- 
oil,  hardly  concerns  us  in  this  manual ;  nor  does  the  right  to 
water  in  lakes  and  rivers.  It  is  enough  to  mention  that  the 
latter  is  the  basis  of  the  Canal  Acts,  regulating  the  construc- 
tion of  canals  and  the  distribution  of  the  water. 

1  The  ownership  of  the  unoccupied  rights  of  user  can  amount  to  owner- 
waste  may  reside  in  the  State,  ship.  Unless  a  claim  be  decided 
though  certain  servitudes  or  rights  of  on  its  merits,  to  be  one  of  pro- 
user  may  be  claimable  by  other  prietary  occupation  and  title,  not  to 
persons,  which  latter  have  to  be  a  mere  user,  it  does  not  destroy, 
provided  for  or  compensated,  before  however  much  it  may  hamper,  the 
the  State  can  exercise  any  complete  State  ownership.  The  distinction 
control.  But  no  amount  of  mere  is  important. 


CHAP.  IV.]       GENERAL  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-TENURE.  239 

§  21.    Right  to  lapsed  Lands,  &c,. — Head  IV. 

It  has  happened  that  estates  were  forfeited  for  rebellion 
after  1857,  or  may  be  forfeited  for  crime  under  the  Criminal 
Law.  Such  lands  then  became  State  property.  The  law  of 
escheat  of  lands  that  had  no  heirs,  was  known  to  the  old 
Hindus  under  the  name  of  'gayari.'  The  Muhammadan 
law  term  '  nazul '  is  also  applied  to  escheated  lands.  But  it 
is  very  commonly  applied  to  lands  or  houses  that  were 
owned  by  the  former  government,  and  therefore  became  the 
direct  property  of  the  succeeding  government. 


§22.    Hypothecation  of  the  Land. — Head  V. 

This  is  really  almost  the  only  vestige  of  any  '  universal ' 
State  claim  to  land.  It  is  obviously  necessary  to  the  security 
of  the  land-revenue.  The  revenue  is,  in  fact,  an  absolute 
first  charge  on  all  land,  and  must  be  satisfied  before  any 
other  claim ;  and  the  land  can  be  sold,  by  the  Bengal  law,  at 
once,  and  by  other  laws  in  the  last  resort,  to  recover  arrears. 

When  Government  sells  land,  and  no  one  buys  it,  the  land 
remains  (as  in  Bengal)  on  the  hands  of  Government,  as  what 
is  called  in  revenue  language,  a  Government  estate,  or  a 
'khas  mahal.'  Should  a  proprietor  decline  the  terms  of 
Settlement,  he  may  be  excluded  from  the  management  for 
a  time ;  but  the  estate,  even  though  farmed  or  managed 
direct  by  the  Collector  ('  held  khas '  as  the  phrase  is)  for 
a  time,  does  not  become  the  property  of  Government. 

§  23.    Government  the  '  universal  Landlord.' 

After  Government  has  so  distinctly  conferred  proprietary 
rights  in  land,  any  later  use  of  the  term  '  universal  land- 
lord,' as  applied  to  Government,  can  only  be  in  the  nature 
of  a  metaphor,  or  with  reference  to  the  ultimate  claim  of 
Government  alluded  to  in  the  last  paragraph,  or  that  which 
arises  in  case  of  a  failure  of  heirs. 


240  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  iv. 

The  only  function  of  a  landlord  that  a  Government  ex- 
ercises, is  the  general  care  for  the  progress  of  the  estates ; 
making  advances  to  enable  the  cultivators  to  sink  wells  or 
effect  other  improvements ;  advancing  money  for  general 
agricultural  purposes  (under  special  Acts) ;  suspending  or 
remitting  the  demand  for  revenue  owing  to  famine  or 
calamity  of  season. 

§  24.    Land-Revenue  ivhether  a  Tax  or  Rent. 

The  land-revenue  cannot  then  be  considered  as  a  rent, 
not  even  in  raiyatwdri  lands,  where  the  law  (as  in  Bombay) 
happens  to  call  the  holder  of  land  an  '  occupant,5  not  a 
proprietor.  The  reason  for  adopting  this  term  will  be 
noticed  in  the  chapter  on  Bombay  tenures.  Here  it  is 
enough  to  say  that  the  special  definition  does  not  entitle 
Government  to  a  true  rent.  Nowhere  and  under  no  revenue 
system,  does  government  claim  to  take  the  '  unearned  in- 
crement,' or  the  whole  of  what  remains  after  the  wages  of 
labour,  or  cost  of  cultivation  and  profits  of  capital,  have 
been  accounted  for. 

If  we  cannot  be  content  to  speak  of  'land-revenue,' 
and  must  further  define,  I  should  be  inclined  to  regard  the 
charge  as  more  in  the  nature  of  a  tax  on  agricultural 
incomes. 


CHAPTER  V. 

A   GENEEAL   VIEW    OF   THE   LAND-EEVENUE    SYSTEMS 
OF   BRITISH   INDIA. 

SECTION  I.— INTRODUCTORY. 

THIS  chapter,  in  which  I  have  endeavoured  to  present 
an  outline  of  the  various  LAND-REVENUE  SYSTEMS  OP 
BRITISH  INDIA,  and  to  show  how  they  originated  and  how 
they  are  connected  together,  will  contain  much  that  is 
already  familiar  to  every  Indian  official ;  and  readers  in  India 
may  therefore  regard  as  unnecessary  many  of  the  state- 
ments and  explanations  offered.  It  seemed,  however,  de- 
sirable to  deal  with  the  subject  from  the  point  of  view  of 
the  general  reader,  and  accordingly  to  avoid  assuming  that 
he  possesses  a  fund  of  knowledge  to  start  with.  It  is  neces- 
sary, then,  to  begin  from  the  beginning,  and  not  plunge  in 
medias  res,  or  at  once  make  use  of  terms  of  revenue-law, 
familiar  enough  to  officials,  but  certain,  until  duly  ex- 
plained, to  appear  mysterious,  if  not  repulsive,  to  others. 

I  may,  however,  assume,  to  start  with,  a  single  item  of 
knowledge,  which,  indeed,  has  been  to  some  extent  ex- 
plained in  the  last  chapter.  The  rulers,  Rajas,  and  emperors 
of  the  successive  governments  in  all  parts  of  India,  have  at 
all  times  raised  the  greater  part  of  their  State  income,  by 
levying  a  charge  on  the  land.  Whether  this  was  an  Aryan 
institution,  or  was  learned  from  the  Dravidians,  or  was  a 
natural  method,  adopted  independently,  I  leave  the  reader 
to  form  the  opinion  which  best  satisfies  him.  But,  as  a 
matter  of  fact,  it  came  to  be  an  universally-acknowledged 
principle,  that  the  king,  Raja,  or  chief  of  a  territory,  had 

VOL.  I.  R 


242  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

a  right  to  a  SHARE  IN  THE  PBODUCE  OF  ALL  CULTIVATED 
LAND.  In  time,  as  might  be  expected,  this  revenue  came 
to  be  no  longer  taken  in  kind,  but  in  the  form  of  a 
money  payment,  made  at  certain  seasons  when  the  harvests 
had  been  realized. 

I  have  to  remark  on  this  generally,  that  the  early 
authorities  are  naturally  concerned  only  with  discussing 
whether  the  king's  share  shall  be  a  sixth,  a  fourth,  &c. 
Nothing  else  was  needed.  It  was  early  recognized  that  the 
share  might  be  increased  in  time  of  war  or  special  necessity, 
but  that  is  all.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  while  the  early  Rajas 
are  supposed  to  have  taken  no  more  than  the  sixth,  it  is 
quite  certain  that  all  or  many  of  the  later  ones  demanded 
the  half.  So  tenaciously  is  old  custom  clung  to  in  India, 
that  in  many  native  states  the  ruler  still  takes  his  revenue 
in  kind.  On  the  whole,  he  is  not  a  loser ;  for  there  has  been 
a  steady  rise  in  the  value  of  grain  ;  and  this,  perhaps,  com- 
pensates him  to  some  extent  for  the  want  of  any  regular 
system  of  periodical  revision  of  assessment. 

But  when  the  time  came  for  the  Government  (it  hap- 
pened under  the  Mughal,  rule)  to  change  the  grain-revenue 
into  cash,  the  first  idea  was  to  roughly  estimate  the  standard 
share  as  yielding  so  many  'maunds'  of  grain1  for  each  crop 
on  each  kind  of  soil,  and  then  to  value  it  at  an  average 
price.  The  early  methods  of  fixing  the  grain- value  were, 
however,  so  rough,  that  practically  it  was  but  an  arbitrary 
process,  effected  with  moderation,  and  with  reference  to  the 
ability  of  the  cultivators  to  pay  easily.  The  change  from 
a  grain-revenue  to  a  cash-payment  had  one  important  con- 
sequence :  from  that  time  forward  it  has  been  recognized  as 
a  general  rule — certainly  it  was  so  by  the  Muhammadan 
governments — that  the  money-payment  needed  to  be  revised 
from  time  to  time,  i.e.  after  the  lapse  of  a  suitable  term  of 

1  The  'Maund'  (man)  is  the  usual  sir  into  sixteen  chhatank  (chittack) 

weight    for    reckoning    solids.      It  of  five  tolas  each.      The  toM  is  the 

varies  in  different  places  ;  but  the  weight  of  the  current  silver  rupee  ; 

general  standard  is  80  Ibs.  =  i  maund.  approximately  two  and  a  half   of 

The   maund   is  divided  into  forty  them  go  to  the  ounce  avoirdupois. 
seers  (sir)  of  two  Ibs.  each,  and  the 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  243 

years.  In  the  days  of  the  later  Mughal  rule,  the  revenue 
was  revised,  not  by  any  regular  process  of  re-valuation, 
but  by  the  expedient  of  adding  on  '  cesses '  to  the  existing 
totals.  These  cesses  were  called  by  various  names,  which 
indicated  either  the  name  of  the  governor  who  imposed 
them,  or  the  pretence  under  which  they  were  levied.  In 
the  Bengal  chapters  we  shall  hear  a  great  deal  about 
'  cesses.' 

But  under  our  own  Government  such  a  device  was  not 
likely  to  be  followed — at  least,  not  as  a  means  of  enhancing 
the  land-revenue l.  It  became  necessary,  then,  to  devise 
some  plan  of  fairly  assessing  the  land-revenue. 

The  process  by  which  the  Government  officials  determine 
the  amount  of  land-revenue  payable,  is  called  a  SETTLE- 
MENT (of  land-revenue)  ;  and  the  person  or  the  body  whom 
Government  recognizes  as  entitled  to  be  proprietor,  subject 
to  the  revenue-payment,  is  said  to  be  '  settled  with,'  or  to 
'  hold  the  Settlement.'  Who  the  '  proprietors '  were  and  are, 
we  have  discussed  in  general  terms  in  the  last  chapter. 

Our  first  experiment  was  made  in  the  province  which 
first  came  under  our  rule — viz.  the  'Bengal,  Bihar,  and 
Orissa,'  of  A.  D.  1765.  Here  the  plan  was  to  find  out 
what  lump-sums  the  several  local  revenue  contractors  had 
been  paying,  or  were,  in  the  accounts,  shown  as  bound  to 
pay.  Such  corrections  and  adjustments  as  were  possible 
were  then  made  in  the  totals,  and  the  persons  responsible 
were  told  to  pay  that  amount ;  and  by  law  it  was  declared 
that  they  should  never  have  it  enhanced. 

So  in  Bengal,  the  process  of  fixing  the  revenue-payment 
having  been  gone  through  once  for  all,  under  pledge  that 
no  future  increase  would  be  demanded,  it  was  called  the 
'PEKMANENT  SETTLEMENT.'  We  shall,  of  course,  have 
much  more  to  say  about  this  hereafter. 

1  I  shall  afterwards  explain  that  and  Government  levies   a  rate   to 

by  law  the  Government  levies  cer-  enable  it  better  to  meet  the  expense 

tain  'local  rates  or  cesses'  for  special  of  periodical  famines — a  rate  which 

purposes,    distinct    from    the    land  gives  rise  to  very  mistaken  notions 

revenue,     which     is     Imperial     or  about  what  people  are  pleased  to 

general.     The   district    roads    and  call  a  '  Famine  Insurance  Fund.' 
district  schools  are  so  provided  for  ; 

li   2 


244  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

But  when  we  began  to  administer  other  provinces — like 
the  North- Western  Provinces,  or  the  districts  of  Madras 
(with  exception  of  the  northern  part) l — it  was  found,  as  we 
have  seen,  that  the  land-tenures  were  wholly  different,  and 
that  there  were  no  '  Zamindars '  to  hold  the  Settlement. 
Moreover  the  inconvenience,  and  injustice  to  the  public,  of 
fixing  the  revenue  for  all  time,  regardless  of  changes  in  the 
value  of  produce,  or  the  rise  and  fall  of  agricultural  in- 
comes, were  soon  recognized.  Therefore  different  plans  of 
making  a  Settlement  were  devised  and  worked  out  for  the 
different  provinces,  according  to  the  requirements  and  local 
conditions  of  each. 

These  plans  have  been  gradually  modified  and  improved 
up  to  the  present  day.  They  retain  certain  general  dis- 
tinctive features,  but  all  have  a  certain  common  basis. 
Speaking  generally,  all  the  methods  commence  with  a  care- 
ful survey,  and  with  a  classification  of  the  soil ;  and  then 
begins  the  Settlement-Officer's  difficult  task,  viz.  to  find 
out  money-rates  per  acre  which  Government  can  fairly 
charge,  as  its  cash  revenue,  on  the  '  proprietors '  for  each 
kind  or  class  of  soil. 

According  to  the  system  in  force,  the  Revenue  is  either 
assessed  in  a  lump  sum  on  a  whole  estate — which  may  be 
a  considerable  area,  or  a  whole  group  of  villages,  or  a  single 
village  (or  parts  of  villages),  or  it  is  assessed  on  single  fields 
or  holdings  surveyed,  numbered,  and  marked  out  on  the 
ground.  When  the  estate  is  in  the  hands  of  a  great  land- 
lord, like  the  Zamindar  of  Bengal  or  North  Madras,  we  call 
it  a  ZAMINDARI  SETTLEMENT  ;  and  in  these  two  instances 
it  is  also  a  PERMANENT  SETTLEMENT. 

In  Oudh  we  have  a  TALUQDARf  SETTLEMENT,  with  great 
Taluqdar  landlords,  but  under  peculiar  conditions,  and  not 
'  permanent.' 

When  it  is  a  single  village  (or  some  part  or  pails  of 
villages)  settled  with  a  landlord  body  or  community,  we 

1  The  Northern  part  was  in  some      made  for  it  with  Zamindars  very 
respects   conditioned   like   Bengal,      much  on  the  Bengal  lines, 
and  a  Permanent  Settlement  was 


CHAP.  V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  245 

call  it  a  VILLAGE  (or  rather  a  '  Mahalwar')  SETTLEMENT1. 
And  as  this  system  is  prevalent  in  North- Western  India 
(and  the  Central  Provinces)  it  is  frequently  spoken  of  as 
the  '  North-West  System ' — for  it  was  devised  in  the  North- 
Western  Provinces. 

In  the  Central  Provinces,  we  have  seen  that  in  each 
village,  Government  conferred  the  proprietary  right  on  a 
person  called  the  '  Malguzar '  ;  this  Settlement  is  therefore 
often  spoken  of  as  theMALGuzARi  SETTLEMENT  of  the  Central 
Provinces,  though  in  all  essentials  it  is  a  Settlement  on  the 
North- West  model. 

Wherever  the  system  assesses  each  field  separately  (as  in 
Bombay  and  Madras,  and  parts  of  the  Central  Provinces, 
and  in  Berar)  we  have  a  RAIYATWARI  SETTLEMENT. 

That  is  the  very  briefest  outline  of  what  we  are  now 
going  to  look  into  a  little  more  in  detail.  But  let  me  add 
one  thing  more  of  this  general  character. 

The  theory  of  the  land-revenue  being,  that  it  is  a  share 
in  the  produce,  that  share  to  be  fixed  by  the  State  itself, 
it  might  be  supposed  that  all  modern  systems  of  assessment 
would  aim  at  finding  out  the  average  weight  or  quantity 
yielded  by  the  share  (of  each  principal  crop  on  each  class 
of  soil),  whatever  the  share  might  be, — one-half,  one-third, 
or  two-thirds,  and  then  valuing  it  in  money  at  a  price 
which  would  (naturally)  be  the  average  harvest  price  of  a 
series  of  years.  In  fact,  in  our  very  first  Settlements  (putting 
aside  the  case  of  the  Bengal  Zamindars),  something  like  this 
was  actually  attempted.  But  it  was  too  difficult  and  un- 
certain ;  and  they  next  tried  to  make  a  calculation  of  the 
'  assets '  of  the  estate.  They  counted  up  the  total  produce 
in  gross,  and  tried  to  find  out  the  costs  of  cultivation,  wages 
of  labour,  profits  of  stock,  &c.,  and,  deducting  the  latter  from 
the  former,  they  took  a  fraction  of  the  balance  as  the 
revenue  or  share  of  the  '  assets.'  But  this  also  proved  im- 
practicable, and  so  they  gradually  perfected  other  methods 

1  See  remarks  on  this  in  Chap.  IV.  one  sum  of  revenue,  is,  in  revenue 

p.  170.     The  village  is  very  often  language,  the  'Mahal'   for  assess- 

the   unit,  but  the   group   of  land  ment  purposes. 
held  under  one   title,  assessed   to 


246  LAXD    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

which  it  will  be  my  object  to  make  plain  in  the  sequel ; 
but  here  I  wish  only  to  make  it  understood  that  modern 
assessment  methods  have  departed  further  and  further  from 
the  plan  of  valuing  in  money  an  actual  share  in  produce. 
Certain  systems,  however,  still  retain  some  vestiges  of  the 
idea:  some  more  than  others. 


SECTION  II. — THE  ORIGIN  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE. 

§  i.  The  'Law  and  Constitution'  of  India. 

In  introducing  the  subject  of  ancient  revenue  systems, 
and  quoting  authorities  as  to  what  was  the  king's  proper 
share,  I  must  remind  the  reader  that  all  this  was  matter  of 
custom — that  curious  and  often  undefinable  feeling  that 
things  ought  to  be  in  a  certain  way  because  they  always 
have  been  so.  The  custom,  however,  has  always  to  give 
way  before  the  necessities  of  the  ruler  ;  and  that  is  why,  in 
spite  of  all  that  can  be  quoted  from  law-books,  we  find 
that,  in  modern  times,  all  Native  States  claimed,  and  still 
claim,  to  be  de  facto  owners  of  every  acre  of  soil  in  their 
States,  and  have  taken  as  much  land-revenue  as  they  could 
get  without  seriously  starving  the  people.  Yet,  in  spite  of 
the  facts,  we  find  writers — especially  the  early  ones — talk- 
ing about  the  '  law  and  constitution  of  India';  and  at  least 
one  book  (Colonel  Galloway's)  has  been  published  under 
that  title.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  there  never  has  been  any- 
thing resembling  a  '  law  and  constitution '  for  any  one  of 
the  diverse  countries  included  in  the  geographical  term 
'  India'  (let  alone  for  the  whole),  in  the  sense  in  which  an 
English  reader  would  ordinarily  understand  the  term. 

Possibly,  in  Colonel  Galloway's  time,  Indian  history  was 
not  accessible  to  the  same  comprehensive  or  panoramic 
view  of  it  that,  thanks  to  the  labours  of  Sir  W.  Hunter  and 
others,  is  now  open  to  us.  How  it  was  likely  that  a  series 
of  loosely-connected  States,  always  at  war  with  one  another, 
overrun  from  age  to  age  by  Dravidians,  Greeks,  Northern 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  247 

Buddhists,  Rajputs,  Jats,  Gujars,  Afghans,  Mughals,  and 
the  rest,  could  ever  have  possessed  any  general  and  authori- 
tative law  entitled  to  be  called  the  '  law  and  constitution  of 
India,'  it  is  not  easy  to  understand. 

I  do  not,  however,  ignore  the  fact  that,  under  all  this 
series  of  dynasties,  there  were  some  indications  of  uniform 
ideas  and  principles.  In  the  absence  of  any  other  force, 
CUSTOM  has  had  a  potent  influence  on  the  rulers  and  con- 
querors no  less  than  on  the  people.  All  that  were  in  any 
way  Hindu,  or  Hinduized,  had  certain  common  feelings  ; 
and  the  Muhammadan  conquerors  of  later  days,  over  whom 
the  law-texts  of  Arabia  or  of  Baghdad  never  had  any 
great  hold,  knew  that  their  only  chance  of  success  was  to 
conform  as  much  as  possible  to  the  custom  of  their  Hindu 
subjects. 

The  early  Hindus  never  had  anything  that  could  be 
called  a  code  of  practical  law.  It  is  absurd  to  suppose  that 
Manu,  or  any  other  author's  collection  of  legal  maxims, 
(especially  in  matters  of  government)  was  '  in  force '  as 
statute  law  is  in  England  or  France.  The  Muhammadan 
law-books  were,  perhaps,  somewhat  more  generally  referred 
to  in  matters  of  criminal  and  civil  law  between  subject  and 
subject;  but  as  regards  Government  and  its  rights,  they 
were  only  quoted  (when  convenient)  with  a  certain  respect ; 
their  phraseology  was  also  adopted,  especially  by  the  more 
religious  of  the  Emperors  ;  but  in  reality  the  legal  '  'ashr,' 
and  '  khiraj,'  and  all  the  rest  of  it,  according  to  the  Musal- 
man  theory  of  conquest  and  taxation,  had  nothing  more 
than  a  nominal  or  theoretic  relation  to  the  land-revenue  as 
actually  levied  in  India. 

In  this  is  one  of  the  great  contrasts  between  Oriental  and 
European  rule.  The  moment  a  modern  Englishman  gets 
into  a  district,  his  law-abiding  soul  looks  for  some  Act  or 
rule,  or  some  '  Circular '  by  which  he  may  be  guided. 
Doubtless  the  '  paternal '  District  Officer  dislikes  the  '  sec- 
tion 10,  sub-section  3,'  that  prevents  him  making  the  order 
that  he  thinks  needed  for  the  particular  case  before  him, 
and  he  abhors  the  pleader,  with  his  niceties  and  technical 


248  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

difficulties ;  but,  all  the  same,  he  desires  a  substratum  of 
plain  and  solid  authority  on  which  to  rely.  He  will  have 
some  kind  of  standard  and  keep  to  it ;  he  will  be  content 
with  nothing  less,  and  he  will  sternly  prevent  any  one  from 
exacting  more.  His  revenue-demand  shall  be  assessed 
according  to  law,  under  the  supervision  of  Commissioners 
and  Boards,  with  the  one  idea  of  making  it  equal,  just, 
and  easily  borne :  but  once  fixed,  it  must  be  paid  in  full, 
regularly  and  to  the  day. 

The  Oriental  administrator,  on  the  contrary,  avoids  rigid 
rules,  and  rarely  attempts  definition.  That  is  why  every 
Indian  institution  connected  with  landed  rights  or  propri- 
etary interests,  often  presents  seemingly  contradictory  and 
irreconcileable  features  ;  a  man  is  what  we  call  a  landlord 
in  one  aspect,  and  something  quite  different  in  another 
aspect.  This  is  distraction  to  the  European  ruler.  To  the 
Oriental  mind  it  is  highly  satisfactory; — to  the  ruler, 
because  it  enables  him  to  do  what  he  pleases  ;  to  the  ruled, 
because  it  discovers  a  way  of  escape:  neither  can  be  caught 
between  the  bars  of  a  rule  and  made  to  feel — '  You  cannot 
do  this  because  it  is  illegal,'  or  (on  the  other  hand)  'You 
must  be  bound  to  submit  to  so  and  so,  because  your  legal 
position  as  a  "  proprietor  "  or  a  "  tenant "  (or  whatever  it  is) 
necessarily  involves  such  and  such  a  condition.'  He  can 
turn  one  face  or  the  other  to  the  outside,  and  act  on  this 
presentment  of  the  case  or  on  that,  as  it  suits  him,  caring 
nothing  for  legal  consistency  or  definiteness  of  principle. 

As  soon  as  circumstances  compelled  the  ruler  to  ex- 
change his  grain-share  for  a  money  payment,  the  earliest 
methods  were  quite  hap-hazard.  Great  rulers  like  Akbar, 
and  wise  ministers  like  Todar  Mai  or  Malik  'Arnbar  (in 
the  Dakhan)  no  doubt  endeavoured  to  propound  a  fixed, 
equitable  rule  for  assessing  land ;  but  they  could  not  bind 
their  successors. 

We  consequently  find  the  later  rulers  enhanced  the  land- 
revenue  from  time  to  time  as  they  pleased;  and  it  is 
absolutely  absurd  to  say  that  by  'ancient  law  and  con- 
stitution ' — or  what  not — they  could  not  do  so.  We  are  no 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-KEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  249 

doubt  credibly  informed  that  in  early  days  the  Rajas 
contented  themselves  with  their  '  sixth ' ;  and  no  doubt, 
as  long  as  there  was  peace,  and  cultivation  went 
on  prosperously,  there  was  little  or  no  temptation  to  take 
more.  But  in  more  recent  times  it  has  always  been 
the  fact  that  the  native  rulers  have  taken  to  the  full 
as  much  as  they  could  get.  But  how  ? — by  an  arbitrary, 
elastic,  method  of  alternate  squeezing  and  loosing.  Native 
rulers  have  always  been  ready  to  take  the  whole  in  good 
years,  but  have  rarely  shown  themselves  wanting  in  a 
perfectly  unsystematic  but  practically-working  sense  of 
adaptation  which  does  not  let  the  pressure  be  overdone 
in  a  bad  year1.  Any  definition  or  straightness  of  'law' 
would  have  militated  directly  against  this  most  obvious  and 
characteristic  feature  of  native  rule. 

And  in  all  cases  the  restraint  of  '  custom '  was  felt  by  all 
classes,  both  ruler  and  ruled.  The  'Amil  or  other  collector 
knew  exactly  how  far  the  golden  eggs  could  be  multiplied 
without  killing  the  goose  that  laid  them. 

When,  therefore,  we  refer  to  Manu  for  Hindu  ideas,  or  to 
the  Hiddyd  and  other  Muhammadan  text-books,  it  is  not 
because  these  have,  or  ever  had,  any  authority  as  practical 
statute-books — at  any  rate  in  the  realm  of  public  or  consti- 
tutional law — but  because  the  books  of  a  time  must  more 
or  less  reflect  the  ideas  of  the  people,  and  because,  of  course, 
a  pious  Hindu  or  a  religious  Muhammadan  prince  would 
always,  to  some  extent,  allow  the  value,  as  guides,  of  books 
written  by  sages  or  doctors  of  his  semi-sacred  law. 

We  may,  therefore,  quote  the  books,  but  remember  that 
the  only  general  '  law  and  constitution '  of  India  was,  that 
the  people  did  what  was  the  custom,  and  the  king  did 
what  he  chose.,  at  least  within  the  limits  of  the  possible — 
limits  which  the  elastic  Oriental  mind  has  ordinarily  well 
known  how  to  keep. 

1  I  speak  of  course  of  the  average  everything  and  left  depopulated 
fair-dealing  ruler.  There  have  been  villages  and  ruined  provinces  ;  but 
tyrants  here  and  there,  who  seized  these  were  exceptional. 


250  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

§  i.    The  Hindu  State  organization. 

Now  let  us  turn  backward,  and  place  ourselves,  in 
imagination,  in  the  days  when  a  regularly  established 
Hindu  State  was  in  working  order,  in  very  much  the 
condition  which  is  indicated  rather  than  described  in 
MANU'S  Institutes. 

The  whole  country  occupied  by  the  tribe  or  clan  who 
selected  and  conquered  the  locality,  was  first  divided  out 
into  large  territories  or  divisions,  and  the  central  and 
largest  (or  at  any  rate  the  best)  one  was  assigned  to  the 
head  chief  called  '  Raja  V 

Bound  about  him,  other  estates,  graduated  in  size,  were 
occupied  by  lesser  chiefs,  heads  of  tribal  groups  or  sections. 
These  would  be  represented  by  such  titles  as  'Thakur,' 
'  Rana,'  'Rao,'  or  'Babu2.'  Every  one  of  these  held  his  estate 
on  certain  terms  of  service  to  the  Raja,  which  I  will  pass 
over  without  more  detail  than  to  say  that  a  fine  was  paid 
on  succession ;  that  homage  was  done ;  that,  on  summons, 
the  chief  had  to  attend  with  his  force;  that  he  was  ex- 
pected to  aid  with  such  contributions  as  were,  in  times  of 
difficulty,  required.  In  some  parts  the  most  distant  of  the 
'  estates '  were  in  hilly  country ;  and  here  the  chief  was 
more  independent  than  the  rest,  and  was  expected  to  keep 
the  passes,  and  prevent  the  descent  of  neighbouring  hostile 
tribes  and  robbers  to  harass  the  dominions  of  the  Raja  and 
his  chiefs. 

Inside  the  Raja's  domain  or '  khalsa,'  as  the  later  Rajputs 
and  also  the  Sikhs  called  it,  the  greater  portion  of  the  land 
was  directly  under  the  control  of  the  king's  officers — a 
graded  series  of  district  and  village  authorities — and  a 
certain  portion  of  it  was  held  or  managed  under  royal 

1  See  Sterling's  account  of  Orissa  territory.' 

kingdoms  in  Asiatic  Researches,  vol.  2  This  term,  now  commonly  em- 

xv.  p.  220.    '  In  every  part  of  India,  ployed  to  designate  a  clerk  in  office, 

it    would    seem    that    under    the  really  applies  to  a  native  gentleman 

Hindus,  the   domains  reserved   for  of  wealth   and  position,  and   pri- 

the  Crown  constituted,  if  not  the  marily  (in  some   places)  indicates 

largest,  at  least  the  most  valuable  the  sons,  nephews,  &c.,  of  the  Raja 

and  productive  shares  of  the  whole  or  other  chief. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  25  I 

grant  or  assignment,  by  courtiers,  ministers  of  State,  chief 
judges,  and  military  officers,  as  well  as  by  the  younger  sons 
and  dependants  of  the  royal  house. 

The  Raja  enjoyed  two  main  sources  of  revenue: — 

I. — The  first  was  the  throne-right  (spoken  of  as  the  'gaddi' 
or  state  cushion)  with  a  right  to  certain  tolls  and  taxes,  transit 
duties  on  trade,  excise,  rights  in  the  forests  (if  there  were 
any) 1,  and  taxes  from  the  artisan  and  trading  classes. 

It  is  possible  that  if  the  other  chiefs  were  not  powerful, 
these  royal  rights  might  extend  over  their  domains  as  well. 

This  group  of  rights  was  indivisible,  or  went  to  the 
successor  of  the  Raja, — always  the  eldest  son  or  next  heir- 
male. 

II. — The  second  source  of  revenue  was  the  share  in  the 
grain  produce  of  every  bigha  of  cultivated  land,  already 
spoken  of. 

It  will  be  observed  that  just  as  the  Raja  took  this  share 
for  his  own  '  khalsa '  or  demesne  lands,  so  did  the  separate 
chiefs  in  their  estates :  the  Raja  took  no  grain-share  in 
them2.  Exactly  in  the  same  way,  where  the  Raja  made  a 
grant  (or  in  later  days  a  sale)  of  a  part  of  his  own  demesne 
lands  to  a  courtier  or  a  general,  &c.,  the  grantee  took  the 
share  (and  perhaps  some  of  the  other  taxes  and  tolls)  which 
would  otherwise  have  gone  to  the  king. 

This  fact  is  at  the  bottom  of  a  great  deal  connected  both 
with  land-tenures,  and  the  land-revenue.  And  we  have 
already  seen  how,  from  the  Raja's  grants  and  from  the 
break-up  of  the  territories,  village  landlord  communities 
have  arisen. 

Of  course  the  fate  of  the  ancient  Hindu  States  has  been 
very  various.  The  smaller  ones  have  often  fallen  out  of 
rank;  the  'Royal'  family  has  quarrelled;  the  estate  has 
split  up  like  those  just  mentioned,  and  dissolved  into  a 

1  See  Chap.  IV.  p.  128.  Coorg,  Malabar,  &c.,  the  fact  being 

a  The   reader  will   bear   this   in  that  the  mistake  arose  from  looking 

mind,  because  forgetfulness  of  it  has  at  lands  which  formed  chiefs'  es- 

been  the  source  of  a  great  deal  of  tates,  from  which  the  Raja  as  tribal 

nonsense  written   in   former   days  chief  never   did    take    a    royalty, 

about  there  never  having  been  any  whether  in  Malabar  or  in  any  other 

Royal  revenue-share  levied,  as  iu  country  where  Rajas  existed. 


252  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

number  of  village-landlord  families,  only  known  from  the 
rest  of  the  village  cultivators  by  their  higher  caste  and 
memories  of  a  more  dignified  origin  in  the  remote  past. 
In  other  cases  the  old  Hindu  kingdoms  were  either  sub- 
dued or  destroyed  before  the  conquest,— whether  of  the 
Afghan,  the  Mughal,  the  Maratha,  the  Sikh,  or  the  armies 
of  Olive  or  Wellesley  or  Lake. 

In  this  case,  the  Raja's  grain-share  passed  on  to  the  con- 
queror, or  succeeding  power.  If  the  Raja  had  been  killed 
in  battle,  or  had  fled,  there  was  no  one  to  share  or  diminish 
it ;  it  was  simply  collected  by  the  State  machinery  of  the 
conquering  king  or  emperor ;  if  the  Raja  survived  under 
the  conqueror  as  a  subordinate  noble,  he  was  probably  in- 
stalled by  royal  grant  as  a  '  Zamindar'  or  '  Taluqdar';  and 
continued  to  collect  the  grain-share  as  before,  but  had  now 
to  pass  on  a  portion — perhaps  the  greater  portion1 — to  the 
treasury  of  the  conqueror  ;  and  he  made  his  own  wealth  by 
other  privileges  which  in  the  end  left  him  richer  than 
before  ;  he  was  allowed  to  cultivate  the  waste,  and  take  the 
profits  for  himself;  he  was  gradually  allowed  to  bargain 
with  the  State  for  a  fixed  revenue  payment  and  keep  the 
difference  between  that  contract  sum  and  what  he  could 
collect  from  the  '  raiyats.'  Then  it  was  that  the  idea  of  the 
right  of  reassessing  the  revenue-share  from  time  to  time, 
ill-defined  as  that  practice  was,  inevitably  occurred  to 
him  ;  and  when,  under  our  own  rule,  the  title  in  the  land 
was  secured  to  the  Zamindars,  the  power  of  raising  the 
assessment  soon  developed  into  the  '  landlord,'  and  his  right 
of  '  enhancing '  the  '  rents,'  which  proved  such  a  source  of 
burning  discussion  for  after  years. 

But  this  is  to  anticipate  ;  we  must  first  consider  how  the 
Hindu  Revenue  Administration  was  conducted,  and  how  the 
system  fell  in  with  Muhammadan  ideas,  and  was  adopted 
by  the  Mughal  conquerors,  and  has  come  down,  in  a  modi- 
fied form,  to  the  British  Government. 

1  When,  in  later  days,  in  Bengal,  local  revenue,  the  theory  was  (and 
the  emperor's  deputy  allowed  the  at  first  the  practice)  that  nine- 
surviving  Rajas  (as  well  as  modern  tenths  of  the  whole  collections  were 
officials  and  farmers)  to  collect  the  passed  on  to  the  State  treasury. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  253 
6  3.    The  Internal  Administration. 

«     t ' 

Taking  what  was  probably  the  most  regularly  governed 
territory,  we  may  look  within  the  Raja's  demesne  to  see 
how  it  was  managed.  The  initial  grouping  of  lands  is  of 
course  the  '  village,'  and  to  this  unit  attention  was  mostly 
paid,  because  if  the  grain  collection  went  wrong  there, 
nothing  else  would  go  right.  In  the  last  chapter  we  have 
fully  gone  into  the  question  of  the  origin  of  villages,  and 
shown  how  cultivation  could  only  be  done  by  aggregates 
of  men  who  were  united  in  some  sort  of  bond  for  mutual 
society  and  protection.  Whether  the  villages  were  actually 
primaeval  settlements  of  tribes,  allotting  the  lands  accord- 
ing to  custom,  or  whether  they  were  later  foundations  by 
colonists  and  settlers,  it  was  natural  that  some  one  man 
should  take  the  lead  as  the  representative  of  the  village  ; 
and  as  the  collection  of  the  king's  share  at  the  threshing- 
floor  required  watching,  that  headman  was  naturally  drawn 
more  and  more  into  connection  with  the  State,  and  became 
in  fact  a  State  officer.  No  wonder,  then,  that  the  office 
soon  assumed  an  hereditary  character,  and  that,  what  with 
the  importance  his  State  connection  gave  him,  and  the 
emoluments  which  he  was  allowed  to  enjoy,  the  headman 
became  an  institution  so  useful,  that  he  survived  where 
many  other  institutions  gradually  disappeared.  The  fact 
that  every  village  from  which  the  king  drew  a  share,  had 
a  headman — alluded  to  in  the  early  books  as  the  '  grdmad- 
hikar,'  and  later  on  by  a  multitude  of  names  ('patel,' 
'mandal/  'pradhan,'  and  later  still,  'muqaddam'  and 
'  lambardar ') — became  a  recognized  universal  fact  of  village 
organization. 

But  the  headman  required  the  assistance  of  a  person  who 
could  write  and  do  sums  and  keep  the  accounts  of  the  col- 
lection, and  register  facts  regarding  the  land  and  its  culti- 
vators ;  so  that  a  village  '  patwari ' — the  '  gramalekhak ' 
(village-writer)  of  ancient  days — became  equally  a  neces- 
sary part  of  the  system. 

The  natural  land-unit  of  the  revenue  system  being  the 


254  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

village,  its  administration  furnished  the  pattern  for  all  the 
rest.  The  village  official  personnel  was,  for  Government 
purposes,  simply  repeated  in  wider  and  wider  circles,  first 
over  a  smaller  area,  and  then  again,  over  a  still  larger  area 
such  as  we  now  call  a  district. 

As  regards  the  '  district,'  there  are  allusions  in  Manu  to 
'  a  lord  over  1000  villages ' ;  and  we  have  traces,  in  parts  of 
India,  both  of  the  ancient  districts  and  of  the  officers  who 
presided  over  them,  still  remembered  in  later  Hindu  dia- 
lects as  '  sirdesmukh  '  (chief  head  of  a  '  des  ')  ;  with  him  an 
accountant  of  the  district  was  also  recognized.  But  the 
most  generally  used  and  best  known  division  was  that 
which  was  smaller  than  a  '  district'  and  comprised  the  charge 
of  eighty-four  villages  or  some  similar  group.  It  is  better 
known  to  us  by  the  later  (Muhammadan)  name  of  'par- 
gana.'  It  was  always  adopted  by  the  Mughal  system,  and 
the  parganas  into  which  the  country  was  then  divided, 
are  almost  everywhere  known  to  this  day.  In  Maratha 
countries,  and  by  the  Sikhs,  the  same  division  was 
known  by  the  name  '  talukaV 

The  pargana  or  taluka  official  staff  just  repeated  that  of 
the  village,  only  in  the  larger  jurisdiction.  There  was  the 
'  desmukh '  or  pargana  headman,  and  the  '  des-pandya,'  or 
desai,  who  kept  the  pargana  accounts.  The  former,  as  we 
shall  see,  became  the  '  chaudhari '  of  later  times,  and  the 
latter  the  '  qanungo.'  Directly  under  these  were  the  villages  ; 
unless  indeed  for  certain  purposes,  a  circle  of  villages  was 
locally  recognized  and  called  a  'tappa,' — intermediate 
between  the  pargana  and  the  single  village. 

It  seems  that  from  very  early  times  these  officials  were 
paid  (wholly  or  partly)  by  holding  land  revenue-free  in 
virtue  of  their  office,  which  is  exactly  the  '  watan  '  it  after- 
wards came  to  be  called  in  Central  India  and  Bombay2. 
'  Let  the  lord  of  ten  villages,'  says  Manu,  '  enjoy  the  produce 
of  two  plough  lands  (or  as  much  ground  as  can  be  tilled 

1  This    was     the    Arabic    word      write  it  so. 

'  ta'alluqa,'  but  as  it  was  adopted  as  2  See  Chapter  IV,  on  Land  Ten- 

a  Hindi  word  in  the  form  taluka,  I      ures,  p.  180. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  255 

with  two  ploughs),  the  lord  of  twenty  that  of  ten  ploughs, 
the  lord  of  100  that  of  a  village,  the  lord  of  1000  that  of 
a  large  village.'  Traces  of  this  holding  of  service-lands  (ser- 
vice I  here  use  of  official  service  as  distinct  from  laud  held 
for  military  service)  we  shall  meet  with  all  over  India  ;  it 
extended  not  only  to  the  village,  subdivision,  and  district 
headmen  and  account-keepers,  but  to  the  watchmen,  priests, 
and  even  artisans  of  the  villages.  The  reason  why  the 
official  holdings,  as  a  direct  origin  of  a  peculiar  land-tenure, 
survived  so  in  Central  and  Western  India,  and  to  a  lesser 
extent  in  the  South,  and  disappeared  in  the  North,  is  that 
in  the  former  countries  the  Muhammadan  kings  were  even 
more  respectful  to  local  institutions  than  the  Mughals  ;  and 
though  the  Mughal  Empire  at  last  extended  over  the  Dakhan, 
its  duration  was  brief  and  its  hold  imperfect.  The  Maratha 
rulers,  who  followed  the  Mughals,  were  Hindu,  and  there- 
fore imbued  with  the  spirit  of  the  universal  Hindu  system. 
Averse  to  revenue-free  holdings  as  they  were,  they  did  not 
dare  to  interfere  with  such  a  deeply-rooted  institution  as 
the  Hindu  official's  hereditary  land-holding. 


§  4.    The  Mughal  Revenue-organization. 

How  very  generally  the  Mughals  preserved  the  Hindu 
system,  only  with  some  attempt  at  definition  and  with  the 
adoption  of  Perso-Arabic  official  terms  for  everything — 
terms  that  have  come  down  to  our  own  officers — is  well 
known  through  the  description  given  by  Ab-ul-Fazl  (Akbar's 
minister)  in  his  Ayin-i-Akbari,  and  through  other  his- 
torians. 

The  great  provinces,  like  Bengal,  Oudh  (in  later  times), 
the  Dakhan,  Allahabad,  &c.,  were  the  grand  divisions,  and 
were  designated  '  SiibaV  Each  Siiba  was  primarily  divided 

1  Before  the  Mughal  times,  some  (officially  called  Subadar)  threw  off 

of  them,  as  Bengal  and  Jaunpur,  their  allegiance  and  set  up  as  sepa- 

had     been     independent    Afghan  rate  States.     Oudh,  and  the  State  of 

kingdoms,     and     became     Miighal  the   Nizam    of  Hyderabad   in    the 

Siibas.     Again   in  the  days  of  de-  Dakhan,  are  familiar  examples, 
cline,  the  Nawabs  or  other  governors 


256  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BEITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

into  districts  (but  larger  than  our  present  districts)  called 
'  SirkarV 

The  Sirkar  was  divided  into  parganas  (sometimes  called 
mahals),  and  these,  for  sojne  purposes,  were  aggregated  into 
contiguous  groups  called  '  dastiir ' 2  (or  dastur-ul-'aml) — a 
grouping  which  does  not  appear  long  to  have  survived,  or 
to  have  had  any  great  importance. 

In  the  reign  of  Shah  Jahan,  another  subdivision  was 
recognized,  that  of '  chakla ' :  it  was  a  division  of  the  Suba. 
Thus,  in  Bengal,  in  the  time  of  Ja'far  Khan,  the  Suba  was 
divided  into  thirty-two  Sirkars  or  into  thirteen  chaklas3. 
We  read  of  the  Company  being  granted,  in  1 760,  the  '  chakla ' 
of  Bardwan  in  Bengal. 

In  Akbar's  time  the  important  revenue  officer  was  the 
''amil'  (or  'amlguzar),  who  supervised  the  village  collections 
of  his  district,  and  adjusted  the  assessments  on  the  prin- 
ciples of  the  Settlement  made  during  this  reign.  The  'amil's 
jurisdiction  was  not  determined  by  area,  but  according  to 
the  amount  of  revenue  under  his  control.  Thus  it  would 
happen  that  the  charge  would  be  small  where  the  land  was 
well  populated  and  highly  cultivated,  and  larger  in  a  poor 
and  barren  country.  The  'amil  was  in  after  times  called 
'  Karori ' — the  officer  who  collected  a  '  crore '  (ten  million = 
Karor)  of  '  dams  '  (i.  e.  R.  2,50,000) 4.  Still  later,  the  Ka- 
rori's  duty  was  restricted  to  revenue-collection,  the  assess- 
ments being  made  by  another  officer  (amin-faujdar),  in 
subordination  to  whom  the  Karori  acted. 

1  Incorrectly    written     '  Circar.'  known  in  Oudh,  not  in  the  North- 
Thus  we  read  of  the  Northern  Cir-  Western  Provinces.    In  Bengal  cer- 
cars  of  Madras.     It  was  suggested  tainly  the  Chakla  was  not  part  of 
that  each  Suba   should  consist  of  a  Sirkar,  but  a  larger  district,  as 
twenty-two  Sirkars,  and  each  Sirkar  the  numbers  in  the  text  show.    The 
of  twenty-two  parganas,  but  this  '  Chakladar'  was  the  District  Officer, 
was  only  an  idea  never  realised  in  and  the  '£mil  was  under  him  for  one 
practice.  or    more    '  parganas  '  :    the    'amil 

2  Beames'  Elliott's  Glossary,  vol.  ii.  might  be  alone,  or  there  might  also 
p.  20  et  seq.  be   a  revenue-farmer  at  the  same 

*  Fifth    Report,    vol.    i.     19,    389.  time.   (North-Western  Provinces  Gazette, 

Beames'   Elliott's   Glossary   speaks  of  vii.  107  note.) 

the   '  Chakla '   as   a   division   of  a  *  The  '  dam '  was  a  small  copper 

'  Sirkar,'     somewhat    larger    than  coin,  of  somewhat  doubtful  value  ; 

a  modern  '  district '  but  less  than  in  Akbar's  time,  it   is  said,  forty 

a  Commissioner's  division.     It  was  went  to  the  rupee. 


CHAP.v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  257 

For  each  pargana  there  was  a  district  accountant- 
registrar,  called  '  Kanungo  '  (Qamingo  =  one  who  declares 
the  rule  or  standard).  He  was  the  Hindu  '  Des-pandya.' 
The  executive  officer  of  the  pargana  was  called  Chaudhari, 
the  old  Hindu  '  des-mukh.' 


§  5.   The  Jdgir  System. 

One  other  feature  of  the  Mughal  system  should  be  men- 
tioned. Just  as  the  Hindus  divided  the  whole  country 
into  the  royal  domains  and  chiefs  domains,  so  the  Mughals 
apportioned  their  territory  into  'khalsa '  and  'jagir'  lands. 
The  former  was  divided  into  charges,  and  managed  by 
'amils  and  State  officials,  as  just  described.  The  rest  was 
divided  out  into  blocks,  or  estates,  which  were  made  over 
for  life  (the  grants  became  hereditary  at  a  later  stage)  to 
certain  military  commanders,  ministers,  and  courtiers,  who 
took  the  revenues  for  their  own  support,  or  that  of  a  mili- 
tary force  which  they  were  bound  to  maintain.  Probably 
the  idea  was  copied  from  the  Hindu  system.  Sometimes 
waste  tracts  were  granted  in  'jagir,'  and  sometimes  out- 
lying and  troublesome  districts.  The  jagirdar  managed 
the  whole,  increased  the  cultivation,  and  applied  the  re- 
venue to  his  own  support,  and  to  the  expenses  of  the 
administration  and  the  pay  of  troops.  While  a  strict 
control  lasted,  the  jagirdar  was  bound  to  take  no  more 
than  the  sum  assigned ;  and  if  more  came  into  his  hands, 
he  had  rigidly  to  account  for  the  surplus  to  the  State 
treasury 1.  The  system  of  assigning  the  revenues  of  a 
tract  as  a  reward  for  good  service,  or  the  support  of  troops, 
is  a  regular  Oriental  method,  and  has  been  continued  in 
our  own  times  in  a  modified  form. 

1  The  system  of  Jaglrs,  which  has  chapter,  is  more  fully  explained  in 
also  been  touched  on  in  the  last  the  chapter  on  Bengal  Tenures. 


VOL.  I. 


258  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 


§  6.   Farming  or  Contracting  Systems. 

The  last  phase  in  the  administration  was  that  which 
marked  the  later  days  of  the  Empire  after  the  death  of 
Aurangzeb. 

I  have  already  explained T  how  important  it  was  for  the 
Mughal  rulers  to  conciliate,  and  if  possible  make  use  of,  the 
old  Rajas,  who,  though  yielding  submission  to  the  conqueror, 
were  only  too  likely  to  give  trouble  directly  a  chance  of 
revolt  occurred.  This  circumstance  led  to  the  appointment 
of  Rajas  to  collect,  or  rather  to  contract  for,  certain  defined 
sums  of  revenue  required  from  their  territories.  I  have  also 
explained  how,  in  days  of  disorder  and  feeble  rule,  such  a 
plan  of  contracting  for  a  fixed  sum  of  revenue  saved  all  the 
trouble  of  local  control,  and  so  was  generally  adopted  ;  and 
then,  not  only  old  territorial  chiefs,  but  speculators,  courtiers, 
and  quondam  officials,  were  allowed  to  become  revenue- 
farmers,  either  of  parganas  or  of  larger  or  smaller  areas, 
according  to  their  means  and  spheres  of  influence.  Their 
territories  were  spoken  of  as  the  '  ihtimdm,'  or  charge.  A 
Raja,  a  chaudhari,  or  a  speculator  with  no  title  at  all,  thus 
appointed  to  manage  the  tract  under  his  influence,  would 
be  equally  designated  as  the  '  landholder '  or  '  Zamindar ' 
of  his  territory,  and  would  be  so  called  in  the  '  sanad,'  or 
official  warrant  of  his  appointment.  A  person  allowed  a 
somewhat  less  important  tract  on  the  same  terms  (and  some- 
times made  subordinate  to  a  '  Zamindar ')  would  be  called 
'  Taluqdar.'  In  Oudh,  the  title  of  '  Taluqddr  '  was  applied, 
with  no  suggestion  of  inferior  rank,  to  holders  of  estates  of 
the  first  class2. 

At  first,  the  duty  of  such  a  '  landholder '  was  strictly  to 
gather  the  revenues  of  the  villages,  and  retain  only  his  own 
recognized  share  of  the  total,  which  was  usually  one-tenth, 

1  See  Chap.  IV.  p.  185.  mindar '   had    acquired    a    special 

2  Possibly  it  was  that  the  Oudh  meaning  in  Oudh,  and  was  applied 
Taluqs  were  not  so  large  as  the  dis-  to  grantees  or  others  who  had  the 
tricts  of  Bengal  Zamindars  :  but  I  management  of  single  villages, 
think  it  likely  that  the  term  '  za- 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  259 

besides  making  certain  other  deductions,  all  exactly  speci- 
fied and  accounted  for.  But  in  time  the  strictness  was 
relaxed,  and  the  '  Zamindars '  were  simply  required  to  make 
good  a  lump-sum,  raised  from  time  to  time,  and  partaking 
more  and  more  of  the  nature  of  a  bargain.  Under  such  a 
system,  oppression  of  the  country  people  was  sure  to  follow. 
All  regular  assessments,  and  authorized  revisions  of  land- 
revenues,  were  further  and  further  abandoned 1.  The 
Treasury  authorities  of  the  province  merely  increased 
their  demands  on  the  '  Zamindar '  by  adding  extra  cesses, 
giving  them  this  name  or  that,  according  to  the  par- 
ticular necessity  or  fancy  that  originated  them.  These 
amounts  had,  of  course,  to  be  got  out  of  the  villages — 
with  a  good  deal  more  besides.  In  the  days  of  decline, 
as  we  shall  see,  both  in  Oudh  and  Bengal,  an  occasional 
vigorous  governor  would  make  a  desperate  grasp  at  the 
reins  of  revenue-control ;  for  a  time  the  revenue-farming,  or 
Zamindari  management,  would  be  set  aside,  and  an  attempt 
made  to  return  to  village  collections  through  the  pargana 
officials ;  but  always  without  lasting  result.  Exactly 
the  same  thing  happened  in  the  first  days  of  British  rule. 
Zamindars  were  set  aside,  and  other  local  collectors  tried  ; 
but  in  vain.  The  Zamindari  system  had  become  the  only 
one  by  which  the  revenues  could  be  secured ;  at  least, 
without  aji  entirely  new  system,  which  would  have  in- 
volved a  survey  of  the  lands,  and  other  steps,  which  were 
not  possible  at  the  time,  even  if  anyone  had  thought  of 
them. 

1  Farming  the   revenues   (a    bad  (home-farm)   at   privileged    rates.' 

example  which  was  often  copied  in  The  farmer,  however,  was  bound 

our  first  essays  at  management)  was  to  let  the  tenant's  rates  alone  for 

always  the  resource  either  of  go-  the  period  of  his  lease.     The  Ro- 

vernments   in   their  decline  or  of  hillas  certainly  succeeded  from   a 

mere  marauders  like  the  Rohillas.  financial  point  of  view.    They  raised 

The  Marathas  adopted  it  also  when  from  Bareilly  a  sum  nearly  equal  to 

their  position  was  not  secure.     The  sixteen   lakhs   of  our  currency  in 

Rohillas  made  farming  the  corner-  1754,  which  is  not  far  short  of  the 

stone  of  their  financial  system,  and  assessment    120    years    later.     But 

it  is   still   in  force   in   the    small  after  twenty- five  years  of  the  Nawab 

Roh  ilia  State  of  Rampur.     '"Pro-  Wazir's;0udh^  rule,  the  revenue  had 

prietors  "  were  not  recognized  ;  the  fallen  to  half  that  amount. — (Review 

only  favour  conceded  to  landholders  of  Bareilly  Settlement  Report,  p.  5. ) 
was  permission  to  hold  their  "  sir" 

8   2 


260  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

How  this  contract  system  spread  all  over  Bengal,  and 
over  the  upper  part  of  Madras ;  how,  in  a  modified  form, 
it  was  adopted  in  Oudh,  and  to  a  much  less  extent  and  in 
a  different  form,  it  prevailed  in  Northern  India ;  how  it 
was  only  allowed  by  the  Maratha"s  to  a  limited  extent,  and 
for  individual  villages  ;  and  how,  wherever  adopted,  it 
produced  various  effects  on  the  land-tenures,  I  have  already 
given  some  idea  in  the  last  chapter.  Here  I  must  return 
to  the  revenue-administration,  and  pass  on  to  notice  the 
changes  that  followed  from  the  example  set  by  the  Mughal 
Empire,  in  later  Hindu  States — Rajput,  Maratha,  and  Sikh. 
Indeed,  they  were  very  slight.  When  we  look  to  the 
organization  of  Rajput  States,  as  we  find  them  after  the 
time  of  Akbar — whose  policy  had  been  to  encourage  and 
gain  the  support  of  the  Rajput  princes — we  find  a  number 
of  Persian  revenue  terms  gradually  introduced,  but  the 
administration  essentially  the  same  as  that  of  the  early 
kingdoms. 

Exactly  the  same  thing  happened  when  Maratha  States 
rose  on  the  ruins  of  the  Muhammadan  and  Pathan  king- 
doms, and  when  the  Sikh  States  took  the  place  of  the 
Afghan  governor  in  the  Panjab. 


§  7.    Post-Mughal  Hindu  Administration. 

The  Hindus  always  held  to  the  system  I  have  already 
described, — the  allotment  of  the  whole  territory  into  tracts 
governed  by  the  Raja  or  overlord,  and  tracts  governed  by 
his  '  feudal '  chiefs ;  and  I  have  before  alluded  to  their 
recognition  of  estates  called  bhumiya — holdings  which  were 
virtually  proprietary  estates  but  of  inferior  rank,  because 
the  holders  were  proprietors,  not  governors.  The  direct 
management  was  by  heads  of  districts,  practically  the  same 
as  the  Muhammadan  'pargana,'  and  called  taluka;  under 
these  were  subdivisions  called  '  tappa,'  and  then  came  the 
villages. 

The  only  remarkable  fact  is  this,  that  the  later  Hindu 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  261 

States  adopted  many  Perso-Arabic  terms  derived  from  the 
Muhammadan  system1. 


§  8.    Mardthd  Revenue  System. 

For  central  government  each  Maratha  State  had  a  Divvan 
or  Minister.  Under  him  was  the  Fard-navis,  a  sort  of 
Financial  Minister,  and  with  him  the  Mazum-  (or  Majmu'a) 
-dar,  or  Registrar.  There  was  also  a  Chitta-navfs  (letter- 
writer  or  Secretary),  a  '  Sikka-navis,'  who  kept  the  Prince's 
seal,  and  a  '  Pot-navis,'  or  Treasury  Officer.  This  group 
formed  the  '  Secretariat '  or  State  Department. 

In  the  districts,  a  considerable  territory  was  in  charge  of 
a  '  kamavisdar,'  who  had  deputies  in  each  subdivision.  The 
deputy,  again,  in  each  patta,  subdivision,  or  tappa,  was  aided 
by  a  'karkun'  or  agent.  The  minor  subdivisions  varied 
according  to  convenience.  The  Marathas  sometimes  con- 
tinued the  use  of  the  Muhammadan  '  sirkar '  and  '  pargana,' 
and  sometimes  spoke  of  the  '  taluka.'  The  '  tappa  '  used 
by  them  was  larger  than  a  pargana,  and  was  subdi- 
vided into  'zilas2.'  But  each  district  was  not  left  to 
the  kamavisdar  alone :  his  authority  was  shared  by  an 
officer  called  the  'zamindar.'  Here  we  have  another  mean- 
ing for  this  Protean  term.  The  zamindar  was,  in  fact,  the 
old  '  desrnukh '  with  a  new  name ;  he  was  the  executive 
head  collector  ;  and  the  kamavisdar  was  really  put  in  as 
a  spy  or  check  on  him  to  prevent  his  absorbing  the  revenue. 
Of  course  the  kanungo  or  district  accountant  was  main- 
tained, and  he  ranked  next  below  the  '  zamindar.' 

§  9.    Later  Rajput  States. 

The  later  Rajput  States  had,  and  still  have,  an  exactly 
similar  system,  only  with  different  names  :  thus  the  diwan 

1  Just  as  the  Sikhs  adopted  Per-  from  the  use  later  acquired,  where 

sian     for    the     official     or     Court  '  zila' '  was  adopted  in  the  Regula- 

language.  tions,   for   the   district    embracing 

8  Malcolm,  vol.  ii.  p.  4.     The  term  several  parganas. 
'zila','  as  here  locally  used,is  different 


262  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

was  called  '  kamdar  '  =  charge  d'affaires ;  the  fard-navis  was 
called  '  daftari,'  and  so  forth. 

It  should  be  remembered  that  certain  tracts  were 
either  held  by  renters  or  farmers,  or  by  'jagirdars,' 
military  and  other  assignees  of  the  revenue  of  certain 
areas ;  and  in  these  tracts  the  official  collectors  did  not 
interfere. 

The  Marathas,  and  the  better  Rajput  chiefs,  were  careful 
of  their  territories.  'All  ground,'  says  Sir  J.  Malcolm1,  'be 
it  ever  so  waste  or  hilly,  is  included  in  the  divisions  (par- 
gana,  tappa,  taluka,  &c.)  which  are  marked  by  natural  or 
artificial  boundaries,  such  as  rivers,  water-courses,  ranges 
of  hills,  trees,  rocks,  ridges,  or  lines  between  any  two  re- 
markable objects.  The  lands  were  measured,  including  the 
space  occupied  by  banks,  walls,  houses,  &c.,  in  the  time  of 
the  Mughal  Government ;  and  this  record  of  measurement 
was  lodged  in  the  office  of  every  zaminddr  of  a  district  as 
well  as  in  the  fard-navis'  (State  Secretary's)  office.  Several 
of  these  records  have  been  saved  ;  but  where  they  are  not, 
the  ease  with  which  the  memory  of  the  respective  limits 
was  preserved  by  the  hereditary  officers  of  the  district  and 
village  to  whom  this  duty  belongs,  is  very  extraordinary.' 

§  10.   -Sikh  System  in  the  Punjab. 

When  the  Sikh  Government  succeeded  to  the  Muslim 
dominions  in  the  Panj&b,  they  followed  the  same  system. 
I  may  pass  over  the  first  short  period  when  the  confederate 
and  equal  chiefs  (grouped  in  what  were  called  'misl') 
divided  the  country  into  a  multitude  of  '  taluqas2.'  Soon 
the  genius  of  Ranjit  Singh  prevailed,  and  he  became  King 
(or  Maharaja)  and  made  the  other  chiefs  '  feudal '  lords  and 
governors  of  districts  under  him.  These  governors  he  called 
'  Jagirdar,  or  '  Diwan,'  or  '  Nazim,'  as  the  case  might  be. 
Under  these,  again,  were  districts  of  manageable  size  (talu- 

1  Vol.  ii.  p.  5.  course   quarrelled,   and   very  soon 

2  The  Sikh  dominion  commenced  they  were  reduced  under  one  head, 
with   a   sort   of   confederacy  of    a  See   Hunter's  India   (Gaz,  vol.   vi. 
number  of  equal  chiefs.     They  of  p.  410,  and  edition.) 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  263 

qas),  and  '  Kardars '  were  the  presiding  officers,  who  assessed 
and  collected  the  revenues. 


§  n.    Resume  of  Native  Systems. 

In  short,  the  student  will  bear  in  mind  that  the  Mughal 
system,  as  introduced  by  Akbar  and  his  successors  (before 
that  organization  was  virtually  replaced  by  the  system  of 
revenue-farming},  was,  in  fact,  the  old  Hindu  model. 
The  Hindu  States  always  kept  it  up,  only  that  they 
preferred  several  of  the  Persian  names  that  the  Mughal 
Empire  had  introduced.  The  fact  was,  that  while  the 
early  Hindu  system  had  been  one  without  any  survey 
or  measurement,  and  without  any  records  to  speak  of, 
the  Mughal  rulers  crystallized  it  into  more  business-like 
permanence,  by  measuring  and  recording  villages,  parganas, 
and  'sirkars'  with  their  revenue  assessment.  Once  fixed, 
the  local  hereditary  officers  became  the  depositaries  of  the 
measures,  rules,  and  facts  (qamingo  means  the  officer  who 
'  declares '  the  '  rule,'  measure,  or  law  in  revenue  matters). 
All  later  Governments  were  glad  to  avail  themselves  of 
these  records;  and  the  old  formal  assessment  of  Akbar's 
date  formed  a  sort  of  basis  or  fundamental  assessment, 
remembered  with  almost  superstitious  reverence,  though 
of  course  it  was  altered  and  increased  according  to  circum- 
stances, and  no  one  really  expected  to  be  assessed  according 
to  it,  unless  he  conceived  a  right  to  hold  at  fixed  rates,  which 
was  thus  expressed.  Briefly,  the  essential  features  of  all 
historic  revenue-management,  whether  Rajput,  Mughal, 
Maratha,  or  Sikh,  have  been  the  following,  under  whatever 
variety  of  names : — 

(1)  the  village,  with  its  headman  and  accountant ; 

(2)  very  frequently  there  was  an  intermediate  grouping 

of  villages  forming  a  'tappa,'  under  a  minor  civil 
officer  and  staff;  this  is  not  always  found ; 

(3)  a  larger  district  forming  a  pargana  or  taluka,  under  a 

district  headman  (kardar,  'amil,  chaudhari,  karorf, 
&c.),  and  aided  by  an  accountant  (kanungo) ; 


264  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

(4)  Several  parganas  united  into  a  sirkar  (or  locally  a 
chakla)  under  a  Diwan,  Nazim,  &c. 

Wherever  revenue-farming  arrangements  were  introduced 
in  the  late  Mughal  days,  it  was  on  a  large  scale  ;  and  the 
local  magnate  who  became  contractor,  first  atrophied  and 
then  obliterated  the  local  revenue  staff;  whereas,  when  the 
Marathas  and  Sikhs  adopted  farming  it  was  chiefly  by 
single  villages  or  small  taluqas. 


SECTION  III. — ANCIENT  AUTHORITIES  REGARDING  THE 
'KING'S  SHARE.' 

§  i.    The  Hindu  Theory. 

I  have  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  the  earlier  races 
who  preceded  the  Aryans — or,  as  I  call  them,  Rajputs, 
according  to  their  later  and  surviving  name — did  not  origin- 
ally accord  their  king  a  share  in  the  grain-heap  of  every 
village  in  his  dominion,  but  allotted  him  the  entire  produce 
of  certain  lands.  In  Chutiya  Nagpur,  for  instance,  among 
the  Dravidian  races,  and  among  the  Gonds  and  others  of 
Central  and  South  India,  we  find  distinct  traces  of  the 
allotment  of  areas  for  the  king,  ministers,  and  so  on,  down 
to  the  village  heads1.  But  even  there  the  practice  gradu- 
ally grew  up  of  taking  a  grain-share  from  the  other  lands 
also.  And  this  practice  became  universal.  The  Hindu 
States  always  took  a  grain-share  for  the  king  in  his 
territories,  and  for  the  chiefs  in  theirs. 

The  idea  of  a  '  share '  for  the  king  seems  to  have  been  a 
very  early  one  :  thus  Sir  John  Malcolm  quotes  the  Mahd- 
bhdrata  as  alluding  to  the  origin  of  kings :  '  Mankind ' 
(says  the  author)  '  were  continually  opposing  each  other, 
and  they  at  last  went  to  Brahma  to  ask  him  to  appoint  a 
king  over  them.  Manu  was  directed  to  be  their  king.  He 
replied,  "  I  fear  a  sinful  action :  government  is  arduous, 
especially  among  ever-lying  men."  They  said,  "  Fear  not ; 

1  See  also  the  section  on  Chutiya'  Nagpur  Tenures  (Bengal). 


CHAP.v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  265 

you  will  receive  a  recompense : — of  beasts  a  fiftieth  part, 
and  also  of  gold,  and  we  will  give  you  a  tenth  of  the  corn, 
increasing  your  store,"'  &C.1  Manu  (chap.  vii.  127-130) 
says :  '  Of  cattle,  of  gems,  of  gold  and  silver,  added  each 
year  to  the  capital  stock  [the  king's  share  is]  a  fiftieth 
part2,  of  grain  an  eighth  part,  or  a  sixth  or  a  twelfth, 
according  to  the  difference  of  the  soil  and  the  labour  neces- 
sary to  cultivate  it.'  In  Chap,  x,  v.  118,  it  is  admitted 
that  the  share  may  be  raised  to  one-fourth  of  the  crops  at 
a  time  of  urgent  necessity,  as  in  war  or  invasion ;  and  so 
the  tax  on  the  mercantile  classes  may  be  raised.  It  was 
noticed  that  in  Alexander's  time  the  cultivators  were 
already  contributing  one-fourth  of  the  grain3.  In  the  great 
southern  Hindu  kingdom  -of  Bijanagar  or  Vijayanagar 
(which  lasted  till  the  seventeenth  century),  the  Minister 
Vidyaranya  declared  that  a  king  who  took  more  than  one- 
sixth  '  shall  be  deemed  impious  in  this  world,  and  shall  be 
cast  into  hell-flames  in  the  next4.' 

Colonel  Wilks,  in  his  History  of  Mysore,  has  given  other 
instances  of  the  southern  kingdoms  taking  one-sixth5. 

Harihar  Hai,  who  was  one  of  the  early  kings  of  Bijanagar 
(A.D.  1334-47),  is  said  to  have  divided  the  grain  thus  :  half, 
including  the  straw,  to  the  cultivator ;  and  the  remaining 
half  was  made  into  three  shares,  one  of  which  went  to  the 
king,  one  to  the  overlord  or  '  proprietor  '  of  the  village,  and 
one-third  to  priests  and  the  religious  classes  ;  but  the  latter 
the  king  also  took,  on  the  plea  that  he  supported  the 
priests  6. 

From  the  many  allusions  in  books,  it  seems  probable 
that,  as  long  as  the  old  kingdoms  were  at  peace,  the  tradi- 

1  Malcolm,  vol.  i.  p.  231,  note.  Wilks  tells  us  of  a  Pandyan  king 

2  Briggs  notices  that  in  the  time  invading  Kanara  in  the  thirteenth 
of  Tavernier  the  king  took  two  per  century,  who  made  the  people  give 
cent,  of  the  gems    found  at    Gol-  him  the  sixth  of  husked  rice,  thus 
khanda   (the    celebrated    diamond  adding  ten  per  cent,   to  the   con- 
mines,  then  worked).  tribution  at  one  stroke. 

3  Strabo,  lib.  xv.  1030  ;  and  Dio-  6  See  this  more  fully  described, 
dorus    Siculus,   ii.    53,   quoted    by  and  the  curious  method  of  calculating 
Briggs.  the  produce  by  a  certain  multiple 

4  Briggs,  p.  62.  of  the  seed  sown,  described  in  Sir 

5  But  it  seerns  that  the  sixth  was  T.  Munro's  Minute  on  Kanara,  given 
enlarged  very  easily.   Thus,  Colonel  in  Arbuthnot,  p.  61  of  vol.  i. 


266  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

tional  sixth  was  adhered  to1.  The  king  had  no  expanding 
administrations  nor  demands  like  those  on  a  modern 
government ;  and  as  long  as  the  revenue-share  came  in 
regularly,  and  as  it  was  moderately  increased  by  increase  of 
cultivation  and  by  the  other  tolls  and  dues  which  the  king 
levied,  he  had  no  great  temptation  to  raise  the  share,  at  any 
rate  formally  and  openly.  But  there  always  comes  a  time 
when  invasion  and  war  and  other  difficulties  disturb  affairs  ; 
and  in  later  days  we  shall  find  Hindu  kingdoms,  no  less 
than  others,  raising  the  revenue  freely. 

In  other  places,  the  share  of  two-fifths  was  commonly 
levied,  and  the  '  panchdo '  is  still  a  traditionally  common 
proportion  of  grain-produce,  now  paid  to  a  '  proprietor '  who 
has  intervened  between  the  cultivator  and  the  king. 

The  '  Fifth  Report '  gives  many  more  details  as  to  the 
extent  of  shares  taken  at  different  times  2.  What  the  Sikh 
demand  was,  will  appear  fully  in  the  chapter  on  the  Panjab 
Revenue  System. 

It  is  unnecessary,  however,  to  go  into  further  detail, 
because,  whatever  was  the  early  practice,  and  whatever  its 
causes  and  its  duration,  it  is  quite  certain,  as  Campbell 
remarks,  that  in  later  times  the  practice  in  all  States — a 
practice  that  can  be  traced  back  before  the  end  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  at  any  rate — was  to  take  a  half  of  the 
grain  in  some  cases,  and  in  places  where  money  assess- 
ments were  levied,  as  much  as  could  be  got  without  driving 

1  Indeed,  Abul  Fazl,  in  the  Ayin-  for  the  royal  '  privy  purse.'  No 

i-Akbari,  says  the  Hindu  custom  public  works,  no  army,  and  no 

was  to  take  one-sixth  (of  the  gross  police  had  to  be  maintained  out  of 

produce).  And  see  M.  Williams'  it.  The  army  was  supported  by  the 

translation  of  the  Sakuntald,  Act  II.  estates  on  the  feudal  system,  and  so 

p.  49.  with  the  police  as  far  as  there  was 

"Vol.  ii.  pp.  411,  462,  472-3;  any  distinct  from  the  military  force, 

see  also  Hunter's  Orissa,  vol.  i.  p.  And  when  the  great  tanks,  bathing 

32-5  ;  Campbell  (Cobden  Club  Papers),  places,  and  other  works  which  are 

p.  155.  See  also  Sir  T.  Munro's  now  looked  on  with  just  admiration 

opinion  in  a  Minute  at  page  92  of  as  showing  the  wealth,  power,  and 

Arbuthnot,  vol.  i.  See  also  note  in  wisdom  of  the  old  kings,  were  made, 

Phillips,  p.  227,  showing  that  there  it  was  chiefly  by  unpaid  labour, 

was  no  real  limit  on  the  share.  It  or  at  least  by  labour  fed  with  food 

should  be  remembered  with  refer-  taken  from  the  neighbourhood.  All 

ence  to  the  supposed  moderation  of  this  cannot  be  ignored  in  comparing 

the  '  one-sixth,'  that  it  really  re-  the  modern  system  with  the 

presented  little  more  than  a  charge  ancient. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  267 

the  raiyats  to  abscond  into  the  jungle,  and  by  the  carefully 
elastic  mode  of  exaction  which  the  old  rulers  were  so 
clever  in  applying. 


§  2.   Muhammadan  theory  of  Land-Revenue. 

I  will  now  briefly  allude  to  the  Muhammadan  law  theory 
of  the  revenue — not,  as  I  have  already  said,  because  the 
Mughals  really  understood  it  or  carried  it  out,  but  because 
it  was  sometimes  convenient  for  the  orthodox  to  refer  to  it ; 
and  because,  occasionally,  fanatical  rulers  did  impose  some 
of  the  taxes  eo  nomine  on  the  Hindus. 

The  theory  was  that  the  inhabitants  of  a  country  might 
be  regarded  as  '  milli,'  or  peaceful ;  '  zinimi'  or  subdued 
infidels ;  and  '  harbl'  those  in  arms  against  the  Muslim  ; 
and  the  treatment  of  a  conquered  country  may  be  briefly 
described  in  the  words  of  an  author  quoted  in  Colonel 
Galloway's  Law  and  Constitution  of  India  l  : — '  When  the 
Imam  (leader  of  the  faithful)  conquers  the  country  by  force 
of  arms,  if  he  permits  the  inhabitants  to  remain,  he  imposes 
the  khirdj  on  their  lands  and  the  jaziya  (correctly  jiziyat] 
on  their  heads '  ;  and  he  adds  that  the  land  then  remains 
the  property  of  the  conquered 2. 

Some  authors  considered  khirdj  to  be  of  different  kinds 
— the  term  in  itself  meant  the  whole  of  the  surplus  pro- 
duce after  deducting  the  cost  of  production  3. 

But  there  was  also  the  more  lenient  form  of  '  khirdj 
mukdsima,'  or  division  of  produce,  by  which  the  sovereign 

1  P.  32  :  the  work  is  called  Siraj-  tribute  as  they  can  bear,  may  be 
ul-wahaj.  imposed,  instead  of  death,  on  in- 

2  With  the   poll-tax  or  '  jaziya '  fidels  ;  and  it  is  commanded  that 
we  have  no  concern  ;  but  the  reader  the  jaziya  and  khirdj  be  exacted  to 
will  find  some  curious  facts  about  it  the   uttermost   farthing,   in    order 
in  Beames'  Elliott's  Glossary,  vol.  ii.  that  the  punishment  may  approach 
sub  voc.  jaziya.     Thus  'Al£-ud-din  as  near  as  possible  to  death.'    '  You 
Khilji  is  described   as   conversing  may  perceive,'   replied    the    king, 
with  a  learned  Qazi — '  From  what  '  that     without     reading     learned 
description  of  Hindus  is  it  lawful  books,  I  am  in  the  habit  of  putting 
to   exact  obedience   and  tribute  ?  '  in  practice  that  which  has  been  en- 
The   Qazi   replies  :    '  Imam    Hanif  joined  by  the  Prophet.' 

says  that  the  jaziya,  or  as  heavy  a  3  Quoted  in  Briggs,  p.  115. 


268  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

took  one-fifth  or  so.  This  was,  of  course,  the  exact  counter- 
part of  the  old  Hindu  grain-share. 

The  tax  converted  into  money  was  called  '  khirdj-mu'wa- 
zifa'  or  simply  '  wazifa,'  and  this  was  (originally)  'regulated 
by  the  ability  of  the  cultivator  to  pay.' 

On  such  general  principles,  it  is  not  surprising  that  the 
Muhamniadan  rulers  exercised  considerable  latitude  in 
assessing  their  revenue  ;  and  that  no  particle  of  evidence  can 
be  adduced  for  the  proposition  that  by  '  law  and  constitu- 
tion '  of  India,  Akbar's  Settlement,  or  any  other,  constituted 
a  standard  to  which  every  one  could  appeal,  and  beyond 
which  he  could  not  lawfully  be  enhanced.  As  a  matter  of 
fact,  in  the  best  days  of  Mughal  rule,  moderation  and  con- 
trol over  collecting  officers  were  duly  observed ;  but  no 
ruler  ever  dreamt  that  he  might  not  from  time  to  time  (as 
he  chose — there  was  no  other  principle)  revise  the  assess- 
ment. Good  rulers  did  so  by  a  formal  measurement  and 
moderate  additions.  Indifferent  rulers  did  so  by  the  easier 
expedient  of  merely  adding  on  '  cesses '  (known  in  revenue 
language  as  '  hubub'  and  'abwdb').  Bad  rulers  simply 
bargained  with  farmers  for  fixed  sums,  thus  both  compelling 
and  encouraging  the  farmer  to  raise  the  assessment  on  the 
cultivators,  or,  in  other  words,  delegating  to  the  farmer  the 
proper  functions  of  the  State  officer  in  revising  assess- 
ments. 

How  the  revenue-farmer  exercised  this  power  we  shall 
see  in  the  history  of  Bengal ;  it  was  the  origin,  of  course,  of 
his  right  of  enhancing  (what  became)  the  rent.  When  the 
raiyats  ceased  to  be  dealt  with  direct  by  the  State  officers, 
they  were,  in  effect,  handed  over  to  the  Zamindar,  who  in 
time  became  '  the  landlord/  and  they  his  '  tenants.' 

Before  the  Mughal  times,  we  find  'Ala-ud-din  (A.D.  1294- 
1315)  imposing  a  half  produce  tax,  or  khirdj  1.  But  the 

1  See  Briggs*  FerisMa,  vol.  i.  347.  grant  of  Government,  pays  no  land- 
The  reader  will  notice  that  this  revenue,  or  of  which  the  revenues 
term,  though  not  now  used  for  are  assigned  to  a  grantee.  The 
the  land-revenue,  has  entered  into  '  land-revenue '  as  an  amount  as- 
common  use  in  the  official  term  sessed  is  jama'  =  total ;  as  a  pay- 
'  lakhiraj,'  i.  e.  land  which,  by  the  ment  it  is  spoken  of  as  '  mdl,'  or  in 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  269 

practically  useful  history  of  land-revenue  begins  with  the 
reign  of  Akbar. 

Before,  however,  I  speak  of  the  Akbarian  Settlement,  of 
which  the  central  feature  was  the  commutation  of  the  grain- 
share  into  a  money  payment,  let  me  introduce  to  the  reader 
the  method  of  grain-division  as  it  used  to  be  employed,  and 
as  it  is  still  locally  employed,  either  between  the  native 
Baja  and  his  subjects,  or  between  landlord  and  tenant,  as 
in  Bihar,  the  Panjab,  and  other  localities. 


§  3.    Practice  of  Grain-division. 

The  earliest  form  of  grain-division  is  the  deposit  of  the 
grain  in  heaps  on  the  threshing-floors  and  measuring  it 
out  with  certain  measures,  which  varied  with  the  custom 
of  the  place.  How  complicated  such  a  measurement  can 
be  made,  and  what  varied  forms  of  fraud  can  be  practised 
on  either  side,  it  is  not  easy  to  realize.  In  the  chapter  on 
SINDH,  I  have  made  allusion  to  the  elaborate  practice 
followed  in  former  days  in  some  of  the  districts  there  ;  and 
in  various  other  provincial  sections  I  have  given  accounts 
of  the  curious  local  practices  of  division.  Here  I  only  give 
a  general  idea  of  the  commonest  forms,  which  were — (i) 
actual  division ;  (2)  estimating  the  standing  crop  and  de- 
claring a  certain  number  of  '  maunds '  to  be  the  king's 
share. 

In  order  to  save  the  trouble  of  dividing,  sometimes — and 
this  was  perhaps  a  step  towards  dissolution  of  the  system — 
a  method  of  estimation  would  be  allowed  ;  a  practised  eye 
looked  at  a  field,  and  judged,  '  The  reaping  of  such  a  field 
will  give  so  many  maunds  of  grain,  of  which  so  many  go 
to  the  king '  ;  and  the  officers  took  that  amount  of  grain, 
whether  more  or  less  than  was  actually  harvested. 

I  will  ask  the  student  to  remember  the  vernacular  terms : 
'  bhaoli '  (or  '  batai ')  by  itself  or  in  compound,  is  applied  to 

some  provinces  'mu'amla.'     (In  the      versal    and   the    only   one    under- 
Panjab  this  use  of  the  term  is  uni-       stood.) 


270  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

actual  grain-division :  '  kankut '  (or  kan)  is  applied  to  the 
estimate. 

§  4.  In  Rdjput  States. 

Colonel  Tod  thus  speaks  of  the  grain-share  collection  in 
Rajput  States1: — 

'There  are  two  methods  of  levying  the  revenues  of  the 
Crown  on  every  description  of  corn  —  "kankut  "  and  "batai"  : 
— for,  on  sugarcane,  poppy,  hemp,  tobacco,  cotton2,  indigo,  and 
garden  produce,  a  money  payment  is  fixed,  varying  from  rupees 
two  to  six  per  bighd.  The  kankut  is  a  conjectural  estimate  of  the 
standing  crop  by  the  united  judgment  of  the  officers  of  Govern- 
ment— the  patel  (village  headman\  pattvdri — and  the  owner  of 
the  field.  The  accuracy  with  which  an  accustomed  eye  will 
determine  the  quantity  of  grain  on  a  given  surface  is  surprising, 
and  should  the  owner  deem  the  estimate  overrated,  he  can 
insist  on  batai  or  division  of  the  corn  after  it  is  threshed.  .  .  . 
In  the  batai  system  the  share  of  the  Government  is  from  one- 
third  to  two-fifths  of  the  spring  harvest3,  as  wheat  and  barley  ; 
and  sometimes  even  half,  which  is  the  invariable  proportion  of 
the  autumnal  crops.  The  "  kankiit"  is  the  most  liable  to  cor- 
ruption. The  cultivator  bribes  the  collector,  who  will  under- 
rate the  crop  ;  and  when  he  betrays  his  duty  the  "  watchman" 
(one  of  the  village  establishment)  is  not  likely  to  be  honest : 
and  as  Indian  corn,  the  grand  autumnal  crop  of  Mewar  (Udaipur 
State),  is  eaten  green,  the  Crown  may  be  defrauded  of  half  its 
dues.  .  .  .  There  was  a  "barar"  or  tax  introduced  to  make  up 
the  deficiency,  which  was  in  no  proportion  to  the  quantity 
cultivated,  and  its  amount  was  at  the  mercy  of  the  officers.' 

§  5.    A  Modern  Native  State. 

The  following  is  another  picture  of  '  batai '  from  one  of 
the  '  tappas '  or  groups  of  villages  called  Khairoda.  in  the 
Mewar  (Udaipur)  State  4  : — '  Of  the  first  crop,  consisting  of 

1  Tod,  i.  431.  3  There  are   in   most   parts  two 

2  Cotton     in     some    places    was  harvests  (see  Chap.    i.  pp.    12-13). 
shared    in    kind.     In    Chittagong  The  spring  crop  is  in  Mewar  called 
certain  of  the  remoter  hill  estates  '  unalu,'  and  the  autumn  crop  '  si- 
used  to  pay  their  revenue  in  cotton,  yalu ' ;  '  un '  =  heat,  '  si '  =  cold  ;  re- 
and  gave  rise  to  the  '  Kapas  mahal,'  ferring    to    summer    and    winter 
or  estate  in  the  accounts,  which  paid  harvest  time. 

in  cotton.  4  Tod,  vol.  ii.  547. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.   2  7  I 

wheat,  barley,  and  gram,  the  produce  is  formed  into  heaps 
of  one  hundred  maunds  each  ;  these  are  subdivided  into 
four  parts  of  twenty-five  maunds  each.  The  first  operation 
is  to  provide  from  one  of  these  the  "  sirano  "  or  seer  on  each 
maund,  to  each  individual  of  the  village  establishment,  viz. 
the  pdtel,  or  headman ;  the  pativdri,  or  accountant ;  the 
shdna,  or  watchman  (guardian  of  crops) ;  the  buldi,  or 
messenger  and  general  herdsman ;  the  hdtM  (alias  satar), 
or  carpenter ;  the  I6hdr,  or  blacksmith ;  the  kumhdr,  or 
potter ;  the  dhobi,  or  washerman ;  the  chamdr,  who  is 
shoemaker,  currier,  and  scavenger ;  and  the  ndi,  or  barber- 
surgeon.  These  ten  "siranos,"  being  one  seer  on  each  heap 
or  two  and  a-half  maunds  to  each  individual,  swallow  up 
one  of  the  subdivisions.  Of  the  three  remaining  parts,  one 
share  (twenty-five  maunds)  go  to  the  Raj  or  State,  two  to 
the  cultivator,  after  deducting  a  "sirano"  for  the  heir- 
apparent,  which  is  termed  "Kunwar-mutka"  (the  prince's 
pot).'  An  innovation  of  late  years  has  been  practised  on 
the  portion  (two  heaps)  belonging  to  the  village,  by  which 
no  less  than  three  maunds  are  deducted  nominally  for  the 
prince,  the  Raja's  chief  groom,  and  his  grain- steward ;  so 
that  the  Government  share  in  total  becomes  three-tenths 
instead  of  one-fourth.  The  autumn  crop  is  also  divided  by 
heaps :  out  of  every  one  hundred  maunds,  forty  go  to  the 
Government  and  sixty  to  the  village  1. 

1  I  cannot  forbear  making  one  skilful  makers  can  be  found,  is  the 

other  extract  describing  batdi  in  one  most  simple  and  expeditious  method, 

of  the  old  Sikh  estates.  I  found  but  requiring  great  Fidelity,  Ex- 

among  the  records  of  the  Ambala  perience,  and  Judgment  in  the 

Commissioner's  office  a  report  on  a  "kunneea"  or  appraiser,  who  should 

lapsed  estate  of  Sirdarni  Daya  Kuii-  be  chosen  from  among  the  oldest 

war,  dated  23rd  May,  1824.  It  con-  Zumeendars,  and  over  whom  the 

tains  the  following  curious  passage  Tuhseeldar  should  keep  a  vigilant 

(which  I  transcribe  exactly — capi-  and  circumspect  Eye.  In  the  case 

tals  and  all)  : —  of  a  cultivator  being  dissatisfied 

'  The  Native  system  of  making  with  the  appraisement  of  his  field 

the  collections  may  be  termed  three-  by  the  kunneea,  an  instant  recourse 

fold  ; — the  kun  (kan)  [also  called  should  be  had  to  the  Practice  of 

"kankut"  and  "tip"],  bataee  ^atail  beating  out  a  Beega  or  a  Biswa  of 

and  tushkhees  (tashkhis),  all  of  the  grain  on  the  disputed  Field, 

which  had  at  different  periods  been  and  thereby  ascertain  the  exact 

adopted  by  the  officers  of  the  late  quantity  to  the  satisfaction  of  both 

Sirdarnee.  The  kun  or  appraise-  parties.  It  is  obvious  that  a  con- 

ment  [of  crop  before  cutting],  if  stant  appeal  to  this  principle  ought 


272  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 


§  6.    Mardthd  System. 

In  the  Mar&tha  States  the  financiers  had  already  replaced 
batdi  by  money-rates.  Sir  J.  Malcolm  l  writes  : — '  The 
mode  of  realizing  the  revenue  varied  little  as  far  as  it 
related  to  the  collections  of  the  cultivators.  Batdi  or  pay- 
ment in  kind  is  very  unusual ;  except  with  the  Rajput 
principalities,  almost  all  the  subjects  in  the  Maratha  States 
pay  in  money.  The  basis  on  which  Settlements  were  gene- 
rally founded  was  a  measurement  of  the  kharif  or  first 
crop 2  when  it  is  cut  down,  and  the  rabi  or  second  crop, 
when  it  is  about  half  a  foot  high,  and  is  renewed  every 
third  year.  This  measurement3  is  made  with  a  coarse 
rope  divided  into  yards.'  In  a  note  the  author  mentions 
that  in  Nimar  no  measurement  had  taken  place  since  the 
Muhammadan  rule,  and  that  the  people  regarded  re-mea- 
surement as  an  innovation,  desiring  to  be  held  to  what  was 
in  the  kanungo's  books. 

A  village  Settlement  had  to  be  made  for  each  harvest 
with  the  headman,  unless  the  village  was  farmed  or  rented. 
The  regular  assessment  was  said  to  be  moderate,  and  was 
intended  to  amount  to  the  money  equivalent  of  twenty-five 
to  forty  per  cent,  of  the  produce  after  deduction  of  seed 

to  be  avoided  as  tedious  and  vex-  Zumeendars,  who  are  tempted  to 
atious,  and  it  is  seldom  that  the  remove  portions  of  grain  during  the 
cultivator  calls  for  its  application,  night  season.  Could  these  and 
still  less  does  the  kunneea  like  to  similar  Difficulties  be  surmounted, 
put  his  judgment  to  the  Test.  no  mode  offers  such  a  show  of  jus- 
'  The  butaee  or  division  of  grain  tice  to  the  Government  and  its  sub- 
on  the  spot  seemed  to  present  many  jects  as  dividing  the  Gifts  of  nature 
objections.  Three  Heaps  are  made  :  on  the  spot. 

one   for   the   Sarkar  (the   Govern-  '  The  tushkees,  or  farm  of  an  es- 

ment),  one  for  the  Ryot,  and  the  tate  to  the  highest  bidder,  distresses 

third  for  the  Khurch,  or  village  ex-  the    cultivator,    however    pleasing 

penses  ;    so  that   the   Government  the  lucrative  receipts  may  appear 

receives  only  about  one-third  of  the  for    the     first    few    years    of    the 

produce,    which    has    led    to    the  lease ' 

phrase  "  bataee  lootaee  "  or  Division  1  Vol.  ii.  p.  24. 

is  plunder.     The  grain  has  to  re-  a  I.  e.  counting  the  year  as  begin- 

main  in  the  field  for  a  length  of  ning  before  the  rains,  which  is  the 

time,  exposed  to  the  Elements,  ere  plan  of  the  fasli  or  agricultural  year, 
it  can  be  trodden  out  and  winnowed,  3  In  Central  India  they  used  the 

added  to  the  expense  of  persons  to  Akbari  measure   of   one   bigha  =  a 

watch  the  khulwara  (khalwara)  or  square  of  60  gaz  or  yards,  which 

stacks  from  the  spoliation  of  the  will  be  explained  further  on. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  273 

and  costs 1.  The  moderation,  however,  was  deprived  of  its 
advantage  by  the  additional  charge  of  '  tafrik '  or  contin- 
gencies. 

The  system  of  management  adopted  by  the  Marathas  was 
not,  however,  uniform  ;  in  outlying  tracts  they  farmed 
their  revenues  and  did  it  cruelly ;  in  other  places  they 
made  no  arrangement  at  all,  but  levied  a  'chauth,'  or 
fourth,  as  tribute.  The  Maratha  'chauth'  in  Bengal  be- 
came historic. 

In  the  Settlement  report  of  the  large  Dholka  taluka,  or 
local  division  of  the  Ahmadabad  Collectorate  of  Bombay, 
I  find  the  most  curious  account  of  the  old  assessments. 
Whether  this  was  altogether  due  to  the  Marathas  or  to  the 
chiefs  (called  taluqdars),  remains  of  the  Muhammadan 
kingdoms  in  the  Guzarat  province,  I  do  not  know ;  but  the 
assessment  consisted  sometimes  of  a  grain-division  (bhag- 
watai),  and  sometimes  of  a  cash  assessment  by  area  (always 
called  bighoti — rate  on  the  bigha).  This  varied  with  each 
crop,  and  was  levied  on  all  sugar-cane,  garden  produce, 
and  vegetables.  Then,  besides  that,  there  was  a  whole 
series  of  '  babti,'  which  is  merely  an  old  friend, — the  Bengal 
'  cess  '  (abwab)  under  a  new  name.  Yet  most  of  the  assess- 
ment was  levied  on  the  basis  or  foundation  of  the  moderate 
and  recorded  rates  of  the  Settlement  effected  by  the  Mu- 
hammadan kings.  The  latter  was  called  the  'ain  (the 
'thing  itself) ;  and  when  the  Marathas  had  levelled  up  the 
village  'ain  to  what  they  considered  as  much  as  could  be 
got,  they  called  it  the  '  kamal '  or  '  perfect '  assessment. 

§  7.    Certain  Crops  always  paid  in  Cash. — Zabti. 

In  concluding  this  notice,  I  ought  to  allude  to  a  fact 
which  perhaps  suggested,  certainly  facilitated,  the  change 
from  a  grain  to  a  money -p&ymeni.  When  vegetables, 
sugar-cane,  spices,  and  similar  crops,  not  forgetting  cotton, 
are  largely  cultivated,  it  is  very  difficult  to  divide  them  in 

1  Irrigated  land  for  opium   and       high  ;  the  black  soil  was  assessed 
sugar-cane  was  rented  at  R.  5  to  zoa       at  R.  i  to  1-8. 
bigha,  and  garden  land  nearly  as 

VOL.  I.  T 


274  LANI)    SYSTEMS   OE   BEITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

kind  ;  the  process  takes  too  long  and  the  produce  is  spoiled, 
or  the  determination  of  a  yield,  when  the  whole  crop  is  not 
taken  off  the  soil  at  once,  becomes  impossible.  At  a  very 
early  date  such  crops  paid  at  customary  rates  in  cash ;  and 
when  in  later  times  all  crops  paid  in  cash,  these — more 
valuable — kinds  of  produce  were  charged  at  a  higher  rate. 
In  revenue  language  they  were  called  '  zabti '  crops,  and 
paid  at  '  zabti '  rates l. 


SECTION  IV. — THE  BEGINNING  OF  REGULAR  ASSESSMENT 
UNDER  NATIVE  RULE. 

The  first  beginning  of  the  change  from  a  mere  levy  of 
a  share  of  the  grain  to  a  regularly-assessed  land-revenue, 
may  fairly  be  traced  to  the  Emperor  Akbar's  Settlement, 
begun  in  1571  A.D.  There  had  been  some  earlier  attempts, 
but  they  were  not  systematic,  nor  have  the  details  come 
down  to  us.  There  was  another  great  Settlement  at  a  later 
date  carried  out  by  the  Muhammadan  kings  of  the  Dakhan, 
but  that  was  almost  wholly  a  copy  of  Akbar's  Settlement. 
The  astute  emperor  employed  a  distinguished  Hindu  Raja, 
Todar  Mai2,  to  do  the  work  conjointly  with  a  Muham- 
madan official.  It  should  be  remarked  that  this  Settlement 
did  not  at  once  enforce  the  method  of  cash  payment ;  it  left 
it  optional  with  the  raiyat  to  pay  the  old  grain-share  if  he 
objected  to  the  commutation  price.  Abul  Fazl,  in  the 
Ayin-i-Akbari,  describes  the  methods  of  grain-division  as 
above  detailed,  showing  that  the  methods  have  never  varied 
in  principle.  He  mentions  the  '  kankut/  or  estimate  of 
crops  while  standing ;  the  '  bhaoli '  or  '  batai '  being  the 
actual  division  of  the  grain  on  the  threshing-floors.  And 
he  adds  another  method  called  'khetbatai/  or  taking  a 
certain  measured  area  of  the  standing  crop  of  each  field,  the 

1  Zabt  (A.)  means  '  sequestered,'  in   Todar  being  the  palatal,   it    is 
set  aside  ;  hence  special  or  excep-  sounded   something  like  r ;   hence 
tional.  the  name  appears  as  Torun  Mall, 

2  This  name  is   found  variously  Toren  Mull,  Tooral  Mai,  and  Tury- 
tortured  in  the  older  books  :   the  d  mal  (in  the  Fifth  Report). 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE  VENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  275 

yield  of  which  is  assumed  to  represent  the  share  of  the 
whole  holding ;  and  one  called  '  lang-batai,'  whereby  the 
cultivator  piles  the  grain  into  as  many  heaps  as  there  are 
shares,  and  the  Government  officer  takes  the  heap  that 
pleases  him. 

§  i.    Akbar's  Settlement  under  Rdjd  Todar  Mai. 

In  1571  A.D.  the  survey  was  commenced  ;  a  standard,  the 
'  ilahi '  gaz,  or  yard-rod,  was  fixed,  and  a  '  tanab '  or  chain  1. 
The  Settlement  extended  to  Bengal  in  1582.  The  classi- 
fication of  land  adopted  was  into  ( i )  '  pulaj  '  2  (or  '  pulej  '), 
which  was  land  that  was  continually  cultivated  and  did  not 
require  fallow;  (2)  'phirawati,'  or  rotation  land  that  re- 
quired a  periodical  fallow  ;  (3)  '  chichar,'  that  lay  fallow  for 
three  or  four  years,  or  rather  that,  being  inundated  or 
otherwise  bad,  could  only  be  occasionally  depended  on  for 
a  crop  ;  and  (4) '  banjar,'  waste  that  had  not  been  cultivated 
for  five  or  more  years.  The  first  three  kinds  were  again 
classed  into  '  best,'  '  middling,'  and  '  worst.' 

The  share  of  Government  was  one-third  of  the  produce  ; 
and  to  ascertain  an  average,  a  bigha  of  each  kind  was  taken 
as  a  sample,  and  one-third  of  the  aggregate  produce  was  con- 
sidered to  be  the  average  bigha  produce.  One-third  of  this 
gave  the  Government  share.  Tables  are  to  be  found  in  the 
Ayin-i-Akbari  showing  the  averge  yield  for  various  crops 
grown  at  each  harvest3.  Garden  crops  and  pan  (the  aromatic 
betel-leaf  used  for  chewing)  were  charged  at  certain  money  - 

1  The  gaz  was  41   fingers  or  33  saries.     I  suspect  it  is  a  corruption 
inches  long;  a  square  of  60  such  of  the  Persian 'palez' — garden-land, 
yards  (a '  jarib '  each  way)  gives  one  land  that  grows  melons,  &c. 
bigha.    The  standard  bigha  of  the  3  See  Briggs,  p.  126  ;  and  Field, 
Upper  Provinces  is  then  3,025  Eiig-  p.  433.     The  names  of  the  crops  in 
lish  square  yards  (five-eighths  of  an  both  are  so  misspelt  as  to  be  un- 
acre).     In  Bengal  it  is  i, 600  square  recognizable;   e.g.  adess  =  'adas,  the 
yards,   or    about    one-third  of    an  Arabic  for  masur  or  lentils  ;    shaly 
acre.     In  other  places  it  is  various.  mushkeen  is  the  Persian  Sltdl-i-mush- 
We  have  still  some  means  of  testing  kin,  or  scented  rice,  one  of  the  best 
the  figures  by  the  mindr  or  'mile  kinds  (bansmatti)  ;  motmg  =  mung  is 
posts,'  which  are  still  standing — a  pulse    (Phaseolus  mungo)  ;   lubyeh  is, 
few  of  them  —  a  long  the  old  imperial  perhaps    '  lobiya  '    (beans).      What 
road  from  Delhi.  '  tyndus'  '  kelet,'  '  berty,'  and  'kawdcy' 

2  This  word  is  not  in  the  glos-  are,  I  cannot  even  guess. 

T    2 


276  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

rates.  For  grain  crops,  the  prices  of  nineteen  years  (from  the 
sixth  to  the  twenty -fourth  of  Akbar's  reign),  were  collected 
by  inquiry.  This  period  was  selected  because  nineteen 
years  being  a  cycle  of  the  moon,  the  seasons  were  supposed 
in  this  time  to  undergo  a  complete  revolution,  and  so  to 
exhibit  all  varieties  of  quantity.  Mr.  Elphinstone  observes 
that  the  Ayin-i-Akbari  gives  no  information  as  to  how  the 
comparative  fertility  of  fields  was  ascertained,  though  it  is 
probable  that  the  three  classes  formed  for  each  of  the  better 
soils  were  applied  in  consultation  with  the  cultivators. 
There  must,  however,  have  been  great  inequality :  for  in- 
stance, if  a  man's  holding  were  all  of  the  '  worst '  kind  of 
pulaj,  in  that  case  the  average  rate  ascertained  as  above 
described,  would  be  too  high. 

The  revenue  on  phirdwati  land  was  calculated  in  the 
same  way,  but  it  was  not  charged  in  fallow  years.  Chichar 
was  allowed  to  be  paid  for  in  grain  or  kind  according  to  its 
yield;  probably  the  actual  crop  was  looked  to.  Banjar 
was  distinguished  by  progressive  rates.  In  itself,  waste  or 
long-fallowed  land  might  be  of  any  class,  and  when  brought 
under  cultivation,  it  was  allowed  to  pay  only  a  sir  or  two 1 
in  kind  for  the  first  year,  four  sirs  for  the  second,  and  so  on 
till  the  full  rate  of  the  land,  according  to  quality,  was  attained. 

It  was  Mr.  Elphinstone's  opinion  that  the  commutation 
rates  above  spoken  of  were  maximum  rates ;  and  indeed 
this  is  probable,  for  they  would  have  been  both  high  and 
unequal ;  and  there  are  other  indications  that  besides  the 
option  the  cultivator  had  of  tendering  grain,  there  was  also 
the  practice  of  allowing  him  to  offer  the  money  value  of  the 
grain  at  the  time. 

§  2.    Akbars  Revised  Settlement. 

But  however  this  may  be,  some  practical  difficulty  cer- 
tainly arose,  for  after  this,  a  new  ten  years'  money  Settle- 
ment was  made  2. 

1  See  note  at  p.  242,  explaining  *  See  the  passage  from  the  Ayin-i- 

the  man,  or  '  maund  '  and  its  sub-       Aklari  quoted  in  Field,  p.  437. 
divisions. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  277 

The  rates  of  actual  collection  from  the  fifteenth  year  of 
the  reign  to  the  twenty-fourth  (inclusive)  were  written 
down,  and  a  tenth  part  of  the  total  was  accepted  as  the 
revenue  for  the  next  ten  years. 


§  3.    Akbar's  Settlement  not  permanent. — The  Native 
Custom  always  contemplated  variation. 

It  is  true  that  such  was  the  fame  of  this  last  assessment, 
that  the  rates  of  it  were  often  appealed  to  as  a  sort  of 
standard ;  but  in  view  of  the  frequent  references  in  Au- 
rangzeb's  and  other  reigns,  to  other  rates  of  collection,  and 
to  orders  restraining  the  collectors  from  taking  more  than 
one-half  the  produce,  it  is  clear  that  it  can  never  have  been 
regarded  by  the  authorities  as  unalterable. 

Besides  this,  it  is  a  matter  of  fact  that  reassessments 
were  made  from  time  to  time.  Mr.  James  Grant  expressly 
insists  that  when  the  '  standard '  assessment  was  referred 
to  (called  'Asl  tumar  jama' — i.  e.  the  land-revenue  proper, 
without  cesses  or  imposts)  it  was  not  Akbar's  that  was 
meant,  but  the  last  authoritative  recorded  assessment 1.  As 
I  have  already  remarked,  it  is  impossible  to  assert  that, 
either  by  law  or  custom,  the  king  or  emperor  was  prohibited 
from  reassessing  or  raising  his  revenue  periodically2.  The 
old  law-books  do  not  deal  with  the  subject,  because  they 
belong  to  a  stage  when  a  share  in  the  produce  was  taken. 

1  In  his 'Analysis  of  the  Finances  or     as     circumstances     suggested, 
of  Bengal,' one  of  the  appendices  to  When,       therefore,       Government 
the  Fifth  Report.     See  (for  instance)  ceased  to  deal  with  the  cultivators 
p.  236,  vol.  i.  of  the  Madras  Reprint.  and  made    a    fixed   contract  with 

2  I   repeat   this,  because  on   the  'Zamindars'  over  them,  it  did  not 
fact  depends  a  great   deal   of  the  follow  that  the  people  had  any  claim 
controversy      about      rent      under  that  their  payments  should  never  be 
the    permanent    Settlement.      The  reassessed  :  Government  might  have 
'tenants'  of  the  'landlords'  were  made   such    a   declaration,    but    it 
the  people  who  had  been  the  cul-  never  did.    The  grievous  defect  was 
tivators  or  de  facto  proprietors  of  the  this,   that  the   Government   never 
holdings  on  which  Akbar's  assess-  devised  any  rule  by  which  the  re- 
ment  was  fixed.    Had  no  proprietors  vision  and   enhancement  of  what 
been  created  by  law  over  them,  they  had  now  become  rent,  could  be  regu- 
would  have  submitted  to  reassess-  lated,  as  it  would  have  been,  sup- 
ment,  say  after  ten   or  fifteen    or  posing  it  had  remained  as  revenue 
thirty  years,  according  to  the  will  under  the   direct  orders  of  a  good 
of  the  governor,  as  prices  altered.  and  considerate  ruler. 

f   VOL.    I. 


278  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  v. 

Even  the  share  varied  according  to  State  necessities ;  but 
putting  that  aside,  it  is  in  itself  an  increasing  quantity, 
(i)  because  values  rise;  and  (2)  as  more  and  more  land  is 
under  the  plough,  the  total  of  the  king's  share  becomes 
larger. 

§  4.    Disadvantages  of  the  Grain-division. 

The  disadvantages  of  a  grain-assessment  are  manifold. 
In  the  long  run  they  outweigh  the  convenience  which  causes 
such  methods  to  be  still  adopted  in  some  places.  They  may 
be  admitted  to  have  some  virtue  in  their  application  to 
precarious  soils  and  climates,  where  it  is  impossible  to  cal- 
culate what  the  produce  or  its  equivalent  will  be  for  even 
a  short  term  of  years.  A  payment  in  kind  may  here  avoid 
the  technical  difficulties  of  a  fluctuating  cash-assessment. 

But  in  fairly  well  developed  districts,  where  irrigation 
secures  the  crops  to  a  considerable  extent,  a  grain  collection 
becomes  intolerable,  and  there  is  nothing  to  recommend 
it.  It  is  a  source  of  never-ending  dispute :  it  is  extremely 
troublesome  for  the  State  officer  to  manage.  It  affords 
the  maximum  of  opportunity  to  the  cultivator  to  pilfer  and 
conceal  on  the  one  side,  and  to  the  officials  and  their  satel- 
lites to  peculate  and  extort,  on  the  other.  Moreover,  when 
grain  markets  are  well  established,  and  values  rise,  the  one 
party  or  the  other  suffers ;  a  very  slight  accident  may, 
in  reality,  double  the  assessment.  The  actual  history  of 
districts  has  shown  that  gradually,  by  the  action  of  the 
people  themselves,  grain  rates  invariably,  if  slowly,  give 
way  to  cash  rates. 

§  5.    Causes  of  a  change  to  Cash-payments. 

The  change  took  place  gradually,  and  was  some- 
times concealed  by  a  fiction ;  as  e.  g.  in  the  case  of 
the  'Khot'  villages  on  the  West  Coast,  where  the 
assessment  was  nominally  in  grain  but  was  levied  in 
cash  by  means  of  an  artificial  valuation.  But  in  general 
the  change  forced  itself  on  the  notice  of  atlministra- 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  279 

tors  directly  the  increase  of  population  and  the  subdivision 
of  farms  made  it  impossible  for  the  full  grain-share  of  the 
State  to  be  collected.  Supposing  that  a  farm  of  eighteen 
acres  yields  ten  maunds  of  grain  per  acre.  Let  us  as- 
sume that  the  cultivator  needs  one-third  of  this  for  his 
subsistence,  that  the  king  takes  one-third,  and  that  the 
remaining  third  covers  the  costs  of  cultivation  and  profits 
of  stock.  The  king  thus  gets  sixty  maunds.  But  in  time 
the  farm  is  subdivided  among  an  increased  number  of 
heirs  of  the  original  holder.  The  individual  holding  now 
becomes  (say)  six  acres.  The  subdivision  will  doubtless 
promote  increased  care  in  tillage,  and  probably  im- 
proved irrigation.  Suppose  these  improvements  double  the 
produce.  The  total  produce  of  the  holding  is  still  only 
one  hundred  and  twenty  maunds,  and  the  king's  share  is 
forty  maunds  :  possibly  the  proportions  can  be  maintained, 
as  prices  will  have  risen,  and  the  shares,  though  diminished 
in  amount,  will  have  become  of  greater  money  value.  But 
there  is  a  limit  to  this ;  for  the  rate  of  production  will  not 
go  on  increasing  in  the  same  proportion  as  the  holdings 
diminish  by  subdivision.  As  the  share  required  for  the 
subsistence  of  the  cultivator  will  not  materially  lessen,  the 
king's  share  cannot  be  paid  at  the  same  rate.  But  the 
king  does  not  like  to  diminish  his  share  ostensibly,  and  the 
expedient  which  conceals  the  fact,  is  to  take  a  sum  of 
money  instead.  This  will  probably  be  calculated  at  some 
rate  per  plough,  or  so  much  for  each  holding  on  an  average 
of  what  has  been  paid  for  a  given  period  of  years.  The 
idea  of  acreage  valuation,  according  to  different  relative 
productiveness,  or  the  idea  of  competition  rents,  are  alike 
unfamiliar,  and  among  the  people  themselves  are  still  im- 
perfectly understood  in  many  districts. 

When  at  last  a  settled  Government,  with  ideas  of  law 
and  order,  begins,  it  becomes  necessary  to  devise  some 
means  of  passing  from  arbitrary  and  unequal  rates  to  an 
assessment  that  shall  be — on  some  definite  principle — just 
to  the  land-holder,  while  giving  a  full  revenue  to  the  State. 


280  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

§  6.    Need  of  periodical  Revision. 

But  the  moment  money  assessments  are  established,  then, 
as  soon  as  there  is  a  change  in  the  value  of  produce,  or  in 
the  value  of  money  itself,  as  coined  money  becomes  more 
plentiful,  or,  owing  to  improved  communications,  or  to  other 
causes,  the  assessments  become  locally  so  unequal  that 
revision  is  called  for  on  this  ground  alone.  Again ;  every 
government — not  excluding  the  best  Oriental  governments 
— regards  the  development  of  districts  as  one  of  its  first 
duties ;  and  the  moment  canals,  railways,  tanks,  wells, 
agricultural-loans  and  the  like,  come  under  consideration, 
it  is  obvious  that  Government  is  entitled  both  to  raise  the 
means  of  expending  capital  on  such  works,  and  to  reap  its 
share  of  the  largely  increased  amount  and  value  of  the 
produce  obtained. 

§  7.   Reflections  on  the  state   of   the  Revenue-System  to 
which  the  British  Government  succeeded. 

When,  in  1765,  British  government  began  in  Bengal,  a 
land-revenue  assessed  in  money  was,  and  long  had  been, 
the  principal  source  of  the  State's  wealth. 

It  is  quite  immaterial  to  discuss  whether  such  a  system 
is  good  or  bad  in  theory,  because  any  such  discussion  would 
be  based  on  European,  not  on  Oriental  ideas. 

In  the  same  way,  in  the  last  chapter  (see  Sec.  vi,  on  Pro- 
perty) I  deprecated  the  argument  as  to  whether  we  should 
call  our  land-revenue  a  '  land-tax '  or  not.  I  know  of  no  idler 
and  less  interesting  war  of  words  than  such  an  argument, 
at  least  under  existing  conditions,  when  rights  in  land  have 
been  well  established. 

An  Oriental  institution  is  what  it  has  grown  to  be,  by 
the  effect  of  custom  and  the  wear  and  tear  of  historical 
events.  To  take  it  up,  turn  it  round,  and  force  it  into  the 
mould  of  any  European  definition  or  theory  of  taxation,  is 
impossible1.  The  land-revenue  is  everywhere  acquiesced 

1  Kaye,  p.  141,  has  some  excellent  English  taxation  and  Indian.  In 
remarks  on  the  difference  between  England  we  are  always  being  taxed 


CHAP.v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  281 

in  by  the  people,  and  paid  without  demur;  it  has  the 
advantage  of  an  immemorial  prescription,  which  in  the  East 
is  a  matter  of  first-rate  importance  ;  and  it  is  quite  certain 
that  no  other  means  of  raising  an  equal  revenue  could  be 
devised,  which  would  work  with  equally  little  trouble  and 
interference  with  the  people.  The  whole  land-revenue  ma- 
chinery works  as  smoothly  as  possible — even  the  difficulties 
of  such  districts  as  Chittagong  or  Sylhet,  in  Eastern  Bengal 
and  Assam,  are  mere  local  problems  which  are  approaching 
solution.  Almost  the  only  grave  objection  that  could  be 
raised  to  the  system  is  the  cost  of,  as  well  as  the  harass- 
ment of  the  people  involved  in.  the  work  of  a  '  Settlement,' 
with  its  survey  and  record  of  the  rights  of  landholders 
and  tenants.  But  this  our  modern  systems  have  tended 
greatly  to  reduce ;  and  it  is  probable  that  before  another 
thirty  years  have  passed,  the  operation  of  revising  the 
revenue  will  be  a  matter  which  will  be  carried  out  with 
hardly  a  perceptible  ruffle  of  the  quiet  course  of  district 
and  agricultural  business. 


SECTION  V. — THE  BEGINNING  OF  BRITISH  LAND-REVENUE 

SYSTEMS. 

We  have  now  seen  how  a  system  of  a  land-revenue  paid 
in  money  was  ready  made  to  the  hands  of  our  first  ad- 
ministrators. Our  laws  have  always  avoided  any  theory 
on  the  subject  of  the  origin  of  the  right  of  the  State,  and 
the  earliest  Regulations  of  1793  contented  themselves  with 
asserting  just  so  much  (and  no  more)  as  would  serve  as  a 
sufficient  basis  for  the  system  when  reduced  to  shape, — 
namely,  that  '  by  ancient  law  (custom  would  have  been 

and  untaxed.  The  Minister  of  Fi-  tical  economical  theories,  but  ac- 
nance  has  his  budget  proposals,  and  cording  as  the  people  take  kindly  to 
the  reduction  of  one  tax  or  the  im-  it  and  it  can  be  realized  without 
position  of  a  new  one  is  a  perpetual  inquisition,  without  pressing  hardly 
subject  for  discussion  all  over  the  and  unequally  on  certain  classes. 
country.  As  a  result  of  it,  ministers  It  is  found  better  to  trust  to  what 
may  fall.  But  in  India  everything  people  have  long  been  accustomed 
goes  by  custom  ;  a  tax  is  good  or  to,  than  to  devise  new  plans  how- 
bad,  not  so  much  according  to  poli-  ever  theoretically  perfect. 


282  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  V. 

better)  the  Government  was  entitled  to  a  share  in  the  pro- 
duce of  every  bigha  of  land,  that  share  to  be  fixed  by 
itself1.'  As  a  necessary  corollary,  it  has  always  held 
that  the  revenue  is  a  first  charge  on  the  estate,  to  which 
all  other  charges  must  give  way ;  and  that,  in  effect,  the 
land  is  hypothecated  for  the  revenue  assessment  on  it. 

I  have  already  explained  that  Government  makes  no 
claim  to  be  the  immediate  or  exclusive  proprietor2  of  all 
lands ;  but  it  reserves  to  itself  the  ultimate  ownership  in 
default  of  any  other  owner, — as,  for  instance,  in  unoccupied 
waste  lands,  as  in  the  case  of  escheat  or  forfeiture  for 
crime.  To  secure  its  own  revenue,  which  (as  just  stated) 
is  a  first  charge  on  all  land,  it  holds  all  land  as  hypothe- 
cated to  itself  for  the  amount  of  the  revenue,  and  conse- 
quently it  reserves  the  right  to  sell  the  land  (under 
whatever  conditions  it  may  enact  by  law)  if  the  revenue 
falls  into  arrear. 

In  order  to  protect  its  subjects,  it  also  reserves  the  power 
to  declare  and  to  adjust  the  rights  of  all  classes  of  rights 
and  interests  in  the  soil,  and  in  some  cases  to  divide 
the  benefits  of  landed  right,  equitably  between  different 
classes. 

It  was  the  misfortune  of  our  early  administrators  that 
they  succeeded  to  Akbar's  revenue  system,  not  developed 
as  it  might  have  been  by  the  practical  wisdom  of  Oriental 
financiers,  but  as  one  which  represented  only  a  state  of 
misrule  and  corruption.  A  thoroughly-developed  native 
system  might  have  been  difficult  to  define  or  explain  in 
a  statute,  but  it  would  have  been  easily  workable. 

As  it  was,  the  administration  had  fallen  into  confusion 
beyond  hope  of  remedy.  Some  theory  or  practice  of 
revising  the  assessments,  some  customary  period  for  such 
revisions,  might  have  been  expected,  but  none  such  was 
left  us.  We  know  that  in  Bengal  reassessment  had  taken 


1  See  preamble  to  Bengal  Eegula-  see  the  Bombay  Revenue  Code,  (B.) 

tions  XIX  and   XXXVII  of  1793.  Act  V  of  1879,  Section  45. 

The  same  phrase  has  been  adopted  2  Chap.  IV.  Sec.  vi.  p.  239. 
in  the  modern  Acts  ;  for  instance, 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.   283 

place  from  time  to  time T.  But  the  only  principle  that 
had  settled  down  into  continuance,  was  the  hateful  expe- 
dient of  adding  cesses  or  'abwab'  to  what  was  called 
the  '  'asl  tumar '  or  standard  sum  still  borne  on  the  books 
as  representing  the  last  measurement  and  assessment. 
And  the  practice  fell  to  a  lower  depth  still ;  the  State 
gave  up  all  control,  and  merely  bargained  with  local  and 
influential  men  in  certain  tracts  of  country,  for  the  largest 
sum  they  could  reasonably  expect  to  realize,  and  left  them 
to  get  out  of  the  people  what  they  could.  In  such  a  state 
of  things,  our  first  officers  did  not  well  know  what  to 
do.  They  were  not  able  to  make  a  survey  before  Settle- 
ment :  general  inquiries  had  been  carried  out,  but  the 
machinery  was  too  sparse  and  imperfect  to  enable  the 
right  sort  of  information  to  be  gained.  The  reason  of  this 
remains  to  be  stated. 

The  Zamindars,  who  had  gradually,  since  the  beginning 
of  the  eighteenth  century,  been  allowed  to  contract  for  the 
revenue  of  large  areas  of  country,  were  the  only  really  well 
established  revenue  machinery  which  remained  in  exist- 
ence. A  century's  growth  had  given  them  such  a  hold, 
that  they  had  not  only  become  virtually  landlords,  so 
that  to  ignore  them  would  have  been  unjust  from  the 
point  of  view  of  private  interest  in  the  estate,  but  from  the 
revenue  point  of  view,  their  aid  was  indispensable.  For,  if 
they  were  not  to  be  trusted  to  for  the  revenue,  who  was  ? 
The  reader  will  be  inclined  to  answer — '  Why,  the  village 
cultivators,  through  their  own  headmen — people  who  were 
the  real  bread-winners  and  proprietors  of  the  soil  on  which 
they  had  resided  for  generations,  and  which  their  fore- 
fathers had  either  conquered  or  colonized  out  of  the  track- 
less jungle.'  This  is  very  easy,  and  even  obvious,  to  say 
now,  with  reference  to  modern  conditions  ;  it  was  not  so  in 
1789.  There  was  no  local  machinery  to  do  such  a  work. 
Even  if  a  complete  district  staff,  with  well-trained  native 
subordinates,  in  subdivisions  and  parganas,  had  existed, 
even  they  could  have  only  succeeded  by  making  out 

1  For  some  details,  soo  Fii-M,  p.  441. 


284  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

village  records  afresh.  For  it  must  never  be  forgotten 
that  the  direct  consequence  of  the  growth  of  the  Zaminddr 
was  twofold.  One  consequence  was  the  existence  of  a 
certain  interest  in  the  estates  which  demanded  a  special 
treatment  at  the  hands  of  our  administrators ;  but  a  still 
more  important  consequence  was  the  gradual  annihilation 
of  the  district  control,  and  the  atrophy  of  the  official 
charges,  which  has  above  been  described.  The  Zamindar 
not  only  relieved  the  kamingos  and  patwaris  of  all  re- 
sponsibility to  the  State,  making  them  therefore  careless 
about  keeping  up  their  records  and  accounts ;  but,  more 
than  that,  when  the  Zamindar  was  only  liable,  as  in  later 
times,  to  answer  for  his  contract  sum,  and  not  for  the 
details  of  his  village  and  pargana  collections,  it  became 
positively  distasteful  to  him  to  have  details  of  authorized 
rents  and  rights  of  raiyats  entered  in  village  records :  the 
kanungo,  then,  got  no  information ;  and  the  village  pat- 
waris were  made  merely  to  keep  just  such  accounts  as  the 
Zamindar  wanted  for  his  own  purposes.  In  a  word,  the 
kanungo  became  an  official  shadow,  and  the  patwaris  the 
bond-slaves  of  the  Zamindars. 

The  few  '  Collectors'  0^1789,  and  their  supervising 
Committees  of  Revenue,  therefore,  could  not  have  thought 
of  going  to  the  villages  as  we  now  should. 


§  i.    Attempt  at  farming  the  Revenues. 

They  did  indeed  try  for  several  years  an  experiment  which 
proved  a  failure.  They  had  heard  of  the  oppression  of  the 
'  Zamindars,'  and  they  thought  that,  if  they  made  indepen- 
dent contracts  with  special  farmers,  these  would  be  more 
amenable  to  restraint.  The  process  was  tried  with  ever- 
increasing  trouble  and  disappointment  from  1770  up  till 
the  date  when  Lord  Cornwallis  came  out  in  1786.  And 
then  a  system  was  adopted  which  restored  the  Zaminda'rs, 
but  gave  them  a  new  position,  which  it  was  expected 
would  remedy  all  defects. 

In  the  chapter  on  Bengal  I  shall  fully  explain  that  the 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  285 

system  which  Lord  Cornwallis  introduced  as  the  celebrated 
'  Permanent  Settlement,'  was  emphatically  not  any  new 
idea  of  his  own.  It  was  elaborated  by  Mr.  Shore1  and  the 
ablest  Civil  servants,  in  communication  with  the  Court  of 
Directors  at  home,  as  the  documents  in  the  celebrated 
Fifth  Report  on  the  Affairs  of  the  East  India  Company  to 
the  House  of  Commons  will  abundantly  testify. 

§  2.    Outline  of  Lord  Cornwallis  s  System. 

In  effect  that  system  recognized  that  the  revenues  must 
be  collected  by  means  of  local  men  of  influence  and 
wealth,  who  took  charge  of  considerable  estates,  larger 
or  smaller,  according  to  circumstances  ;  and  that,  in  order 
to  give  these  persons  confidence,  they  must  be  endowed 
formally  with  such  an  interest  as  made  them  legally  and 
in  name,  what  most  of  them  were  de  facto, — '  proprietors  ' 
or  '  landlords.'  The  king's  subjects,  or  '  raiyats,'  then  be- 
came the  tenants  of  the  new  landlords.  It  was  well 
understood  that  they  were  not  ordinary  tenants,  in  the 
sense  that  they  were  persons  located  by  the  Zamindar  on 
contract  or  lease.  Some  of  them,  of  course,  would  be  so — 
as,  for  example,  when  the  landlord  began  to  break  up  the 
waste  and  to  form  new  colonies  of  cultivators  ;  but  others 
— the  majority — would  be  the  original  and  hereditary 
possessors  of  the  village  soil.  It  was  intended  to  protect 
their  rights,  as  we  shall  see  ;  but  unfortunately  the  inten- 
tion was  not  practically  carried  out.  The  benefit  to  the 
landlord  was  secured ;  that  intended  for  the  tenant  was 
not.  As  far  as  the  revenue  is  concerned,  the  main  feature 
of  the  system  was  the  plan  of  fixing  in  perpetuity  the  sum 
to  be  paid  annually  for  each  estate.  The  details  of  that 
proposal  I  shall  describe  in  the  chapter  devoted  to  Bengal; 
here  it  is  enough  to  say  that  our  first  revenue  system 
in  Bengal  involved  (i)  the  acknowledgment,  as  landlords, 

1  Mr.  Shore  did  not  advocate,  but  he  agreed  with   the   others  in  se- 

strongly    opposed,    the    particular  curing  the  position  of  the  Zamin- 

feature   of    the    Settlement  which  dars. 
caused  it  to  be  '  permanent.'     But 


286  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

of  persons  found  in  actual  charge  of  large  areas  of  land, 
and  (2)  an  assessment  of  such  reasonable  sum  as  could  be 
discovered  by  comparing  the  accounts  of  actual  payments 
in  previous  years;  the  sum  so  fixed  being  declared  un- 
alterable for  ever. 


SECTION  VI. — THE  MAIN  PEINCIPLES  OF  THE  BENGAL 
SETTLEMENT  AND  WHAT  HAS  RESULTED  FROM  THEM. 

§  i.  Special  features  of  the  Settlement. 

About  this  PERMANENT  (Zamindari)  Settlement,  there  are 
three  things  to  be  observed. 

I.  The  system  involved  the  presumption  that  for  every 
local  estate  or  group  of  lands  there  must  be  some  person 
with  whom  Government  should  settle,  or  (in  official  phrase) 
who  should  '  hold  the  Settlement ' ;  and  further,  that  this 
person,  or  middleman  between  the  raiyat  and  the  State, 
should  be  vested  with  a  proprietary  interest  in  the  land. 
The  benefits  and  obligations  in  such  an  arrangement  or 
contract  were  to  be  reciprocal.  The  Government  was  to 
have  some  one  who  was  to  be  looked  to  as  responsible,  in 
person  and  estate,  for  punctual  payment ;  the  person  was 
to  be  given  the  means  of  discharging  his  responsibility  by 
having  a  secure  title  to  the  land  for  which  he  engaged.  He 
was  to  be  irremoveable  (otherwise  than  temporarily,  in 
the  event  of  his  not  agreeing  to  the  terms  offered).  He 
was  to  be  at  liberty  to  raise  money  on  the  credit  of  the 
land,  to  sell  or  gift  it,  or  pass  it  on  to  his  children  by 
inheritance  or  bequest,  as  the  case  might  be.  In  other 
words,  he  was  to  be  declared  and  legally  installed  as  pro- 
prietor or  landlord. 

This  principle  has  always  been  followed,  either  in  set 
terms  or  in  some  equivalent  shape,  in  all  Settlement 
systems. 

In  all  systems  which  deal  with  a  landlord,  the  middle- 
man may  be  an  actual  person  or  an  ideal  person — a  body 
or  a  community  considered  as  one  legal  person,  by  means 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE VENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  287 

of  a  representative  (as  in  the  North- Western  Settlements). 
In  other  systems,  where  there  is  no  middleman,  actual  or 
ideal,  the  cultivator  is  directly  settled  with.  In  the  former 
case,  under  whatever  necessary  limitations,  the  Zamindar, 
the  Taluqdar,  or  joint  body  of  village  co-sharers,  is  '  owner' 
or  '  proprietor.'  To  say  that  a  man  is  '  proprietor,'  and 
that  he  is  the  '  malguzar '  or  revenue-payer,  are,  in  our 
official  literature,  practically  synonymous ;  to  say  that 
a  man  pays  four  annas  of  the  revenue,  means  also  that 
he  is  owner  of  one-fourth  of  the  estate,  fractions  being 
commonly  stated  in  so  many  '  annas  \  (sixteenths)  of  the 
'rupee'  (taken  as  the  total).  And  even  in  Madras  and 
Bombay,  where  (as  explained  in  Chapter  IV)  no  landlord 
body  had  grown  up  over  the  village  cultivators,  so  that 
they  could  not  be  regarded  as  a  jointly  responsible  pro- 
prietary of  the  whole,  the  individual  occupants  were 
nevertheless  vested  by  law  with  a  definite,  transferable, 
and  heritable  right,  subject  to  the  revenue  demand :  and 
this,  for  most  practical  purposes,  is  undistinguishable  from 
a  proprietary  title  1. 

II.  Another  thing  to  be  observed  in  the  Bengal  Settle- 
ment is,  that  the  amount  of  revenue  to  be  paid  by  the 
Zamindar  being  once  ascertained,  that  amount  was  fixed 
for  ever  under  the  law  of  1793.     Hence  this  first  experi- 
ment in  Settlements  is  called  the  PEEMANENT  SETTLEMENT. 

III.  The  amount  was  determined,  not  with  reference  to 
any  area-survey,  any  consideration,  that  is,  of  the  number, 
various  fertility,  or  productive  power,  of  the  acres  held  in 
each  case,  or  of  the  influence  of  proximity  to  market  and 
facility  of  communication,  on  the  value  of  produce.     Local 
scrutiny,  as  we  shall   see,  was  directly  forbidden  to  the 
Collectors  ;  they  were  directed  to  make  the  best  estimate 
they  could,  of  a  fair  lump  sum  for  the  whole  estate,  on  a 
consideration  of  what  sums  had  been  paid  in  the  past,  and 
of  the  general  prosperity  of  the  owners. 

1  For  remarks  on  the  occupancy  tenure   defined   by  statute,  but   is 

rights  in  Bombay,  see  the  chapter  practically   settled   by  judicial  de- 

on  Land-Tenures  in  Bombay.  The  cision  to  be  proprietor  of  his  holding. 
Madras  raiyat  has  not  had  his 


288  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

§  2.    Remarks  on  the  three  features. 

These  features  demand  some  further  remark,  as  having 
given  rise  to  various  and  important  results. 

The  first  feature  in  itself  needs  no  comment,  especially  in 
view  of  our  immediate  subject.  But  indirectly,  the  ques- 
tion of  'proprietor'  and  his  'title'  have  given  rise  to  all 
those  difficult  questions  about  grades  of  proprietary  interest 
and  privileges  of  tenant-right,  which  have  been  such  a 
source  of  controversy  in  India.  An  outline  of  the  subject 
was  presented  in  Chap.  IV.  Sec.  iv.  p.  196. 

§  3.   The  second  feature. 

This  feature — the  permanency  of  the  assessment — has 
had  a  great  influence.  For  a  long  time,  and  under  other 
methods  of  Settlement,  which  we  shall  have  to  discuss, 
people  thought  that  as  soon  as  a  fairly  good  method  was 
elaborated,  the  resulting  assessment  might  be  declared 
fixed  and  unalterable.  After  the  first  Settlements  of  the 
North -West  Provinces,  for  example,  a  great  discussion 
arose,  and  was  continued  for  some  years  ;  indeed,  the 
question  of  a  Permanent  Settlement  for  all  districts 
lingered  on,  till  it  received  its  quietus  in  a  despatch  of 
the  Secretary  of  State  in  1882.  The  history  of  this  ques- 
tion is  important,  but  will  not  be  understood  till  some 
description  of  the  other  Settlement  systems  has  been  given. 
I  therefore  defer  its  further  mention  for  the  present. 

§  4.  Effects  of  Laws  for  the  Realization  of  Revenue. 

But  connected  with  this  subject,  though,  perhaps,  in- 
directly, is  the  law  enacted  for  the  realization  of  the 
revenue. 

While  the  Government  had  conferred  valuable  rights 
on  the  Zamindars,  it  required  of  them  (what  they  had  been 
little  in  the  habit  of  rendering)  a  prompt  and  punctual 
payment  of  the  fixed  revenue  amount.  From  the  first  it 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  289 

was  notified  that  if  the  instalments  ('kist,'  or  properly 
'  qist ')  were  not  paid  at  due  date,  the  estate  would  be  sold. 
Government  would  not  imprison  the  person  of  the  land- 
lord, nor  take  his  private  goods  and  chattels  l  ;  that  would 
be  an  indignity.  As  will  appear  more  fully  in  the  sequel, 
circumstances  brought  about  a  vast  number  of  sales  for 
arrears  of  revenue  2  during  the  first  ten  years.  And  as 
these  sales  introduced  a  purchaser  who  necessarily  had 
a  clear  title,  another  bouleversement  of  the  tenant  relations 
resulted.  This  last  is  a  question  of  tenures,  and  does  not 
now  concern  us;  but  the  subject  of  'sale-law'  is  here 
mentioned,  as  it  is  a  distinctive  feature  of  the  old  Bengal 
revenue-administration. 

§  5.   Remarks  on  the  third  feature. 

The  fact  that  the  Permanent  Settlement  was  made 
without  any  survey,  and  without  any  record  of  landed 
rights  and  interests,  has  proved  more  fraught  with 
evil  consequences  than  perhaps  any  other  feature  of  the 
Settlement.  It  is  difficult  now  to  say  what  Lord  Cornwall! s 
really  thought  when  he  prohibited  any  detailed  scrutiny  of 
the  estates ;  but  his  first  object  was  to  be  liberal  to  the 
Zamindar,  and  to  make  him  feel  secure  as  to  the  intentions 
of  the  Government ;  and  to  do  this  it  seemed  important 
to  prohibit  all  minute  inquisition  into  his  affairs  or  rents, 
and  to  fix  a  lump  assessment  on  general  considerations. 
For  the  same  reasons,  it  was  impossible  to  harass  him  with 
conditions  about  his  subordinate  tenants  and  with  vexa- 

1  The  law  is  spoken  of  as  the  especially  under  the  circumstances 
'Sunset  law'  The  Deputy-Collector  of  the  terrible  famine  of  1772,  of 
would  sit  in  his  Treasury  office  on  which  such  a  graphic  account  is 
'  Kist-day'—  the  latest  date  for  pay-  given  in  Hunter's  Annals  of  Rural 
ment  of  the  revenue  instalment —  Bengal.  The  country  had  not  re- 
till  he  saw  the  sun  go  down.  Then  covered  from  it  in  1789.  But  as 
he  closed  the  doors.  The  man  who  cultivation  extended,  peace  bore  its 
rushed  up  with  his  bag  of  money  fruits,  and  prices  rose,  the  assess- 
after  the  door  was  shut,  would  be  ment  became  lighter  and  lighter  ; 
too  late.  and  sales  of  course  became  less 

1  The  revenue,  though  per-  frequent.  At  the  present  day  it  is 

manently  fixed,  was  not  at  first  extremely  light,  probably  not  more 

very  light :  it  is  admitted  by  good  than  one-third  or  even  one-fourth 

judges  to  have  been  the  reverse,  of  what  it  ought  to  be. 

VOL.  I.  U 


2QO  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

tious  interference  in  his  dealings  with  them.  It  was 
supposed  that  the  newly-acknowledged  landlord  would 
extend  cultivation,  and  thereby  enlarge  his  own  receipts ; 
that  he  would  improve  the  class  of  crops  grown ;  and,  as 
differential  rates  were  always  acknowledged  for  richer  and 
poorer  crops,  it  was  vaguely  supposed  that  rentals  would 
rise  in  this  way.  Whatever  the  process,  the  landlord 
would  certainly  become  rich  ;  on  the  other  hand,  he  would 
employ  and  liberally  pay,  more  and  more  labour ;  every- 
where he  would  be  known  as  the  benevolent  landlord  of  a 
contented  tenantry ;  he  would  abstain,  under  the  strict 
orders  of  Government,  from  levying  '  cesses  '  in  addition  to 
the  rents,  which  latter,  it  was  supposed,  would  settle 
themselves  by  the  good  understanding  of  both  parties  ;  he 
would  always  grant  a  '  patta '  (pottah)  to  his  tenants,  and 
so  have  it  definitely  on  record  what  land  they  held,  and 
what  rent  they  were  to  pay.  Lastly,  as  both  classes  grew 
rich,  though  the  land-revenue  would  not  alter,  other 
revenues  would  increase  ;  for  wealthy  people  demand  more 
and  more  in  the  way  of  foreign  imports  and  articles  of 
luxury,  and  the  custom-house  would  reap  the  benefit  in 
the  shape  of  duty.  All  these  expectations  have  been 
rudely  disappointed,  with  some  rare  exceptions  ;  the  Za- 
mindars,  as  a  class,  did  nothing  for  the  tenants  but  rack- 
rent  them,  or  hand  them  over  to  'patnidars'  or  rent-farmers, 
who  did  so  still  more.  They  made  no  improvements ;  and 
their  wealth  did  not  augment  the  general  revenues  by 
income  from  other  sources  of  indirect  taxation.  All  the 
while,  the  want  of  a  survey  (for  revenue  purposes)  has  been 
seriously  felt.  Agricultural  statistics,  which  are  available 
for  other  provinces,  are  wanting  in  Bengal.  But  even  to 
enumerate  the  inconveniences,  the  difficulties  under  the 
tenant-law,  and  the  endless  litigation,  that  the  absence  of 
an  authoritative  record  of  subordinate  rights  may  cause, 
would  occupy  more  space  than  I  can  here  give.  In  short, 
some  day  a  district  cadastral  survey  and  a  record  of 
rights  and  rents  must  come;  and  the  sooner  it  is  com- 
menced, the  better  it  will  be  for  the  province. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-BE  VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  291 


SECTION  VII. — EESULTS  OF  THE  ACQUISITION  OF  OTHER 
PROVINCES. 

§  i.  Different  conditions  occur. 

But,  whatever  may  have  been  thought  of  the  'method  of 
assessing  the  revenue  in  Bengal,  the  continuance  of  that 
method  in  other  provinces  which  came  under  British  rule 
was  rendered  practically  impossible  by  the  totally  different 
circumstances  of  those  provinces.  I  would  here  invite  the 
reader  to  refer  to  the  coloured  map,  in  which,  by  means  of 
tints,  each  referring  to  a  certain  year  or  group  of  years,  I 
have  shown  how  the  different  districts  and  provinces  gradu- 
ally were  added  to  the  East  India  Company's  dominions. 

§  2.  Madras. 

The  first  grant  was  that  of  the  districts  in  the  north 
of  MADRAS,  called  the  '  Northern  Sirkars  V  In  these 
districts  there  were  local  chiefs  who  had  the  management 
of  the  revenues,  and  were,  in  fact,  Zamindars,  like  those  in 
Bengal.  But  in  other  districts  of  Madras  that  fell  to  our 
lot  as  the  result  of  escheats,  and  the  wars  with  Mysore  in 
1791  and  1799,  there  were  no  Zaminddrs.  In  some  dis- 
tricts there  were,  indeed,  chiefs  called  '  polygars '  (pale- 
gara).  In  origin,  they  were  frontier  chiefs — relics  of  that 
Hindu  organization  which  I  have  described.  Under 
favourable  circumstances,  they  would  all  have  been  recog- 
nized as  Zamindars  and  landlords,  and,  indeed,  some  few  of 
them  were  so  recognized ;  but  the  majority  of  them  chose 
to  resist  and  to  rebel,  and  the  '  polygar  wars,'  as  the 
books  call  the  military  campaigns  necessary  to  put  them 
down,  have  added  not  a  few  stirring  pages  to  the  military 
history  of  Madras. 

1  Sirkar  (or  Circar  as  the  popu-       madan  system    already  described, 
lar    form    is)    was    the    Revenue       p.  256. 
division  or  district  of  the  Muham- 


U    2 


LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BKITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  V. 


§  3.   Permanent  Settlement  ordered.  —  Its  failure. 

By  the  time  the  Madras  territories  were  fairly  con- 
solidated, Lord  Cornwallis's  principles  were  in  full  force  ; 
a  Permanent  Settlement  was  ordered  and  carried  out 
(though  with  some  improvements  as  to  the  'tenant's' 
position)  in  North  Madras,  and  in  the  case  of  certain  peace- 
able '  polygars.'  But  how  was  it  to  be  effected  for  Chingle- 
put,  Salem,  and  Tanjore,  and  the  '  Ceded  Districts,'  where 
there  were  no  Zamindars  ?  The  unhappy  idea  that  occurred 
to  the  authorities  was  to  create  landlords,  by  making  the 
villages  into  large  groups  or  parcels,  called  inuttha  (mootah 
of  the  old  reports),  and  selling  the  Settlement  rights  to  the 
highest  bidder  !  The  real  Zamindar,  in  his  natural  growth 
of  a  century  and  a  half,  was  bad  enough  ;  but  what  could 
be  said  for  an  auction-room  landlord?  Of  course  the 
system  failed  miserably. 

§  4.   Commencement  of  a  neiu  method. 

Meanwhile,  the  Madras  authorities  were  making  a  new 
departure.  They  had  not  civil  servants  enough  to  under- 
take all  the  district  Settlements,  and  they  determined  to 
employ  some  of  the  ablest  of  their  military  servants,  who 
had  gained  familiarity  with  the  languages,  localities,  and 
people,  in  the  course  of  their  military  duty.  New  men 
have  new  ideas  ;  and  if  these  are  only  based  on  a  real 
acquaintance  with  the  people  in  their  village  homes,  they 
are  likely  to  be  valuable.  It  is  enough  to  name  CAPTAIN 
MUNBO  (afterwards  Sir  Thomas  Munro,  Governor  of 
Madras)  as  among  the  ablest  of  these  Settlement  officers. 
In  the  Madras  chapters  I  give  all  details,  but  here  I  may 
shortly  mention  that  MUNEO  developed,  if  he  did  not  origin- 
ate, the  idea  of  surveying  the  districts  and  dealing  direct 
with  the  village  landholders. 

To  advocate  and  to  defend  this  system,  he  wrote  many 
able  minutes,  and  conferred  with  the  Court  of  Directors 
at  home  in  1807:  the  result  was  the  authoritative  adop- 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  2Q3 

tion   of  the    system   known    as  the   '  RAIYATWARI  '    Set- 
tlement. 


§  5.    Circumstances  which  led  to  the  neiv  system. 

The  villages  of  the  Madras  districts  were,  as  we  have 
seen,  mostly  of  the  non-landlord,  or  raiyatwdri  type.  And 
even  where  high-caste  families  or  colonizing  adventurers 
had  once  established  themselves  as  landlord  communities, 
the  results  of  later  Hindu  conquests,  and  of  the  Muham- 
madan  rule,  where  it  had  extended,  had  been  to  destroy 
such  rights,  and  to  reduce  the  village  cultivators  to  a 
common  level.  There  were,  here  and  there,  more  or  less 
vague  recollections  that  some  of  the  villagers  held  a  supe- 
rior position ;  they  claimed  mirdsi  rights  (rights  by  ancient 
inheritance),  and  so  forth ;  but  this  was  exceptional : 
speaking  generally,  the  villages  were  only  aggregates  of 
separate  cultivators,  held  together  under  a  common  head- 
man, each  man  regarding  himself  as  only  responsible  for, 
and  connected  with,  his  own  land.  On  the  whole,  it 
was  clear  that  a  system  of  dealing  with  the  individual 
occupants  of  the  land  would  be  best.  The  system  now 
proposed,  was  to  commence  with  a  survey  of  fields,  to 
classify  these  according  to  soil,  and  then,  by  various 
means,  to  determine  a  sum  of  money  to  which  each  should 
be  separately  assessed.  Claims  to  the  waste,  or  other 
vestiges  of  privilege  belonging  to  a  once  superior  class, 
would  be  practically  adjusted,  within  the  lines  of  the 
system. 

§  6.   Features  of  the  Raiyatwdri  system. 

The  effect  of  former  misrule  in  many  of  the  districts  had 
been  to  inspire  a  great  dread  of  a  fixed  revenue  responsi- 
bility. But  few  of  the  cultivators  cared  to  be  bound  down 
(so  to  speak)  to  their  farm  or  holding  ;  if  they  could  not 
make  it  pay,  they  would  give  it  up  rather  than  owe  the 
revenue — so  thoroughly,  in  a  large  number  of  instances,  had 
private  property  in  land  been  broken  down.  It  was  there- 


294  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.       [CHAP.  v. 

fore  a  principle  of  the  new  system  that  each  man  was  free 
to  hold  his  land,  subject  to  payment  of  the  assessment,  or 
to  give  notice  and  relinquish  it  if  he  pleased. 

The  waste  (and  abandoned)  fields  were  not  given  over  to 
villages,  except  a  limited  area  for  pasture.  The  waste 
'  numbers '  were  retained  in  the  hands  of  the  State,  as  a 
means  of  extending  cultivation  and  increasing  the  revenue, 
when  better  times  came,  and  land  was  more  in  demand. 
Any  man  (with  a  certain  preference  in  favour  of  old  culti- 
vators) was  at  liberty  to  apply  for  a  vacant  or  waste 
number,  on  agreeing  to  pay  the  revenue  which  would 
become  due  on  it  according  to  its  class. 

In  order,  therefore,  to  know  what  land  every  cultivator 
had  actually  held  in  each  year,  what  he  was  to  pay,  and 
what  to  receive  remission  for,  an  annual  account  was 
made  out,  under  a  simple  system ;  this  process,  known  as 
the  '  annual  jamabandi,'  is  characteristic  of  the  system  of 
Madras  and  of  Bombay  also. 

§  7.  The  Mode  of  Assessment. 

It  was  long  before  any  definite  mode  of  assessment  was 
adopted.  The  first  Settlements  endeavoured  to  find  out 
rates  for  the  different  classes  and  kinds  of  soils  adopted  for 
assessment  purposes ;  and  in  doing  so,  regard  was  had  to 
existing  rates  ;  perhaps  I  ought  to  say  great  reliance  was 
placed  on  them.  It  was  known  that  under  the  late  rulers, 
certain  sums  were  paid  for  certain  fields,  and  were  shown 
in  the  accounts.  But  these  rates  were  probably  very  high, 
and  moreover  had  to  be  adjusted  and  equalized,  to  give 
soil-rates.  Then  too,  there  was  free  recourse  to  consultation 
with  the  people  and  comparing  one  village  with  another. 
Rates,  in  short,  were  founded  partly  on  old  accounts,  and 
partly  on  estimates  based  on  general  considerations  and 
the  local  officers'  sense  of  fitness. 

The  local  officers,  I  suspect,  were  much  inclined  to  lower 
the  rates  ;  but  the  necessities  of  the  Government  in  those 
days  rendered  reduction  an  unpalatable  proposal,  and  hence 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  295 

they  did  not  venture  to  be  as  liberal  as  they  would 
have  wished.  Whether  this  is  so  or  not,  the  fault  of  the 
early  Settlements  certainly  was,  that  the  rates  were 
pitched  too  high.  They  worked  so  badly  (in  that  respect) 
that  the  history  of  our  revenue-administration,  as  found 
in  the  District  Manuals,  is  chiefly  an  account  of  revisions 
and  remissions,  and  of  devices  for  mitigating  over-heavy 
assessments x. 

It  was  also  a  common  practice  in  the  earlier  Settlements, 
to  discover  the  produce  of  an  acre  of  each  class  of  soil,  to 
value  that  produce — of  course  a  low  average  quantity — at 
an  average  price  deduced  from  a  number  of  yearly  price- 
tables,  and  then  to  calculate  out  the  costs  of  cultivation 
and  profits  of  stock,  and  take  a  fraction — never  exceeding 
fifty  per  cent. — of  the  balance.  This  method  is  still  recog- 
nized in  Madras,  to  some  extent  at  least,  and  especially  as 
a  test  for  checking  rates  arrived  at  in  other  ways. 

As  a  method  pure  and  simple,  it  is  an  impossible  one; 
the  '  average  produce '  never  can  be  ascertained ;  the  cir- 
cumstances of  localities — even  those  near  together — are  too 
unaccountably  various ;  and  the  costs  of  cultivation  may 
be  calculated  by  the  most  experienced  officers  at  widely 
different  figures  for  the  same  areas. 

The  modern  system  of  Madras  assessment  has  developed 
more  in  the  direction  of  making  simple  and  accurate  the 
classification  of  soils,  and  applying  a  comparatively  simple 
scale  of  rates  to  the  soils,  than  in  any  novel  method  for 
fixing  the  rates  themselves. 

The  soil  classification  is  both  simple  and  neat ;  and  it 
answers  every  purpose.  A  different  classification  and 
grouping  are  adopted  in  '  dry  lands,'  i.  e.  those  cultivated  by 
rain,  or  by  wells,  and  those — chiefly  rice-lands — which  are 
'  wet,'  or  habitually  irrigated  by  tanks.  First  of  all,  there 
is  the  usual  grouping  of  villages  according  to  position;  for 
it  is  obvious  that,  given  a  certain  kind  of  soil,  the  same 

1  The  accounts  too,  bristle  with  ology,  which  gives  the  Revenue  his- 
technicalities  and  the  most  heart-  tory  an  air  of  mystery  and  difficulty 
rending  local  vernacular  phrase-  which  does  not  really  belong  to  it. 


296  LA.ND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

rate  may  be  too  high  if  the  village  is  in  a  remote  inacces- 
sible group,  and  too  low  if  it  is  in  command  of  a  good 
market  and  close  to  an  important  line  of  communication. 
Soils  are  naturally  divided  into  certain  series — '  black 
soil,'  '  red  soil,'  &c.,  &c.  But  each  series  will  have  several 
classes,  according  to  the  proportion  of  the  mineral  material 
which  gives  the  character  to  the  soil.  This  is  technically 
called  '  clay.'  Every  series  may  show  a  soil  (I)  nearly  all 
'  clay,'  (II)  half  clay  and  half  sand,  (III)  mostly  sand.  These 
are  the  classes  of  the  series.  And  once  more,  each  class  of 
each  series  may  differ  within  itself ;  there  may  be  a  '  good ' 
sort,  or  '  best,'  'ordinary,'  or  '  worst,'  &c.,  of  the  same  class. 
As  the  I,  II,  III  classes  belong  to  the  first  series,  and  the  IV, 
V,  VI  to  the  second,  and  so  on,  the  Koman  numeral  used 
for  the  classes  suffices  also  to  include  the  series.  The  sort 
is  indicated  by  an  Arabic  numeral.  Thus,  having  a 
standard  table  in  use,  there  is  no  occasion  to  write  out  at 
length,  series,  class,  and  sort,  but  only  the  two  numerals. 
Thus  '  IV.  5 '  by  the  table,  indicates  '  Regar '  series  of  the 
mixed  or  loamy  class,  and  of  the  '  worst '  sort. 

It  is  not  necessary  to  have  a  separate  rate  of  assessment 
for  each  separate  class  and  sort,  because  it  is  obvious  that 
the  same  rate  which  suits  one  kind  in  one  group  of  villages 
will  suit  other  kinds  in  other  groups. 

Hence  lists  of  rates  are  made  out,  called  '  taram.'  In  all, 
let  us  suppose,  that  twelve  rates  will  cover  XIV  classes, 
with  their  sorts.  Then  the  first,  or  highest,  taram  will 
apply  (in  dry  soils)  to  the  best  land  in  the  first  group  ;  the 
second  taram  of  the  first  group  will  be  the  first,  or  highest, 
of  the  second  group ;  the  third  will  be  the  highest  of  the 
third  group,  and  so  on ;  the  lowest,  or  twelfth,  taram 
will  probably  not  be  used  in  the  first  group,  and  only  in 
the  second  and  lower  groups. 

The  actual  taram -rates  per  acre  are  ultimately  based 
on  a  calculation  of  an  average  produce  of  one  or  two 
'  standard '  grains,  valued  at  a  low  average  price. 

The  grains  selected  as  the  '  standard '  are  always  food- 
grains,  and  are  ascertained  by  referring  to  the  statistics  of 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-SEVERE  ADMINISTEATION.  297 


a  taluka,  and  seeing  what  food-grains  are  most  largely 
cultivated. 

The  costs  of  production  are  calculated  and  deducted,  and 
fifty  per  cent,  of  the  balance — not  more — is  taken  as  the 
Government  revenue  per  acre. 

There  are  special  charges  and  allowances  made  where 
the  land  bears  two  crops  in  the  year;  but  for  such  details 
the  chapter  on  Madras  must  be  consulted. 

But  though  this  calculation  of  average  produce  duly 
valued,  and  the  deduction  of  costs,  and  the  taking  a  fraction 
of  the  balance,  represents  the  theory1,  as  a  matter  of  fact 
existing  rates  (as  these  have  been  in  the  course  of  years 
modified  till  they  work  well)  are  much  looked  to,  and  they 
can  be  altered  on  general  considerations,  and  without  a 
lengthy  re-calculation,  when  necessary. 

Thus,  when  a  calculation  on  the  produce-basis  has  once 
been  made,  and  prices  have  steadily  risen  since ;  the  rate 
can  be  raised,  at  a  revision,  by  a  simple  percentage  addi- 
tion. And  so  with  the  calculation  of  costs  made  to  get 
the  net  balance.  It  is  rarely  that  a  new  investigation  has 
to  be  made ;  figures  are  taken  from  neighbouring  districts, 
or  other  talukas  similarly  situated,  and  the  use  of  these  is 
justified  in  various  ways. 

It  is  also  a  feature  of  this  system  that  certain  remissions 
for  loss  of  crop  are  regularly  allowed  at  the  annual  jama- 
bandi ;  this  is  not  found  in  any  other  system. 


1  Here  is  an  example  given  briefly 
and  in  abstract : — Suppose  a  taluka 
has  13  per  cent,  of  '  Ragi '  cultiva- 
tion, and  13  of  '  Varagu/  and  these 
are  the  highest  of  the  food-grains. 
Other  grains  approximate  in  value, 
so  that  we  can  treat  them  prac- 
tically as  if  they  were  Ragi  and 
Varagu,  respectively.  Thus  we  may 
let  the  whole  produce  be  fairly 
represented  by  48  per  cent.  '  Ragi ' 
and  52  per  cent.  '  Varagu,'  or 
roughly,  half  and  half.  Then, 


taking  a  class  and  sort  of  soil  (say 
IV.  2)  in  the  first  or  best  group  of 
villages,  the  outturn  of  grain  is 
found  to  be  320  Madras  measures 
of  Ragi  and  440  Varagu.  Roughly 
each  acre  has  50  per  cent,  of  each, 
or  1 60  +  220,  and  the  value  by  the 
price  table  is  R.  7.1.7  +  6.1.11  =  13.3.6. 
Suppose  the  costs  of  cultivation  to 
be  R.  6.3.6  ;  then  the  net  produce  is 
7.0.0.  50  per  cent,  of  this  is  R.  3.8.0, 
which  is  the  taram  (or  revenue  rate) 
applicable. 


298  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

§  8.    Rates  not  permanent. 

In  the  early  days  expressions  may  be  found  in  many  of 
the  official  minutes,  to  show  that  it  was  then  thought 
possible  to  fix  rates  once  for  all ;  so  that  though  the 
revenue  would  rise  by  new  lands  being  brought  under 
cultivation,  the  rates  would  not  alter.  But  the  Settle- 
ments, as  I  have  said,  made  before  the  modern  system 
was  developed,  worked  so  badly,  that  the  rates  had  to  be 
again  and  again  revised ;  doubtless  this  had  its  effect  in 
showing  how  unwise  it  is  to  talk  about  a  permanent  Settle- 
ment, while  information  as  to  rates  is  not  perfect,  or  while 
conditions  are  in  any  degree  undeveloped. 

The  tendency,  in  revision  Settlements,  not  to  alter  rates 
found  to  work  well,  is  distinctly  visible  in  Madras.  Indeed 
it  is  laid  down  as  a  principle,  that  at  revision,  no  change 
is  to  be  made,  except  on  the  ground  of  a  general  rise  in 
prices. 

§  9.   'Ceded'  and  'Conquered'  Districts  in  Upper  India. 

While  the  Madras  Raiyatwdri  system  was  being  worked 
out  and  discussed  in  letters  from  home  (which  I  quote  in 
the  Madras  chapters),  there  had  been  important  ADDITIONS 
to  BENGAL.  Passing  over  the  Benares  province,  which  was 
permanently  settled  in  I795-961,  we  come  to  the  year  1801, 
when  a  number  of  districts  were  '  ceded '  by  the  Oudh 
Government,  in  order  that  the  revenue  might  pay  for 
troops  to  defend  the  King  of  Oudh  from  his  many  enemies. 
And  two  years  later  (1803)  the  result  of  Lord  Lake's  cam- 
paigns had  been  to  wrest  from  the  Marathas  a  number  of  dis- 
tricts adjoining  the  former  (and  extending  into  what  is  now 
the  Panjab  Province)  known  as  the  'conquered'  districts. 
The  same  campaign  also  added  to  Lower  Bengal  the  districts 

1  The  ordinary  law  and  practice  rights  recorded,  and  management 

were    followed  ;    but    the    tenures  carried  on  exactly  as  in  the  rest  of 

were  somewhat  different.  Moreover,  the  province,  with  the  one  special 

being  soon   annexed   to  the  other  feature  that  the  assessment  is  un- 

North-West  Provinces,  the  Benares  alterable, 
districts  were  in  time  surveyed,  all 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  299 

of  Orissa.  The  student  will  remember  that  when  the  Em- 
peror granted,  in  1 7 65,  the  civil  government  of  Bengal  to  the 
Company,  it  was,  in  form,  the  grant  of  '  Bengal,  Bihar,  and 
Orissa.'  The  '  Orissa '  of  those  days  meant  the  district  of 
Midnapore  (Mednipur),  exclusive  of  the  Pataspur  pargana 
beyond  the  Subarnrekha  river.  The  '  Orissa '  conquered 
in  1803  was  described  in  the  Regulations  passed  for  the 
Settlement,  as  the  pargana  of  Pataspur  and  the  Cuttack 
(Katak)  province  (now  Puri,  Balasore,  and  Cuttack). 

In  all  these  districts,  both  of  the  North- West  and  of 
Orissa,  there  were  but  few  Zaniindars.  I  may  pass  by 
Orissa,  as  it  did  not  present  any  such  features  as  led  to 
a  special  theory  of  Settlement :  the  law  ultimately  passed 
for  the  Settlement  of  these  new  territories,  was,  in  reality, 
framed  chiefly  with  reference  to  the  North -West  Provinces. 

§  10.    Absence  of  Zaminddrs- — Strong  Village 
Communities. 

In  the  North- West  Provinces  the  feature  that  brought 
about  a  revolution  in  Settlement  ideas,  was  the  fact  that, 
though  here  and  there  there  were  native  Rajas  who  had 
become  revenue  '  Zamindars '  and  Taluqdars  of  great  estates, 
their  growth  was  not  in  all  cases  equal1  ;  and  whether 
there  were  overlords  or  not,  the  village-bodies  had  (except 
in  parts  devastated  by  the  Rohillas)  preserved  a  vitality 
which  soon  attracted  attention.  There  were,  in  many  of 
them,  bodies  claiming  descent  from  a  chief  or  other  notable 
who  had  founded  the  village  or  obtained  it  on  grant. 
They  were  now  numerous  and  frequently  had  divided  the 
village  into  shares  called  '  patti ' ;  but  they  had  a  strong 
claim  over  the  whole  area,  including  the  site  on  which 
the  village  dwelling-places  clustered,  and  a  certain  extent 
of  waste  and  pasture-ground  beyond.  They  had  never  been 
ground  ddwn  to  being  ( tenants '  under  any  Zamindar,  or  if 
the  process  had  begun,  it  was  not  difficult  to  arrest  it. 

I  do  not  mean,  of  course,  that  all  villages  were  like  this  ; 

1  They  had   not,  in  fact,   grown   into  the  very  nature  of  things  as 
they  had  in  Bengal. 


3OO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

but  this  was  a  salient  feature  among  them.  There  were,  no 
doubt,  many  villages  which  were  only  of  recent  growth. 
Throughout  Rohilkhand,  for  example,  the  Rohillas  had 
destroyed  all  rights,  and  such  villages  as  had  revived,  now 
mostly  contained  groups  of  ruined  tenants  ;  and  a  '  pro- 
prietor '  had  arisen  in  the  person  who  had  come  forward  to 
pay  the  revenue,  ancl  re-establish  the  cultivation1.  Other 
villages  had  really  passed  under  the  power  of  Taluqdars 
and  Rajas,  and  formed  part  of  their  estates.  This  brief 
resume  will,  I  think,  be  quite  sufficient  after  what  has  been 
said  in  the  last  chapter. 

§  ii.  Early  Regulations  did  not  comprehend  the  position. 

At  first,  however,  the  Settlement  Regulations  still  sug- 
gested by  their  language  that  the  Bengal  system  would 
apply.  They  appear  to  suppose  that  there  must  be  a 
landlord  over  every  estate  to  be  settled  with ;  and  the 
permanency  of  the  Settlement  was  contemplated.  As  a 
preliminary  measure,  contracts  were  made  with  farmers 
who  undertook  one,  or  a  few,  or  many  villages ;  and  this 
was  productive  of  great  mischief.  The  Regulations  directed 
that  a  Settlement  should  be  made  for  a  term  of  five 
years  and  then  renewed,  and  then  renewed  again  for  a 
short  term ;  and  that  when  the  fourth  Settlement  was 
complete,  it  should  be  PERMANENT  (if  sanctioned  by  the 
home  authorities).  This,  it  was  thought,  was  a  cautious 
plan,  allowing  ample  time  for  collecting  information,  and 
for  testing  by  practice  the  effect  of  the  Settlements — five 
years  was  long  enough  to  reveal  errors,  and  not  long 
enough  to  stereotype  them.  But  the  design  was  only 
partly  carried  out. 

Two  things  followed :  first,  the  authorities  at  home  were 
by  this  time  thoroughly  aware  of  the  danger  of  fixing  a 
permanent  assessment  on  imperfect  data,  and  for  districts 
not  yet  developed;  they  therefore  prohibited  the  per- 

1  In  the  course  of  a  few  genera-       body  (as  the  case  might  be)  of  pro- 
tions  the    descendants  of   such   a      prietary  co-sharers. 
person  became  a  joint  or  a  divided 


GHAP.  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  30! 

manency  of  the  Settlement  ;  and  a  new  Regulation  had  to 
be  passed  announcing  that  the  assent  spoken  of  in  the  first 
Regulations  was  withheld.  Second,  the  inquiries  gradually 
made,  showed  that  the  true  titles  of  those  who  held 
interests  in  villages  had  been  greatly  overlooked,  and  that 
rights  had  been  destroyed  by  the  farming  system,  and  that 
all  sorts  of  frauds  in  selling  villages  for  arrears  of  revenue 
had  taken  place  ;  this  was  an  additional  reason  for  not 
hastening  a  permanent  Settlement  which  would  have 
necessitated  the  irrevocable  determination  of  who  was  the 
proprietor.  (See  Sec.  VII.  §  i.) 

§  12.    The  Result  of  Settlement  Inquiries. 

When  the  time  for  the  Fourth  Settlement  came  round,  a 
very  capable  Commission  was  appointed  to  make  it  with 
all  care  and  circumspection. 

This  Commission,  with  its  Secretary,  was  so  useful  that 
it  was  afterwards  made  permanent,  and  developed  into  the 
Board  of  Revenue  or  chief  controlling  authority  in  revenue 
matters,  over  the  north-western  districts  of  Bengal.  The 
districts  themselves  were,  as  I  have  explained,  separated 
from  Bengal  in  1834-6,  and  formed  into  a  distinct  province 
under  a  Lieutenant-  Governor. 

The  labours  of  the  Commission  were  concluded  by  a 
report  to  Government  on  which  Mr.  Holt  Mackenzie  wrote 
a  long  and  most  valuable  minute  dated  ist  July, 


§  13.  Holt  Mackenzie's  Minute.  —  Regulation  VII  of  1822. 

This  minute  strongly  protested  against  all  artificial 
creation  of  landlords,  forcing  farmers  of  revenue  and 
headmen,  who  were  mere  representatives  of  the  body, 
into  the  position  of  landlord  ;  and  finally  urged  the  survey 
of  the  districts  and  the  complete  record  of  all  rights  and 
shares  and  interests  in  the  village  lands. 

1  This  invaluable  paper,  which  is  in    the    Revenue    Selections,    North- 

to  the  '  village  Settlement  '  system  Western  Provinces,   1818-20.     Cal- 

what  Mr.  Shore's  minutes  were  to  cutta,  1866. 
the  Bengal  Settlements,  is  reprinted 


302 


LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  V. 


The  result  was  the  passing  of  the  celebrated  Regulation 
VII  of  1822,  which  long  remained  the  central  law  of  the 
TEMPORARY  SETTLEMENT  system 1. 

Under  this  system,  certain  principles  soon  developed. 
The  aim  was  to  restore,  and  even  perhaps  unduly  re- 
store, the  rights  of  the  village  owners ;  recognizing  their 
landlord  character,  they  were  settled  with,  not  indivi- 
dually, but  as  a  joint  body.  That  body  was  jointly  and 
severally  liable  for  the  revenue,  and  was  entitled  to  the 
whole  area  determined  by  the  survey  as  appropriated 
to  the  village,  whether  cultivated  or  waste.  There  were 
some  cases  where  villages  were  clearly  owned  by  Rajas 
or  others ;  and  here  while  the  Raja  (as  Zamindar)  held 
the  Settlement  and  was  'proprietor'  par  excellence,  the 
villagers  became  'subordinate  proprietors,'  in  which  case 
their  rights  were  protected  by  a  sort  of  secondary  Settle- 
ment, called  (formerly)  a  '  mufassal  Settlement 2  ' :  this 
determined,  for  the  whole  period,  what  they  were  to  pay  to 
the  overlord,  just  as  the  main  Settlement  determined  what 
he  was  to  pay  to  the  Government. 


§  14.    Policy  of  setting  aside  the  Overlords. 

But  a  policy  soon  developed  itself,  of  setting  aside  the 
overlord  with  a  '  taluqdari '  money  allowance,  and  settling 
direct  with  the  villagers.  This  resulted  from  the  law  which 
prescribed  that  where  there  were  several  parties  with 
interests  in  the  land,  the  Settlement  Officer  should 
determine,  under  the  orders  of  superior  authority,  with 


1  The  term  '  temporary '  has 
been  always  used  to  indicate  Settle- 
ments that  are  not  permanent.  It 
is  not  a  very  happy  choice,  as  it 
suggests  the  idea  of  something  that 
is  a  make-shift  or  to  be  replaced  by 
something  else.  That  is  not  the 
meaning.  All  that  is  denoted  is 
that  the  assessment  is  fixed  for  a 
period,  usually  thirty  years  (some- 
times less),  after  which  the  rates 
may  be  revised,  and  the  records  of 


rights  also,  if  they  need  it. 

"  I  may  repeat  an  explanation  of 
the  term.  The  Arabic  mufassal 
means  '  separate '  or  distinct. 
Hence  the  '  mufassal  jama '  is  the 
subordinate  revenue  payable  to  the 
overlord  as  distinct  from  that  which 
the  latter  pays  to  the  Government. 
The  term  '  mufassal '  (or  commonly 
mofussil)  is  applied  also  to  the  dis- 
tricts as  distinct  from  the  capital  or 
'  sadr.' 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  303 

which  party  the  Settlement  was  to  be   made,  and   how 
the  interests  of  the  others  were  to  be  recognized. 

§  15.    New  principle  of  Assessment. 

The  next  principle  was  that  the  assessment  was  to  be  on 
a  different  plan  from  that  pursued  in  Bengal.  The  Gover- 
nor-General ordered : — 

'  It  seems  necessary  to  enter  on  the  task  of  fixing  in  detail 
the  rates  of  rent  [revenue]  and  modes  of  payment  current  in 
each  village,  and  applicable  to  each  field  :  and  anything  short 
of  this  must  be  regarded  as  a  very  imperfect  Settlement.' 

The  revenue  was,  in  shor^  to  depend  upon  inquiry  into 
the  actual  produce  of  all  varieties  and  classes  of  land. 
From  the  gross  produce  was  to  be  deducted  the  calculated 
amount  of  the  cost  of  cultivation,  the  wages  of  labour,  &c. ; 
and  the  net  result,  added  to  any  profits  derived  from 
the  produce  of  grazing  and  waste  lands  (and  the  pro- 
spective value  of  waste  when  brought  under  the  plough), 
was  spoken  of  as  the  'assets'  of  each  village  or  other 
estate.  The  Government  revenue  consisted  of  a  fraction, 
at  first  ordered  to  be  two-thirds,  and  afterwards  about  one- 
half,  of  this  sum  of  '  assets  V 

§  1 6.   Duration  of  the  Temporary  Settlement. 

As  the  law  said  nothing  about  the  duration  of  the 
Settlements,  the  Government  fixed  from  time  to  time,  from 
motives  of  policy  and  convenience,  such  term  as  was 
thought  fair.  The  object  was,  to  give  the  village  body  or 
other  proprietor  the  benefit  of  a  solid  property,  encourage 
improvements  by  securing  to  him  the  benefit  of  all  in- 
crease during  the  term  of  Settlement ;  avoiding,  also,  the 
trouble  and  expense  of  a  too  frequent  repetition  of  the 
elaborate  process  of  assessment.  The  term  of  thirty  years 

1  In  the  Bengal  chapters  I  have  of  the  fraction  of  the  estate  assets 
discussed  at  some  length  the  origin  taken  by  Government. 


304  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

was  fixed,  not  by  law,  but  by  executive  order,  for  the  first 
'Regular  Settlement.'  And  this  term  has  become  very 
general  for  Temporary  Settlements.  In  some  cases,  a  period 
of  twenty  or  even  ten  years,  has  been  preferred.  The 
special  considerations  bearing  on  the  subject  in  each  case, 
must  be  reserved  to  the  detailed  chapters. 

§  17.    Explanation  of  'Regular'  and  'Summary' 
Settlement. 

I  may  mention  that  when  it  is  necessary  in  a  new 
province,  to  fix  a  preliminary  amount  of  revenue,  pending 
a  more  exact  adjustment,  and  pending  arrangements  for 
a  survey  and  record  of  rights,  such  a  Settlement  is  called 
a  c  summary'  Settlement.  When  the  full  operations  required 
by  law  have  been  gone  through,  it  is  a  'first  Regular 
Settlement ' ;  and  subsequent  Settlements  are  called  '  Re- 
settlements,' or  '  Revision '  Settlements. 

§  1 8.  '  Temporary'  Settlements  are  also,  in  the  North-West 
Provinces,  village  or  mahdl  Settlements. 

The  Regulation  VII  Settlements  are  spoken  of  as  Settle- 
ments under  the  TEMPORARY  system,  and  also  as  under  the 
VILLAGE,  or,  more  correctly,  the  MAHAL,  system,  because,  in 
the  bulk  of  cases,  the  village  is  the  estate  or  unit.  But  this 
is  not  always  the  case,  for  it  may  be  that  part  of  a  village 
or  parts  of  several  villages  are  held  under  one  title,  and 
therefore  form  the  unit  of  assessment,  or,  in  Revenue 
language,  the  MAHAL.  Sometimes  the  Settlement  is  said 
to  be  '  zamindari,'  not  because  there  is  any  great  landlord 
or  '  Zamindar '  as  in  Bengal,  but  because  the  principle  is 
maintained  that  the  Government  deals  with  a  landlord,  not 
with  the  individual  raiyat ;  only  that  in  this  case  the  land- 
lord is  not  (or  not  usually)  a  single  individual  but  an  ideal 
body, — the  village  community  jointly  liable  for  the  revenue, 
and  regarded  as  a  corporate  unit  represented  by  its  '  lam- 
bardar,'  as  the  headman  is  called  in  the  North-West 
Provinces.  (See  Chap.  IV,  pp.  152-3.) 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  305 

§  19.   Failure  of  the  first  method  of  Assessment. — Modifica- 
tion of  the  Regulation  VII  system. 

For  the  first  eleven  years  but  slow  progress  was  made 
with  the  North -West  system,  as  I  may  shortly  call  it.  The 
machinery  was  insufficient  for  the  purposes  of  such  an 
inquiry  into  produce  as  I  have  indicated.  The  Government 
repeatedly  complained  of  want  of  progress ;  and  the  Board 
were  compelled  to  admit  that  they  could  record  little  or 
none.  The  fact  is,  the  villages  in  the  North -West  Pro- 
vinces, as  a  rule,  are  not  '  raiyatwari ' ;  there  are  landlord 
classes  in  the  villages,  even  where  there  are  not  great 
landlords,  and  they  did  not  .facilitate  such  inquiries.  The 
result  was  (as  we  shall  see  in  more  detail  in  studying 
the  North -Western  Provinces)  that  a  Committee  was  assem- 
bled, over  which  the  Governor- General  presided  in  person ; 
and  Regulation  IX  of  1833  was  passed,  which  improved  the 
official  machinery  and  abolished  the  minute  inquiry  into 
the  produce  of  fields  and  the  costs  of  production. 

§  20.    Tenants  and  Cash  Rents. 

By  this  time  the  use  of  coined  money  was  so  general, 
that  in  the  older  districts,  land  was  not  only  largely  held 
by  tenants  (the  co-sharers  not  themselves  cultivating),  but 
the  rents  were  commonly  paid  in  cash,  not  in  grain ;  and 
thus  it  became  possible  to  adopt  the  system  of  Settlement 
which  has  been  gradually  perfected  into  the  modern  plan. 
I  should  defeat  my  present  object  by  going  into  detail 
(which  is  given  elsewhere),  but  I  may  say  generally,  that 
the  beginning  of  the  new  system  was  first  to  ascertain 
a  general  lump  sum  which  each  estate  could  afford  to  pay ; 
and  this  lump  sum  was  tested  by  seeing  how  it  would 
fall  as  an  acreage  rate  on  the  lands,  and  how  such  rates 
would  compare  with  what  the  Settlement  Officer  calculated 
were  fair  and  proper  rates  for  the  different  sorts  of  land. 
Later  on  in  revenue  history,  the  fixing  lump  sums  was 
discarded,  and  attention  was  given  to  classifying  soils 

VOL.  I.  X 


306  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

carefully  and  determining  acreage  rent-rates  independently 
for  each. 

The  village  system  being  strong,  either  the  original  body, 
or  one  of  later  origin  (the  descendants  of  a  grantee,  village- 
founder  or  revenue-farmer)  had  usually  maintained  their 
lands  and  their  privileges ;  and,  as  a  natural  consequence, 
village  institutions — the  headman  and  the  patwari  (with 
their  records  and  accounts) — had  not  suffered  the  decay 
that  marked  them  under  the  different  historical  conditions 
that  had  arisen  in  Bengal. 

Hence  it  was  possible  to  ascertain  from  the  village  records 
(as  compiled  and  formulated  in  the  Settlement  operations) 
what  rates  of  revenue,  and  to  some  extent  of  rent,  were 
proper.  But  at  first  the  system  demanded  a  great  deal 
more  reliance  on  what  ought  to  be,  and  would  be,  than 
what  actually  was.  And  it  must  be  admitted  that  village 
accounts  were  often  purposely  framed  to  represent  the  rents 
as  lower  than  they  really  were ;  and  the  Settlement  officials 
had  to  'correct'  them  by  bringing  them  up  to  what  (by 
inquiry  and  the  application  of  various  test  calculations) 
they  supposed  them  really  to  be  and  likely  to  become. 
Moreover,  much  land  was  held  by  the  proprietors  them- 
selves, and,  of  course,  paid  no  rent  or  only  a  nominal  sum 
for  village  account  purposes.  This  land  had,  therefore, 
to  have  its  full  rental  ascertained  and  recorded ;  so  too 
there  were  lands,  held  rent-free  in  charity  or  for  religious 
purposes,  which  the  land-owners  granted,  not  the  Govern- 
ment, and  these  had  also  to  be  valued.  By  thus  ascertain- 
ing an  ideal  or  corrected  rent  for  every  acre  in  the  village, 
a  new  total  'assets'  sheet  was  made  out.  It  will  be 
remembered  that  at  first,  owing  to  the  difficulty  of  finding 
out  the  real,  actual,  rents,  the  plan  adopted  was  to  make 
allowance  for  what  it  was  believed,  on  general  consider- 
ations, the  rates  would  be  raised  to  in  the  years  imme- 
diately succeeding  the  Settlement. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  307 

§  21.   Proportion  of  the  total  rental  Assets  taken  by 
Government. 

The  early  rule  was  to  take  two-thirds  of  what  were 
roughly  calculated  to  be  the  '  assets '  of  each  estate.  But 
after  twenty  years  of  gradual  growth  in  the  methods  of 
Settlement,  this  proportion  was  reduced.  When,  under  rude 
methods,  we  take  the  assets  at  a  very  low  figure,  it  is 
morally  certain  that  in  reality  they  are  very  much  greater ; 
and  if  we  take  as  much  as  two-thirds  of  such  lowly- 
calculated  assets,  we  are  really  taking  a  moderate  share. 
But  the  more  our  system  approaches  to  ascertaining  the 
full  income  of  an  estate,  the  more  moderate  must  we  be  in 
the  proportion. 

In  1855  it  was  determined  that  the  Government  share 
should  be  reduced  to  about  fifty  per  cent,  of  the  assets. 

§  22.  Principle  of  the  later  North-Went  Assessments. 

The  later  systems  of  assessment  in  the  North -Western 
Provinces  are  really  successive  attempts  to  perfect  the 
methods  of  calculating  the  rental  assets ;  and  they  have 
twice  been  modified.  The  first  modification  consisted  in 
a  simpler  and  better  soil-classification  and  in  attending 
more  (but  still  not  entirely)  to  actual  rents.  The  latest 
modification  may  be  briefly  described  as  attending  only 
to  actual  rents. — refusing  all  speculative  additions,  though 
of  course  carefully  correcting  the  village  records,  by  addi- 
tions to  supply  manifest  under-statements,  or  to  fix  rental 
rates  for  lands  for  which  either  privileged  rates,  or  no  rents 
at  all  are  paid,  and  which  are  not  entitled  to  escape  assess- 
ment. Then  we  speak  of  the  '  corrected  assets.' 

§  23.    The  Proprietor's  'Sir.' 

I  have  already  explained  (Chap.  IV.  sec.  ii,  §  47)  the  term 
'  sir,'  and  I  must  ask  the  student  to  familiarize  himself 

X  2 


308  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  V. 

with  it.  When  the  bulk  of  lands  in  any  estate1,  whether 
in  Bengal  or  the  North -West  Provinces,  is  rented  out, 
certain  lands,  often  the  best,  are  kept  in  the  hands  of  the 
co-sharers  (or  the  sole  proprietor  as  the  case  may  be),  and 
are  cultivated  as  the  home-farm,  by  hired  labour,  or  even 
by  the  family  itself.  Such  land  is  called  '  sir.'  It  some- 
times happens,  if  the  revenue  is  light,  that  the  landlords 
are  able  to  pay  the  whole  out  of  the  proceeds  of  the 
rented  lands,  supplemented  by  grazing  fees  from  common 
lands  and  other  miscellaneous  sources  of  income :  and  then 
each  enjoys  his  '  sir  '  for  his  sole  personal  benefit ;  or,  if  the 
income  is  not  sufficient  to  meet  the  Government  demand, 
the  proprietor  (or  each  co-sharer)  may  have  to  make  up 
by  a  rate  or  rent  on  his  '  sir,'  what  is  deficient.  The  im- 
portance of  the  sir  land  in  estimating  the  '  assets '  of  the 
estate  is  very  great.  The  revenue  being  a  fraction  of  the 
'  rental  assets '  as  estimated,  it  is  obvious  that,  in  order  to 
get  at  a  fair  rental  value  for  the  entire  estate,  rent-rates 
must  be  assumed  for  all  •'  sir '  lands,  because  these  are  not 
actually  rented,  and  do  not  appear  in  the  rent-roll  of  the 
village  (or  if  they  do,  it  is  at  nominal  or  privileged  rates). 
If,  therefore,  the  '  sir '  be  valued  at  full  rental  rates,  the 
revenue  of  the  whole  estate  will  be  much  higher  than  if 
some  lower  rates  were  fixed.  And  as  a  matter  of  fact,  the 
holder  of  '  sir '  was  greatly  benefited  by  the  successive 
changes  in  the  assessment  rules.  But  this  is  a  point  of 
detail  which  I  must  reserve  for  the  special  chapters  de- 
voted to  the  North -West  Provinces.  I  will  here  only  men- 
tion that  the  last  modification  allowed  the  sir  to  be  valued 
at  twenty-five  per  cent,  below  the  full  rates  as  calculated  for 
tenants.  In  future  revisions,  however,  this  allowance, 
which  is  certainly  over  liberal,  will  be  reduced  to  between 
ten  and  fifteen  per  cent. 

There  are  also  certain  other  privileges  attached  to  '  sir ' 

1  Any  estate,  that  is,  where  It  is  are  mostly  of  non-agricultural  castes, 

not  a  mere  farm  or  holding  worked  and  the  bulk  of  their  land  is  held 

by  an  (agriculturist)  landlord,  as  in  by  tenants  who  represent  the  old 

the    Panjab.       In     the    provinces  cultivators    before    the    '  landlord ' 

named  in  the  text,  the  landlords  came. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  309 

land.  For  example,  it  may  happen  that  the  estate  is  sold  for 
arrears  of  revenue  ;  the  proprietor  will  not  be  turned  out 
of  his  '  sir,'  but  be  allowed  to  remain  in  possession  as  an 
'  exproprietary  tenant' :  and  the  same  thing  would  happen 
if  the  proprietor  declined  the  terms  of  Settlement  and 
Government  gave  the  estate,  for  a  time,  to  some  one  else. 

When  the  tenant-law  grants  occupancy-right,  with  its 
attendant  rental  limits,  on  ordinary  land,  it  always  ex- 
empts the  proprietor's  sir  from  such  burdens.  It  thus 
becomes  a  matter  of  importance  to  see  that,  under  colour 
of  any  legal  definition  of  '  sir,'  a  proprietor  is  not  enabled 
to  get  the  best  part  of  the  village  lands  into  his  own  hands 
and  so  defeat  one  of  the  most  important  rights  of  the  village 
tenantry.  It  was  (among  "other  things)  to  prevent  an 
incipient  danger  of  this  kind,  that  the  Central  Provinces 
Land-Revenue  Act  was  amended  in  1889. 

This  general  sketch  (and  it  is  not  exhaustive)  will  at 
once  suggest  the  importance  of  the  term  '  sir '  which  crops 
up  again  and  again  in  revenue  literature ;  and  it  should  be 
remembered  accordingly. 


§  34.    The  Panjab  Territory  and  its  Settlement. 

The  history  of  our  territorial  acquisitions  already  given, 
will  have  informed  the  student  that  (exclusively  of  the 
Delhi  districts)  the  Panjab  was  acquired  partly  in  1846, 
and  as  a  whole  in  1849.  ^ne  Delhi  districts  in  the  region 
of  the  Jamna,  and  forming  part  of  the  '  Conquered  districts  ' 
of  the  year  1803,  were  at  first  under  the  North -West  Pro- 
vinces, and  afterwards  (1858)  were  added  to  the  Panjab 
owing  to  the  events  of  the  Mutiny. 

The  Panjab  Settlements  were  made  entirely  on  the  North- 
West  model,  which  was  easily  copied  because  the  villages 
were  of  the  landlord  or  joint  type  and  in  a  still  more 
perfect  state  than  in  the  North- West  Provinces.  From 
causes  which  I  cannot  here  examine,  no  Rajas  and  Taluq- 
dars  had,  as  a  rule,  survived,  over  the  communities  of  Jats, 
Rajputs,  Arains,  and  others.  The  Sikh  rule  had  placed 


310  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

jagirdars  over  many  of  them,  these  being  in  fact  the  chiefs 
of  territories  holding  estates  in  'feudal'  subordination  to 
the  Maharaja  on  the  usual  Hindu  model.  It  was  rarely, 
however,  that  such  overlords  had  grown  into  '  actual  pro- 
prietors.' The  '  superior '  claims  were  almost  all  disposed 
of  by  grant  of  cash  allowances ;  and  in  the  overwhelming 
majority  of  cases,  the  village  joint-body  was  the  imme- 
diate or  actual  landlord.  The  landlord  families  were 
mostly  of  the  agricultural  castes,  and  consequently  the  land 
was  largely  cultivated  by  the  co-sharers  themselves,  and 
only  held  by  tenants  to  a  limited  extent :  these  tenants 
pay  grain-rents  in  most  cases.  Moreover,  there  had  been 
no  farmers  and  revenue  sales  to  speak  of,  so  that  new  pro- 
prietary bodies  (descendants  of  the  farmers  and  purchasers) 
— and  nearly  always  persons  who  do  not  themselves  culti- 
vate— had  not  grown  up  over  the  villages. 

These  features  at  once  necessitated  a  different  mode  of 
ascertaining  the  assets  of  estates  for  revenue  purposes.  As 
cash  rents  paid  by  tenants  were  the  rare  exception,  the 
re7ifaZ-asset  plan  above  described  could  not  be  adopted. 
At  the  same  time  the  method  of  working  out  produce  rates, 
and  calculating  costs  of  production,  was  hardly  more  feasible 
in  the  Panjab  than  it  was  in  the  North- Western  Provinces. 

The  method  actually  adopted  was  that  also  at  first  used 
in  the  North -West  Provinces  (and  especially  for  districts 
where  grain-rents  were  common),  namely,  the  calculation  of 
lump  sums  of  revenue  to  be  distributed  over  the  holdings, 
and  called  the  '  aggregate  to  detail '  method.  It  consisted 
in  looking  to  former  revenue-payments,  and  then,  with  the 
aid  of  local  knowledge  of  the  growth  and  prosperity  of  a 
pargana  or  other  circle  (adopted  with  reference  to  similarity 
of  market  advantages,  soil,  irrigation,  and  other  conditions), 
determining  a  lump  sum  for  the  whole  area,  which  it  was  sup- 
posed would  be  fair.  This  was  tested  by  distributing  it  over 
the  villages ;  and  once  more,  by  dividing  the  village  totals 
over  the  holdings,  it  could  be  seen  whether  these  were  fair. 
Produce- estimates  were  often  made  use  of,  and  by  turning 
into  money  a  sixth,  a  fifth,  and  so  on,  of  the  gross  produce 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  3 1 1 

it  was  seen  how  the  rates  would  compare  with  those  first 
assumed.  Then,  perhaps,  some  lands  did  pay  money-rents, 
and  these  could  be  made  use  of  for  comparison ;  and  so 
also  could  plough-rates,  when  the  people  made  use  of  cer- 
tain rates  for  each  '  plough '  possessed  by  the  village-body. 
Fair  rates  being  thus  got  out  and  submitted  for  sanction,  a 
total  was  again  made  out  for  each  village,  and  the  total 
would  be  finally  modified  with  reference  to  the  class  of 
cultivators,  to  prospects  of  utilising  the  waste,  or  to  profits 
from  grass.  A  village  jama'  would  thus  be  arrived  at ;  and 
this  would  be  distributed  over  the  holdings  in  consultation 
with  the  co-sharers.  These  latter  always  well  understood 
such  an  operation  (called  making  the  '  bachh  ') ;  and  then 
the  whole  business  was  concluded.  It  is  of  no  use  for  my 
present  purpose  to  describe  the  latest  rules  for  assessment : 
they  prescribe  a  more  exact  but  simple  method  of  soil 
classification  and  the  direct  calculation  of  revenue-rates 
per  acre,  which  rates  are  one-half  the  rental  rates  as  ascer- 
tained on  a  basis  of  actually  observed  facts  of  payment,  in 
specimen,  or  standard,  areas.  These  rules  will  be  noticed 
in  detail  in  the  chapters  on  the  Panjab. 

§  25.    The  Central  Provinces  System. 

In  order  to  complete  the  series  of  developments  of  the 
'  village  or  mahal  system,'  I  will  pass  over  what  ought,  in 
point  of  time,  to  have  been  mentioned  before — the  Bombay 
system — and  so  proceed  to  notice  another  development  of 
the  North-West  system.  The  Northern  districts  (Sagar, 
Damon,  and  Jabalpur)  of  what  is  now  called  the  '  Central 
Provinces '  were  early  settled  on  the  North-West  plan,  not 
without  some  considerable  difficulties,  the  record  of  which 
must  be  reserved.  But  when  the  rest  of  the  province  was 
added,  and  the  whole  formed  into  a  Local  Administration 
(under  a  Chief  Commissioner)  in  1863,  there  was  some  dis- 
cussion as  to  what  sort  of  general  Settlement  should  be 
made.  The  villages,  except  a  few  in  the  North,  were  not 
of  the  landlord  or  joint  type,  but  represented  aggregates  of 
cultivators,  each  claiming  his  own  holding  and  nothing 


3 1 2  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

more,  like  the  villages  of  Bombay  and  Madras.  There  is 
no  doubt  that  a  raiyatwdri  Settlement,  as  in  Madras  or 
Bombay,  would  not  only  have  been  possible,  but  highly 
advantageous.  However,  the  North- West  Provinces  prin- 
ciples were  in  the  ascendant,  and  a  village  Settlement  was 
ordered.  But  the  jointly  responsible  body  was  rarely  to 
be  found;  and  the  Maratha  system,  which  had  long  pre- 
vailed, had  also  produced  its  natural  results.  That  system 
was  one  of  keen  financing ;  it  was  as  opposite  as  possible 
to  the  lax  system  of  the  later  Muhammadan  rule ;  a 
Maratha  governor  rarely  (in  such  of  his  territories  as  were 
firmly  in  hand)  farmed  out  the  revenues  of  large  tracts  or 
made  reckless  revenue-free  grants.  He  went  straight  to 
the  villages,  caring  nothing  for  individual  rights,  and  made 
the  pdtel  or  headman  responsible  for  the  village  total 
assessment.  Where  the  local  hereditary  pdtel  was  ineffi- 
cient, or  some  interested  person  could  get  the  preference 
over  him,  he  was  superseded,  and  the  person  who  obtained 
the  farm  of  the  village  was  spoken  of  as  the  mdlguzdr  or 
'  revenue-payer.'  The  persons  thus  employed  and  trusted 
must  have  had  large  and  undefined  powers ;  and  they  con- 
sequently grew  in  influence  and  gradually  acquired  a 
g'wasi-proprietary  position.  It  is  no  doubt  a  matter  of 
opinion  to  what  extent  these  headmen  and  farmers  (whom 
we  now  generically  call  '  malguzars ')  had  really  become 
proprietors.  The  progress  made  in  that  direction  varied 
in  different  districts  and  under  different  local  conditions. 


§  2,6.    Mdlgtizdrs  recognized  as  Village  proprietors. 

However  that  may  be,  it  was  determined  to  make  these 
'  revenue-payers '  '  proprietors,'  and  the  Settlement  was 
made  with  them.  There  might  be  one  '  malguzar,'  or  there 
might  be  several  descendants  of  one ;  but  the  individual  or 
the  body  jointly  was  recognized  as  proprietor ;  and  this 
fact  gave  the  peculiar  character  to  the  Central  Provinces 
Settlement  which  has  caused  it  to  be  popularly  called  the 
i '  Settlement ;  and  it  has  had  curious  results. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  313 

§  27.    Features  of  the  Settlement. 

As  regards  the  first  assessments,  there  is  nothing  par- 
ticular to  record.  They  followed  the  '  aggregate  to  detail ' 
method ;  and  the  interesting  system  of  soil  rent-rates 
elaborated  for  the  present  Settlement  (since  1881)  must  be 
reserved  for  description  at  a  later  stage. 

A  number  of  estates  have  been  left  in  the  hands  of  Gond 
and  other  chiefs  with  the  usual  designation  of  Zamindarl ; 
but  the  noticeable  peculiarity  of  the  more  or  less  artificial 
position  of  'malguzar'  proprietors  is,  that  Government 
never  abandoned  the  village-holders  as  it  did  in  Bengal. 
Nor  did  it  acknowledge  the  '  malguzars '  everywhere.  In 
the  Central  Provinces  we  have  some  tracts  which  are 
frankly  raiyatwdrC 1  (where  there  is  no  over-proprietor  or 
landlord) ;  and  in  the  malguzari  villages  there  are  a  consider- 
able body  of  sub-proprietors  and  a  large  number  of  original 
tenants,  over  whom  the  landlord  has  no  power  as  to  evic- 
tion and  enhancement;  their  rents  are  all  fixed  by  the 
Settlement  Officer  for  the  term  of  Settlement. 

§  38.    Oudh  Taluqddri  System,. 

There  is  one  other  form  of  Settlement  with  a  middleman 
landlord ; — I  refer  to  the  Oudh  Settlement.  The  province  was 
annexed  in  1856.  The  neglect  of  the  local  native  adminis- 
tration had  resulted  in  the  abandonment  of  all  real  control 
over  the  revenue,  and  in  the  adoption  of  a  system  of 
settling  different  tracts  of  country  by  bargain  with  local 
magnates  for  a  fixed  (but  from  time  to  time  enhanceable) 
sum  total  of  revenue.  The  moment  such  a  tract,  called  a 
'  taluq,'  came  on  to  the  State-books,  all  note  of  the  villages 
composing  it  was  dropped,  and  only  the  taluq  and  its 
annual  total  recorded. 

This  course  was  certainly  facilitated,  if  not  initiated,  by 
the  earlier  history  of  Oudh.  The  province  had  been  the 

1  Ajid  so  recognized  by  the  Revenue  law  as  amended  in  1889. 


314  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

very  centre  of  the  old  Aryan  dominions.  To  this  day  the 
limits  of  a  number  of  petty  kingdoms — Gonda,  Atraula, 
and  many  others — can  be  traced ;  and  Mr.  Benett  has  told 
us,  in  more  than  one  excellent  Settlement  Report,  how 
these  kingdoms  were  organized  and  managed,  and  how 
village  communities  grew  up  out  of  their  dismemberment 
and  decay.  The  petty  kings  were  probably  once  united  in 
a  confederation  under  some  great  Maharaja ;  but  at  the 
Muhammadan  conquest  they  were  not  strong  enough  to 
resist  the  Great  Mughal,  though  still  able  to  give  him 
much  trouble,  if  not  conciliated  and  made  use  of.  Na- 
turally enough,  they  were  allowed  to  contract  for  a  revenue- 
payment  for  their  old  dominions  (or  such  part  of  them 
as  remained),  and  then  were  called  '  Taluqdars.' 

The  plan  being  profitable,  it  was  extended.  Other 
persons,  namely  Court  favourites,  bankers,  and  speculators, 
occasionally  obtained  similar  grants  of  'taluqs'  and  be- 
came '  Taluqdars';  but  the  marks  of  origin  long  survived  in 
the  ominous  distinction  of  '  pure  '  and  '  impure '  Taluqdars. 

How  far  in  the  century  between  1750  and  1856  the 
Taluqdars  had  by  purchase,  by  violence,  or  by  founding 
new  villages,  really  worked  themselves  into  a  proprietary 
position,  I  cannot  here  examine.  Opinions  still  vary  on  the 
subject ;  and  it  is  obvious  that  the  process,  which  undoubt- 
edly did  go  on,  must  have  reached  very  various  stages  in 
different  places,  and  under  different  conditions,  especially 
with  reference  to  the  character  and  caste  of  the  village 
bodies. 

§  29.    Circumstances  necessitated  the  recognition  of 
Taluqdars. 

Here  I  need  only  note  that,  under  the  North-West 
policy  of  ignoring  the  overlords  and  settling  direct  with  the 
villagers  as  proprietary  bodies,  the  first  plan  of  1856  was 
to  settle  with  the  villagers  under  the  North- West  Provinces 
law.  though  it  must  be  admitted  that,  even  under  that 
plan,  Taluqdars  were  much  more  recognized  as  de  facto 
owners,  than  is  sometimes  supposed. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  3  I  5 

Scarcely,  however,  had  the  Settlement  begun,  when  the 
Mutiny  broke  out,  and  the  Taluqdars,  with  a  few  exceptions, 
revolted.  What  had  been  done  towards  Settlement,  in  the 
matter  of  records,  perished.  The  people  voluntarily  re- 
turned to  the  Taluqdars  and  paid  their  revenue  to  them. 

When  the  pacification  of  1858  ensued,  views  had 
changed;  the  great  body  of  the  Taluqdars  were  am- 
nestied, and  a  Settlement  was  made  with  them.  This 
necessitated  an  elaborate  series  of  provisions  as  to  the 
protection  to  be  afforded  to  villages  in  the  taluqs.  Some 
had  so  far  preserved  their  integrity  that  they  were  en- 
titled to  a  '  sub-settlement ' ;  others  had  not,  but  various 
degrees  of  occupancy-right  and  rent-limitation  were 
acknowledged ;  all  these  measures  have  been  the  subject 
of  much  criticism.  Besides  that,  the  general  question  of 
tenant-right  left  a  long  legacy  of  trouble  which  has  only 
found  its  end  (for  the  present  at  any  rate)  in  the  tenant- 
law  of  1886. 

There  is  nothing  to  call  for  remark  as  to  the  method  of 
Settlement  which  was  based  on  the  earlier  North -West 
Provinces  system.  This  Settlement  is  distinctively  spoken 
of  as  the  TALUQDARf  Settlement. 

§  30.    The  Bombay  System. 

Such  has  been  the  development  and  the  variation  of 
Temporary  Settlement  systems  originating  in  Regulation 
VII  of  1822  and  Regulation  IX  of  1833. 

We  must  now  retrace  our  steps  to  look  to  Western  India. 
The  Bombay  territories  (speaking  generally)  were  acquired 
between  1 803-1 8 1 8,  as  the  result  of  the  defeat  of  the  Maratha 
power.  For  a  long  time  no  progress  was  made  in  the  re- 
venue-administration. A  system  of  farming  the  revenues, 
on  the  basis  of  the  Maratha  or  other  preceding  assessments, 
was  pursued,  and  with  very  unsatisfactory  results. 

There  never  was  any  appearance  of  great  '  Zamindars,' 
so  that  the  Bengal  system  could  not  have  been  thought  of. 
The  bulk  of  the  villages  in  the  Dakhan  districts  were  of  the 


3 1 6  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

raiyatwdrt  type,  though  in  certain  parts  there  were  a  few 
'  narwa,'  '  bhagdari,'  and  other  estates  jointly  held  by  com- 
munities connected  by  a  tie  of  descent.  In  Guzarat,  also, 
the  immigration  of  martial  tribes  of  the  Rajput  type,  and 
the  government  by  chiefs,  had  left  traces  of  an  '  overlord '  or 
taluqdari  tenure  over  the  villages ;  while  in  the  Konkan, 
'khots,'  or  revenue-farmers  of  the  Maratha  rule,  had  ac- 
quired rights  over  the  villages,  of  a  somewhat  peculiar 
character. 

A  portion  of  these  territories  had  originally  been  settled 
by  Malik  'Ambar,  the  best  representative  of  the  power  of  the 
Muhammadan  kings  of  the  South  in  their  palmy  days1.  This 
minister  had  been  at  much  pains  to  secure  and  acknowledge 
a  proprietary  right,  and  this  tended  to  preserve  the  ances- 
tral communities,  where  they  existed ;  since  ancestral  hold- 
ing is,  in  all  Eastern  countries,  the  strongest  form  of 
connection  with  the  soil.  In  his  time,  village  assessments 
in  the  lump,  were  apparently  the  rule ;  and  although  the 
Maratha  system  had  superseded  that  of  Malik  'Ambar, 
and  was  essentially  a  raiyatwari  system,  it  had  not  obli- 
terated the  traces  of  the  former  system.  It  is  therefore 
not  wonderful  that  the  opinion  should  have  been  advocated 
that,  in  Bombay,  the  existing  status  of  the  raiyatwdri 
villages  was  in  many  cases,  if  not  universally,  due  to  the 
decay  of  an  earlier  landlord  or  joint  constitution,  rather 
than  inherent  in  the  nature  of  the  groups  themselves2. 

At  first,  indeed,  the  matter  did  not  come  prominently  to 
notice,  because,  during  the  early  years  of  our  rule,  the  terri- 
tories were  provided  for  by  the  usual  tentative  arrange- 
ments for  farming  the  revenues  on  short  leases.  A  twenty 
years'  experience,  however,  during  which  grievous  hardships 
were  inflicted  on  the  districts,  sufficed  to  make  us  at  once, 
and  for  ever,  discard  the  farmers,  and  set  about  finding 
a  better  plan. 

1  He  also  settled  most  of  Berar.          Vol.  III.    (Bombay  chapters).     At 
a  Details  about  the  faint  survival       best,  the  Dakhan  mirds  right  was 
of  '  mirasi '  claims  will  be  found  in      too  shadowy  for  practical  revival. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  317 


§  31.    Attempt  to  introduce  a  system  of  Settlement  ivith 
Villages  jointly. 

The  raiyatwari  system  was  then  much  in  vogue,  conse- 
quent on  Sir  Thomas  Munro's  action  in  Madras.  But  Mr. 
Elphinstone,  the  then  Governor  of  Bombay,  took  the  view 
above  alluded  to,  about  the  joint  system,  and  was  anxious 
not  only  to  maintain  it  wherever  it  could  be  found,  but  even 
to  create  it  in  the  case  of  those  communities  where  no  land- 
lord claims  survived ;  securing,  indeed,  the  rights  of  each 
cultivator  by  record,  but  establishing  a  joint  responsibility, 
and  settling  with  the  original  '  patels '  or  headmen  of  the 
village  as  representatives  of  the  body. 

It  is  no  easy  thing,  however,  to  create  a  joint  responsi- 
bility where  it  does  not  in  fact  exist.  Although  long  years 
of  custom  may  have  taught  the  cultivator  to  submit  to  an 
annual  adjustment  of  his  individual  burdens  and  liabilities 
by  the  headman,  it  has  never  laid  him  under  any  responsi- 
bility in  case  one  of  his  neighbours  failed  *. 


1  The  account  of  the  Bombay 
system  in  Campbell's  Modern  India 
(1858),  though  giving  a  good  de- 
scription of  Mr.  Elphinstone's 
views,  is  now  too  much  out  of  date 
to  be  otherwise  useful ;  for  the 
Bombay  system  has  since  been 
altered  and  perfected  in  a  way  that 
has  completely  outgrown  a  descrip- 
tion penned  more  than  thirty  years 
ago.  The  account  is  also  to  some 
extent  marred  by  the  author's  ap- 
parent prejudice  in  favour  of  the 
joint  responsibility  and  village 
settlement  with  which  he  was  fa- 
miliar. His  objections  to  the  Bom- 
bay system  (notably  the  costliness 
of  the  village  officials  and  the  re- 
cognition of  rights  to  rent-free  hold- 
ings) affect  mere  accidents  of  the 
place,  they  do  not  touch  the  prin- 
ciples of  the  system.  As  a  matter 
of  fact,  many  of  these  evils  have 
been  removed  or  greatly  mitigated. 
He  also  speaks  of  the  joint  respon- 
sibility as  if  it  was  an  easy  thing  to 
introduce.  But  in  fact  it  is  not  so. 
To  establish  it  artificially  over  whole 
districts,  and  tell  the  people  '  the 


system  is  convenient  to  your  rulers, 
and  when  you  are  wiser  you  will 
see  that  it  is  also  calculated  to  pro- 
mote your  own  interest,'  is  beset 
with  such  difficulties  as  to  make  it 
impracticable.  The  people  posi- 
tively decline  to  undertake  that  the 
solvent  members  shall  be  respon- 
sible for  the  defaulting  ones.  What 
becomes  of  your  system  then  ?  I 
need  hardly  point  out  the  futility 
of  comparing  revenue  systems  in 
point  of  inherent  merit,  because 
every  system  may  be  good  or  the 
reverse  according  as  it  fits  the  facts. 
But  even  admitting  the  superior 
facilities  which  the  joint-village 
system  offers  to  revenue-manage- 
ment, the  originators  of  the  Bombay 
system  claim  for  it  certain  counter- 
balancing advantages.  By  breaking 
up  the  land  into  small  holdings, 
and  allowing  every  occupant  to 
keep  as  many  of  his  '  numbers,'  or 
give  up  as  many,  as  he  thinks  de- 
sirable, the  small  farmer  is  enabled 
to  contract  his  operations  or  enlarge 
them  according  to  the  capital  and 
stock  at  his  disposal.  The  revenue 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 


The  plan  of  settling  for  a  lump  sum  with  the  village  as 
a  body  used  to  be  advocated  because  it  was  said  to  facilitate 
revenue-management ;  it  enabled  Government  to  deal  with 
fewer  units.  The  Bombay  officers  do  not,  however,  admit 
that  there  is  any  difficulty  in  dealing  with  thousands  of 
separate  cultivators 1.  The  difficulty  only  seems  great  to  those 
accustomed  to  deal  with  one  or  with  a  few  revenue-payers. 
At  any  rate,  if  there  is  difficulty,  it  is  obviated  by  a  perfect 
survey,  a  clear  and  complete  record  of  each  lot  or  field  and 
the  revenue  assessed  on  it,  and  by  a  thorough  control  over  the 


being  fixed  for  a  long  term,  of  years, 
the  farmer  gets  all  the  benefit  of  a 
long  lease  without  its  disadvantages. 
Nor  does  the  Government  really 
lose  ;  because  taking  its  revenue, 
not  from  one  estate,  but  from  the 
whole  country,  that  revenue  must, 
under  any  system,  fluctuate  with 
the  circumstances  of  the  country  at 
large.  With  farmers  of  large  capital, 
the  long  fixed  lease  may  answer 
best ;  but  with  those  of  small 
means,  the  risk  and  responsibility 
which  have  to  be  set  off  against  the 
security  of  profits,  are  more  to  be 
considered,  and  such  risks  are 
avoided  by  giving  the  villager  the 
right  of  holding  his  land  from  year 
to  year  only,  if  he  pleases. 

In  the  North-West  Provinces 
every  village  is  allowed  an  area  of 
waste,  which  it  can  bring  under 
cultivation  without  the  total  assess- 
ment of  the  village  being  increased. 
Under  a  raiyatwAri  system,  any 
uncultivated  number  that  is  taken 
up  has  to  be  paid  for  ;  but  in  prac- 
tice this  does  not  interfere  with  the 
extension  of  cultivation  ;  and  as  a 
matter  of  fact,  though  the  North- 
West  assessment  does  not  increase 
when  the  waste  of  the  village  is 


made  to  yield  crops,  still  that  as- 
sessment is  originally  fixed  after 
taking  into  consideration  the  capa- 
bilities of  the  estate,  and  the  prob- 
able average  yield  of  the  whole,  for 
the  entire  term. 

It  is  also  urged  that  the  village 
officers  collect  the  revenue  from 
each  separate  holder  just  as  easily 
as  they  do  from  a  joint  body,  who, 
though  together  responsible,  still 
ultimately  pay  separately  according 
to  known  shares  ;  and  as  under  the 
Bombay  system  every  occupant  is 
furnished  with  a  receipt  book,  which 
the  patw&ri  (paiidyS  or  kulkarni) 
is  bound  to  write  up,  there  is  no 
room  for  fraud.  To  any  one  who 
wishes  further  to  study  the^wos  and 
cons  of  both  systems,  and  the  im- 
provements which  the  Bombay 
authorities  made  on  the  Madras 
system  to  remove  objections,  I  can- 
not do  better  than  recommend  the 
perusal  of  the  able  '  Appendix  I '  to 
the  Official  Correspondence  on  the  Bom- 
bay Settlements  (reprint  of  1877  : 
Bombay  Government  Press). 

1  In  the  Bombay  and  Madras 
Presidencies  the  number  of  raiyats 
and  average  size  of  holdings  are  as 
follows  (Govt.  Ind.  Statistics,  1886-7) : — 


Presidency. 

Number  of 
raiyats. 

Average  size  of  holding. 

Madras 

3,  OSS,  788 

Bombay 

1,284,238 

!  Northern  division  8  acres  ) 
Central           „     32     „      [  21-5  „ 
Southern        „     23     ,,      ) 

CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  3 1 9 

village  accountants  and  revenue-officers  of  small  local  sub- 
divisions of  districts. 

It  was  no  doubt  this  inherent  difficulty  of  creating  a  joint 
responsibility  where  it  did  not,  naturally  or  in  fact,  exist, 
that  led  to  the  abandonment  of  the  design  to  make  village- 
Settlements,  and  to  the  adoption  of  the  separate  field  or 
'raiyatwari'  system.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  a  sort  of  joint 
responsibility  is  kept  up  in  certain  villages  where  the 
rights  of  co-sharers  have  survived  to  this  day. 

§32.    Progress  of  the  system  in  Bombay. 

The  defects  of  the  survey- Settlement,  as  at  first  worked 
(up  to  1 835),  acted  as  a  warning  to  the  authorities ;  and 
a  new  departure  was  then  made.  An  experimental  re- 
survey  of  the  Indapur  taluk  having  proved  successful, 
the  same  method  was  followed  elsewhere.  In  1847 
three  of  the  ablest  Settlement  Superintendents  met  and 
were  able  to  formulate  the  results  of  practical  experience, 
in  the  shape  of  a  complete  scheme  for  the  survey  and 
assessment  of  village  lands.  It  was  not  till  1865  that  a 
local  Act  was  passed  specifically  legalising  the  system. 
This  Act  has  in  its  turn  been  repealed  ;  and  the  whole 
law  has  now  been  completely  revised  in  the  Land-Revenue 
Code  (Bombay  Act  V  of  1879).  There  is  but  little  mention 
of  a  Settlement  (although  the  term  does  occur  in  the  Code) ; 
there  is  really  a  survey  and  assessment  only.  There  is  no 
procedure  like  that  of  Upper  India, —  proposing  a  certain 
sum  as  the  assessment  on  the  whole  village,  discussing 
the  matter  with  the  village  proprietary  body,  and  perhaps 
making  a  reduction  and  coming  to  terms  with  the  re- 
presentatives, who  then  sign  an  agreement  to  be  respon- 
sible. Under  the  Bombay  system,  every  acre  is  assessed 
at  rates  fixed  on  almost  scientific  principles,  and  then 
the  occupant  must  pay  that  assessment  or  relinquish  the 
land. 


32O  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

§  33.    OutliTie  of  the  Bombay  System. 

The  system  will  be  described  more  in  detail  in  the  sequel, 
but  here  I  may  generally  indicate  the  outlines  of  the  pro- 
cedure. 

A  certain  convenient  unit  of  division  is  selected  to  form 
the  '  survey  number '  or  '  field.' 

Every  field  or  lot  is  surveyed,  and  then  the  work  of 
classification  begins.  The  soil-classes  are  noted,  and 
each  field  is  examined  and  a  sort  of  diagram  of  it  made, 
which  shows  not  only  its  soil,  but  any  defects  which  re- 
duce its  value.  It  is  thus  ascertained  for  every  field 
what  is  its  relative  value ;  in  other  words, — taking  the 
maximum  rate  for  the  class  as  one  whole  or  sixteen  annas 
(on  the  Indian  method  of  reckoning), — whether  the  field 
can  be  assessed  at  the  maximum  or  at  something  less, — at 
fourteen  annas,  at  twelve  annas,  and  so  on,  down  to  a 
minimum.  The  department  charged  with  this  work  be- 
comes highly  experienced  in  the  process,  so  that  it  can  be 
performed  with  the  greatest  accuracy  and  fairness.  Culti- 
vation is  usually  classed  into  wet  and  dry :  the  process  just 
described  treats  land  only  on  its  dry  aspect ;  if  there  is  irriga- 
tion, then  an  additional  rate  may  be  charged,  which  will  be 
higher  or  lower  according  to  the  goodness  and  value  of 
the  source  of  irrigation ;  the  rate  is  only  applied  to  such 
land  as  is  really  capable  of  irrigation  from  the  source  in 
question 1. 

Next,  the  Settlement  Officer  begins  his  work  as  assessor 
of  actual  rates ;  he  has  before  him  the  facts  of  soil  classi- 
fication on  its  unirrigated  aspect,  and  the  details  of  the 
means  of  irrigation  where  they  exist ;  he  has  to  fix  what 
are  to  be  the  full  or  maximum  rates  for  dry  soil,  and  what 
are  to  be  the  additional  rates  for  irrigation.  These  rates  he 

1  Wet  cultivation  is  rice  land,  or  directly,  but  a  certain  addition  may 
land  that  is  always  flooded  for  cul-  be  made  to  the  rate,  on  account  of 
tivation.  A  '  dry  '  field  may  have  a  an  easy  supply  of  subsoil  water  re- 
well  or  other  means  of  partial  water-  garded  as  one  of  the  qualities  of  the 
ing,  that  does  not  make  it  '  wet '  soil, 
land.  Wells  are  not  now  charged  for 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADHINISTKATION.  321 

calculates  with  the  aid  of  all  the  data  he  can  collect,  regard- 
ing former  history,  the  general  situation,  climate,  proximity 
to  market,  &c.  Having  thus  arrived  at  the  absolute  or  full 
rates,  the  field  diagrams,  which  show  the  relative  values,  at 
once  enable  the  rates  to  be  applied.  A  sixteen  anna  field 
pays  the  full ;  an  eight  anna  field  the  half,  and  so  on. 

In  Bombay  (just  as  in  Madras)  the  occupant  of  such  a 
survey  number  holds  it  on  the  simple  terms  of  paying  the 
revenue  ;  if  he  admits  that  he  is  (or  is  proved  by  a  decree 
of  Court  to  be)  holding  on  behalf  of  some  one  else,  as  a 
tenant,  or  in  an  inferior  position,  then  the  'superior 
holder's '  name  is  entered  in  the  register,  not  his :  he 
becomes  the  '  inferior  holder,'  and  it  is  the  superior  who  is 
entered  in  the  register  as  the  '  occupant '  responsible  for  the 
assessed  sum.  Any  one  who  is  recorded  as  the  responsible 
holder  can  simply  resign  (if  he  does  not  like  to  pay  the 
assessment)  any  field  in  his  holding.  The  assessment  is 
fixed  for  a  period  of  thirty  years,  so  that  a  man  who  elects 
to  hold  continuously,  knows  for  certain  that,  during  that 
long  period,  all  the  profit  he  can  make  will  go  to  him. 

At  the  beginning  of  each  year,  he  can  signify  to  the 
mamlatdar  (or  local  revenue  officer  of  a  taluka  subdivision) 
what  fields  he  wishes  to  hold  and  what  he  wishes  to  give 
up :  as  long  as  he  does  this  in  proper  time,  he  is  free  to  do 
as  he  pleases.  If  he  relinquishes,  the  fields  are  available 
for  any  one  else ;  if  no  one  applies  for  them,  they  are 
usually  auctioned  as  fallow  (for  the  right  of  grazing)  for 
the  year,  and  so  on,  till  some  one  offers  to  take  them  up  for 
cultivation.  Nothing  whatever  is  said  in  the  Revenue 
Code  about  the  person  in  possession  (on  his  own  account) 
being  '  owner '  in  the  Western  sense.  He  is  simply  called 
the  '  occupant,'  and  the  Code  says  what  he  can  do  and  what 
he  cannot 1.  The  occupant  may  do  anything  he  pleases  to 
improve  the  land,  but  may  not  without  permission  do  any- 

1  The  '  right  of  occupancy  ' — the  saying  that  the  occupant  is  the  pro- 

right  to  be  an  occupant — is  itself  de-  prietor  of  the  soil.     In  the  official 

clared  to  be  a  transferable  and  herit-  language    of    the   Presidency,   the 

able  property  (Code,  section  73)  ;  but  occupant   is  said  to  hold  on  '  the 

that  is  quite  a  different  thing  from  survey  tenure.' 

VOL.  I.  Y 


322  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

thing  which  diverts  the  holding  from  agricultural  purposes. 
He  has  no  right  to  mines  or  minerals. 

These  are  the  facts  of  the  tenure ;  you  may  theorize  on 
them  as  you  please  ;  you  may  say  this  amounts  to  pro- 
prietorship, or  this  is  a  'dominium  minus  plenum';  or 
anything  else. 

The  question  of  tenancy  is  just  as  simply  dealt  with.  I 
have  stated  that  if  it  appears  that  the  occupant  is  in  posses- 
sion in  behalf  of  some  one  else,  that  some  one  else  is  recorded 
as  the  'superior  holder,'  and  he  becomes  the  'inferior 
holder.'  What  sort  of  '  inferior ' — whether  a  tenant  or  on 
some  other  terms — is  a  simple  question  of  fact  and  of  the 
agreement  or  the  custom  by  which  he  holds  1. 

If  an  occupant  dies,  one  (the  eldest  or  managing)  heir 
must  be  entered  as  the  succeeding  occupant  who  has  to  pay 
the  revenue  ;  for  there  can  only  be  one  registered  revenue- 
payer  for  each  field  or  recognized  share  of  a  field  with 
a  separate  survey  number ;  though  of  course  there  may  be 
several  sharers  (joint-heirs  of  the  deceased  owner,  for  in- 
stance) in  it.  Which  of  them  is  so  entered  depends  on  the 
agreement  of  the  members  of  the  family,  or  on  the  result 
of  a  Court  decree,  if  there  is  a  dispute.  Sharers  can  always 
get  their  shares  partitioned,  recorded,  and  severally  assessed, 
as  long  as  there  is  no  dispute  as  to  what  the  shares  are. 

I  should  here  add  that  BERAK  was  settled  on  the  Bombay 
system. 


§  34.    The  Revenue-Systems  of  other  Provinces. 

The  retrospect  just  brought  to  a  close  embraces  all  the 
older,  and  most  of  the  larger,  provinces  of  India.  The 
others  that  have  special  systems  really  need  but  little  pre- 


1  There  is  also  no  artificial  tenant  there  may  be  a  superior  holder 
right.  In  Bombay,  as  in  all  other  drawing  a  revenue  from  the  estate : 
provinces,  there  are  jagir  and  other  there  the  actual  occupants  are  sub- 
'  mam' holdings  which  are  revenue-  occupants,  not  tenants,  as  they  do 
free,  or  only  lightly  assessed,  and  not  hold  in  consequence  of  any  con- 
occasionally  other  tenures  in  which  tract  with  the  superior. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  323 

fatory  comment.  ASSAM,  of  which  a  small  portion  only  had 
been  permanently  settled,  when  it  formed  part  of  Bengal ; 
the  little  province  of  COORG,  and  the  great  and  growing 
province  of  BUEMA,  are  all  of  them  managed  under  local 
systems  of  Land-Revenue  Settlement  which  have  this  great 
advantage; — they  are  free  of  all  theories  and  artificial 
creations,  with  all  that  has  elsewhere  necessarily  followed 
from  such  creations.  They  are  (in  this  manual),  therefore, 
classed  as  varieties  of  the  RAIYATWARI  system. 

But  they  have  little  or  nothing  in  common  with  the  sys- 
tems of  Bombay  and  Madras,  except  this  one  thing,  that 
there  is  no  middleman — landlord,  or  overlord,  or  ideal  cor- 
porate body — between  the  actual  soil-occupant  and  the 
State. 

In  the  map,  which  indicates  by  different  colours  the  area 
which  each  Settlement  system  I  have  been  reviewing  occu- 
pies, I  have  ventured  to  give  the  same  tint  to  Madras  and 
Bombay  and  Berar,  because  the  systems  differ  only  in  de- 
tail ;  but  I  have  given  a  different  tint  to  Assam  and  Burma, 
though  I  have  endeavoured  to  indicate  their  connection 
with  the  raiyatwari  system  by  making  it  a  different  shade 
or  tint  of  the  same  colour. 


SECTION  IX. — THE  MACHINERY  OF  BRITISH  LAND- 
REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION. 

§  i.    Modern  organization  of  Territory. 

Perhaps  I  ought  next  to  devote  some  space  to  describing 
how  the  various  British  revenue  systems  are  worked ;  how 
the  records  are  preserved  ;  how  the  land-revenue  is  col- 
lected ;  how  questions  of  revenue-law  and  matters  of 
executive  management  are  disposed  of  under  each  system, 
and  in  each  province.  But,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  each 
province  must,  in  the  sequel,  have  a  separate  chapter  on 
this  subject,  and  it  would  be  of  little  use  to  present  a  series 
of  provincial  abstracts  in  this  place.  Some  of  the  most 

Y  2 


324  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH  INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

essential  matters  of  management  must  also  be  further 
discussed  in  another  connection  in  the  remaining  sections 
of  this  chapter.  I  will  therefore  here  offer  only  a  brief 
outline  of  what,  with  some  slight  modifications,  is  the 
general  framework  or  basis  of  constitution  COMMON  TO  ALL 
PEOVINCES,  as  regards  their  land-revenue  administration. 

In  all  provinces  the  district  is  the  starting-point.  The 
Magistrate  and  Collector,  as  he  is  called  in  the  Regulation 
Districts,  and  Deputy  Commissioner,  as  he  is  called  in  the 
rest,  is  the  head  of  the  district :  and  he  is  supported  by 
Assistants  and  Deputies,  who  are  either  general  assistants 
or  are  in  charge  of  subdivisions  of  the  district,  in  which 
such  assistants  are  practically  chiefs,  only  acting  under  the 
general  control  of  the  district  head. 

Of  the  multifarious  duties  of  the  District  Officers  I  am 
not  here  going  to  speak  ;  they  are  described  elsewhere  1. 

In  all  provinces  but  Madras2,  a  varying  number  of 
districts  forms  a  division,  which  is  presided  over  by  a 
'  Commissioner.'  The  duties  of  this  officer  are  those  of 
inspection  and  general  control  in  the  districts  ;  to  hear 
appeals  in  any  case  from  district  orders ;  and  to  be  the 
channel  of  communication  between  the  district  and  the 
higher  revenue  authorities  and  the  Government. 

At  the  head  of  the  revenue-administration  in  Bengal, 
Madras,  and  the  North- West  Provinces,  is  a  Board  of 
Revenue ;  in  the  Panjab  there  are  two  Financial  Com- 
missioners with  Secretaries,  who  in  fact,  though  not  in 
name,  form  a  Board.  In  Burma  there  is  a  Financial 
Commissioner  instead  of  a  Board.  In  the  Central  Provinces, 
Oudh  and  Assam,  the  Chief  Commissioner  is  himself  the 
chief  revenue  authority. 

Under  the  district  there  are  now,  in  all  provinces,  small 
local  subdivisons,  which  are  to  our  administration,  what 

1  See,  for  instance,   the   Bengal  directly  with  the  Board  of  Revenue, 
chapter  on  Revenue  Officers  ;  and  which  (as  reorganized  in  1886)  con- 
especially  see  Sir  John  Strachey's  sists  of  '  Commissioners '  for  several 
India,  Lect.  X,  and  p.  263  et  seq.  departments  of  duty  who  are  aggre- 

2  In  Madras,  the  Collectorates  or  gated  in  the  Board  instead  of  pre- 
Districts  are   larger  and   are   sub-  siding  over  local  areas  of  territory, 
divided ;  the  Collector  corresponds 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE  VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  325 

the  pargana  was  to  the  Mughal  system.  But  they  are,  for 
convenience,  usually  made  larger  than  the  old  pargana 
or  taluka,  and  sometimes  consist  of  several  such  areas 
combined. 

In  Bengal  for  a  long  time,  as  there  were  only  a  certain 
number  of  district  Zamindars  to  deal  with,  local  centres 
of  revenue-management  and  collection  were  not  thought 
of;  but  of  late  years,  as  the  estates  subdivided,  Govern- 
ment estates  became  more  numerous  and  business  generally 
increased,  a  system  of  subdivisions  of  districts  has  been 
adopted,  and  these  subdivisions  are  usually  under  Sub- 
Deputy  Collectors,  and  are,  in  fact,  very  much  like 
the  tahsil  subdivisions  of  .  other  provinces  to  be  next 
mentioned. 

In  all  Northern  and  Central  India,  the  district  (which, 
if  large,  may  have  one  or  more  primary  subdivisions)  is 
always  subdivided  into  'tahsils/  which  are  groups  usually 
consisting  of  several  parganas  of  the  older  system.  The 
head  (native)  official  who  receives  revenue  at  his  local 
or  tahsil  treasury,  is  called  a  Tahsildar.  This  term  is  in 
use  in  certain  districts  of  Assam,  all  over  the  North- West 
Provinces,  Oudh,  the  Central  Provinces,  the  Panjab,  and 
in  Madras.  In  Bengal,  the  Tahsildar  is  only  known  as 
a  minor  official  in  certain  special  cases,  as  in  Government 
estates,  or  where  there  are  numerous  small  holdings. 
The  Tahsildar  is  usually  assisted  by  a  Naib  or  Deputy 
Tahsildar. 

In  Burma  there  is  a  somewhat  similar  system,  of  course 
under  Burmese  nomenclature. 

In  Bombay  the  same  system  obtains,  except  that  the 
local  areas  are  called  '  talukas,'  retained,  I  believe,  without 
aggregation  from  the  older  system.  The  officers  in  charge 
are  called  'mamlatdar'  aided  by  subordinates  called 
'  karkun.'  In  Madras,  the  Mughal  administration  was  not 
sufficiently  generally  established  to  make  its  divisions  well 
known.  The  district  subdivision  is  the  '  taluk/  and  the 
native  officer  is  (as  stated)  the  Tahsildar. 

The   object  of  this  universal  local   subdivision,  in  its 


326  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

slightly  varying  forms,  is  the  same.  The  local  officer — 
vested  with  small  criminal,  and  sometimes  with  civil-court 
powers — has  to  receive  the  revenues  of  the  local  area,  to 
keep  a  close  watch  over  the  agricultural  and  social  con- 
dition of  the  sub-district,  and  to  see  the  village  officials 
are  doing  their  duty.  For  this  purpose  the  Tahsildar 
(or  whatever  he  may  be  called)  has  not  only  an  office  and 
treasury  establishment,  but  also  a  stafi  of  kanungos  (or 
Revenue  Inspectors),  one  of  whom  usually  remains  at  the 
tahsil  headquarters  to  compile  statistics  and  see  to  the 
despatch  of  the  proper  returns  to  the  district  headquarters, 
while  the  others  constantly  move  about,  check  the  work  of 
the  village  patwaris,  and  see  that  they  do  their  duty  in 
keeping  a  record  of  all  changes  in  the  maps,  and  in  the 
proprietary  interests  as  they  occur  by  inheritance,  gift 
and  sale  (and  to  some  extent  by  mortgage),  as  well  as  in 
keeping  the  statistics  of  crops  sown,  and  other  matters 
which  local  rules  require. 

The  Agriculture  and  Land  Record  Department  aids  the 
district  officer,  especially  in  seeing  that  this  important  duty 
is  carefully  and  punctually  fulfilled,  as  it  is  on  the  proper 
performance  of  it  that  several  important  features  of  district 
administration  depend. 

Some  of  these  duties  of  the  local  establishments  are  of 
modern  introduction  ;  they  may  be  reckoned  as  among 
the  results  of  the  Famine  Commission  of  1879,  but  success 
is  already  beginning  to  be  attained.  And  in  the  North - 
West  Provinces,  where  the  system  has  been  longest  in 
operation,  the  improvement  in  the  records  and  statistics 
has  already  been  very  considerable.  Indeed,  though  we 
have  not  yet  arrived  at  the  wished-for  ideal  of  revisions 
of  Settlement  being  carried  out  by  the  district  staff  abso- 
lutely without  extraneous  aid,  a  step  in  that  direction 
has  been  taken.  The  cost  of  the  latest  revisions  will 
hardly  be  one-third  of  what  it  used  to  be ;  and  both  the 
labour  involved  and  the  duration  of  the  work  will  be 
greatly  curtailed. 

As  far  as  the  general  working  of  the  system  is  concerned, 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  327 

— the  collection  of  the  revenue,  and  other  branches  of 
general  duty, — it  is  a  matter  of  fact,  for  years  past,  that 
these  local  agencies  have  worked  well.  Sales  of  estates 
for  revenue-arrears  are  now  rare,  and  coercive  processes 
seriously  carried  out  are  also  rare.  In  most  cases  the  issue 
of  notices  ('  dastak ')  or  very  temporary  detentions  at  the 
tahsil,  are  quite  sufficient. 

§  2.    Other  branches  of  the  Revenue  Officer's  duty. 

I  have  purposely  avoided  mentioning  other  branches  of 
work  for  the  district  staff;  many,  such  as  Excise,  Stamps, 
and  Registration  of  Assurances,  are  foreign  altogether  to 
my  purpose.  But  even  those  directly  and  indirectly  con- 
nected with  land-revenue  can  only  be  enumerated.  These 
are  first,  the  disposal  of  matters  connected  with  the  collec- 
tion, recovery  of  arrears,  and  the  suspension  and  remission 
of  land-revenue  ;  next,  questions  of  boundary,  and  those 
matters  of  land-revenue  law  which  require  to  be  dealt  with 
by  revenue-officers.  In  some  provinces  cases  between  land- 
lord and  tenant  as  to  enhancement,  ejectment,  improve- 
ments, and  the  like,  are  heard  by  Revenue  Courts.  In 
all  provinces,  the  registration  of  transfers  of  proprietary 
interests  ;  the  making  of  partitions  of  estates  ;  the  manage- 
ment of  estates  of  which  Settlement  has  been  declined, 
or  which  are  under  direct  management  by  reason  of 
default  in  revenue  payments ;  the  management  of  estates 
of  minors  and  others  under  the  Court  of  Wards  ;  the  special 
Settlement  of  alluvial  areas,  or  measures  taken  for  re- 
duction by  reason  of  diluvion ;  assessment  of  revenue-free 
areas  when  the  estate  lapses,  or  the  assignment  for  life 
or  lives  falls  in ;  acquisition  of  land  for  public  purposes  ; 
making  loans  for  agricultural  improvements,  and  to  aid 
cultivators  for  general  agricultural  purposes  ; — these  are  all 
matters  of  a  Land-Revenue  officer's  duty.  There  may  be  also 
work  in  connection  with  the  law  under  which  certain  cesses 
are  levied  for  roads  and  schools  and  to  meet  the  costs  of 
famine  relief,  and  in  Bengal  in  connection  with  embank- 


328  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

ments a  and  special  surveys.  The  Land-Revenue  Administra- 
tion has  also  to  watch  the  effect  of  the  Settlements,  whether 
the  assessments  work  well  or  bear  hardly,  and  to  take 
note  of  the  condition  of  the  people,  as  evidenced  by  the 
frequency  of  mortgages  and  sales  of  land,  and  to  study  the 
general  question  of  indebtedness  of  the  agricultural 
classes.  Irrigation  questions  and  appeals  regarding  rights 
of  water,  and  right  of  taking  water- channels  across  land, 
also  occupy  no  little  time  in  canal  districts ;  while  (in  the 
Panjab,  for  example)  schemes  for  the  construction  of  canals 
in  districts  where  the  soil  is  good,  but  the  rainfall  is  so 
scanty  that  canal  irrigation  is  the  only  condition  under 
which  husbandry  is  possible,  have  led,  of  late  years,  to 
questions  of  colonization  on  an  extensive  scale,  and  of  the 
location  of  villages  under  appropriate  rules.  Lastly,  in 
certain  districts,  the  results  of  local  mistakes  in  Settle- 
ments of  past  years,  or  of  the  improvidence  of  certain 
classes,  or  both  combined,  may  have  also  left  us  a  legacy 
of  duty  in  securing  relief  from  hopeless  debt,  in  the  shape 
of  several  '  Encumbered  Estates  Acts,'  or  'Raiyats'  Relief 
Acts. 

The  mere  enumeration  of  these  matters  will  show  how 
the  land-revenue  administration  of  an  Indian  district  is  in 
fact  the  central  part  of  Government,  and  how  it  comes  into 
contact  with  almost  every  other  branch  of  administration 
which  can  be  named. 


SECTION  X. — RESUME  OF  THE  PRINCIPLES  OP  LAND- 
REVENUE  ASSESSMENTS. 

§  i.    Objects  of  Settlement. 

The  duty  of  making  or  revising  assessments  of  land- 
revenue  is  a  separate  branch  ;  it  may  be  undertaken  by  the 
Collector,  and  will  be  more  frequently  so  in  the  future ;  but 

1  Embankments,  i.e.  by  which  local  authorities  from  ancient  times, 
floods  are  kept  out  of  culturable  is  of  great  importance  in  many 
lands.  This  work,  always  laid  on  parts  of  Bengal  proper. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  329 

hitherto,  a  special  Settlement  officer  (or  Settlement  Col- 
lector) aided  by  a  special  staff,  has  been  employed.  The 
object  of  a  Settlement,  I  may  repeat,  is, — (i)  to  assess  the 
Land-Revenue  ;  (2)  to  furnish  the  officer  responsible  for  its 
collection  with  a  correct  list  of  the  persons  by  whom  it  is 
payable ;  (3)  to  give  those  persons  a  secure  title,  and  at  the 
same  time  to  secure  the  rights  of  those  who  hold  on  shares 
with  them,  or  those  who  hold  under  them. 

At  the  risk  of  some  repetition,  I  shall  here  briefly  resume 
the  general  principles  of  assessment  as  they  are  developed 
in  the  several  provinces. 

It  will  be  observed  that,  while  the  modern  land-revenue 
assessments  trace  back  their  origin  to  the  old  principle  of 
the  Raja's  share  in  the  produce,  and  derive  their  authority 
from  that  ancient  custom,  the  actual  levy  of  a  share,  or 
anything  representing  it,  has  long  since  been  abandoned ; 
the  old  theory  and  the  actual  practice  have  been  sundered 
widely  apart  by  the  changing  circumstances,  both  of 
different  provinces  and  different  eras  of  history. 

If  all  land-tenures  had  remained  unaltered,  or  had  pre- 
sented uniformly  the  features,  say,  of  an  ordinary  Madras 
village,  where  each  cultivator  deals  direct  with  the  State 
officers,  responsible  for  no  one  but  himself  and  for  the  crop 
his  own  labour  has  raised,  then  no  doubt  the  revenue 
might  long  have  remained,  in  true  theory,  a  share  of  the 
produce  valued  in  money.  And,  indeed,  in  Madras  the 
land -re  venue  is  still  professedly  in  theory,  and  to  some 
extent  in  practice,  based  on  the  value  of  a  share  in  the  net 
produce  of  land.  (See  Sect.  vii.  p.  296.) 

In  Bombay,  though  in  principle  the  same  direct  dealing 
with  the  cultivator  is  adopted,  the  plan  has  been,  ever  since 
1847,  frankly  to  abandon  the  practice  of  produce-calculation. 
At  the  same  time,  the  conditions  of  land-holding  do  not 
afford  any  possibility  of  finding  out  a  rental  value.  In 
Bombay  there  is  the  usual  preliminary  division  of  villages 
into  similarly  situated  groups.  For  each  group  certain 
maximum,  or  full,  or  standard,  cash  rates  per  acre  of  certain 
determinate  kinds  of  soil,  are  worked  out.  The  rates  are 


330  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

based  on  a  number  of  practical  and  general  considerations, 
reference  being  had  to  what  has  been  paid  in  the  past, 
to  the  present  increase  in  cultivation,  general  prosperity 
and  rise  in  prices  of  produce:  such  full  rates  being  made 
to  vary  in  each  group  with  reference  to  the  relative 
advantages  of  each.  But,  before  applying  these  full  or 
standard  rates  (for  each  group),  every  field  is  classified  by  a 
skilful  and  practised  staff,  and  valued  relatively,  according  to 
its  kind,  and  according  to  various  circumstances  which  add 
to  or  diminish  its  value  individually.  The  result  is  that  the 
value  of  each  field  is  nicely  graduated  on  a  scale  extending 
from  a  minimum  up  to  the  full  rate :  the  scale  is  expressed 
in  '  annas '  or  fractions  according  to  the  common  practice. 
Supposing,  then,  the  'full  rate,'  applicable  to  the  group, 
is,  for  a  given  soil,  as  above,  R-3  :  then  a  field  belonging 
to  such  order  of  soil,  and  of  such  depth,  and  so  free  from 
accidental  defects  that  it  ranks  as  '  16  annas,'  its  rate  will  be 
R.  3 ;  but  should  the  soil  be  of  less  depth,  or  of  an  inferior 
grade,  and  subject  to  defects,  then  it  may  only  rank  as 
'  4  annas,'  and  therefore  pay  only  one-fourth  of  the  R.  3. 
That  is  the  plan  of  valuing  land  as  land  watered  only 
by  the  rain  of  heaven.  If  in  such  land  there  is  irrigation 
from  a  tank  or  by  'lift'  from  a  river,  or  by  well,  such 
irrigation-advantages  may  be  taken  into  account  by  rates 
charged  in  excess  of  the  '  dry -rate ' ;  if  it  is  '  garden '  land, — 
i.e.  brought  by  long  culture,  manure,  and  watering,  up  to 
a  high  standard, — it  will  pay  rates  of  its  own;  and  so 
if  it  is  permanent  '  wet '  or  rice  land. 

In  the  Temporarily  Settled  provinces,  where  the  whole 
village  is  dealt  with  as  the  unit,  the  assessment  is  in  one 
sum,  which  is,  however,  distributed  among  the  co- sharers 
according  to  their  constitution ;  so  that  the  separate  pay- 
ments are  just  as  well  known  as  under  the  raiyatwari 
system. 

The  first  Settlements  date  from  a  time  when  the  '  aggregate 
to  detail'  method  of  assessment  in  use  in  the  North -West 
Provinces,  and  advocated  in  Thomason  s  well-known  Direc- 
tions to  Settlement  Officers  was  the  common  one.  In  practice, 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  331 

a  lump  sum  was  estimated  for  the  '  pargana,'  or  a  circle  of 
similarly-situated  villages  (assessment-circle),  and  then  this 
sum  was  divided  so  as  to  give  the  amount  for  each  village. 
There  were  three  real  grounds  for  fixing  this  sum — -first,  the 
knowledge  of  what  sums  had  been  paid  in  the  past  (with  the 
additional  fact  that  they  had  been  paid  with  ease  or  the 
reverse) ;  secondly,  the  rise  in  general  prices,  population, 
increase  of  advantages  in  the  matter  of  wells,  roads  to 
market,  &c.  These  considerations  suggested  that  the  total 
might  be  increased,  or  maintained  as  it  was,  or  possibly 
diminished.  Thirdly,  there  was  the  general  sense  of  a  locally 
experienced  officer  that  such  a  sum  would  be  fair,  the  esti- 
mate having  been  arrived  at  after  careful  inspection,  inquiry 
among  the  people,  and  consultation  with  experienced  native 
subordinates.  These  grounds,  however,  had  to  be  more 
elaborately  justified  in  the  Assessment  Reports,  in  which 
various  rate  calculations  were  set  out,  tending  to  check 
and  to  illustrate  or  justify  the  general  totals  proposed. 

The  proposed  village  totals  would  then  be  worked  back- 
wards into  the  form  of  rates  on  the  acre  of  each  different 
kind  of  soil  (according  to  a  fixed  classification),  and  the 
rates  would  be  justified  by  comparing  them  with  rates 
got  out  by  estimating  produce,  and  valuing  one-sixth1 
of  the  gross  produce  at  average  prices,  by  calculating 
a  fair  rate  on  the  number  of  ploughs  in  the  village,  and 
so  forth.  Under  this  method,  the  revenue  was  not  abso- 
lutely divorced  from  the  old  idea  of  a  share  of  the  produce, 
and  it  is  confidently  believed  (in  the  Panjab,  for  example) 
that  our  land-revenue  can  be  stated  to  represent  not  more 
than  the  traditional  sixth  at  the  outside,  probably  in  many 
cases  not  more  than  a  tenth  or  twelfth,  of  the  gross 
produce. 

1  One-sixth,  because  it  was  roughly  lord's  share  :  so  that  the  Govern- 

estimated,  that  of  the  total  produce  ment  revenue  share  was  fifty  per 

two-thirds    represented    the    cul-  cent,  or  one-half  of  the  latter, 
tivator's  and   one-third  the  land- 


332  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH  INDIA.       [CHAP.  v. 

§  2.    Later  Methods  of  Assessment. 

But  in  the  North  -West  Provinces,  Oudh,  and  the  Central 
Provinces,  a  totally  new  element  had  gradually  been 
introduced.  In  these  provinces  the  landlord  classes  were 
largely  non-agriculturist,  and  in  consequence  the  land 
was  mostly  cultivated  by  tenants,  and  the  rents  thus 
realized  from  the  land  came  to  be  more  and  more  com- 
monly paid  in  cash.  At  the  present  day  the  cases  where 
grain-rents  are  paid  are  insignificant  (and  the  means 
of  ascertaining  a  cash-rate  by  comparison  are  easy) ;  so 
that  the  system  is  not  altered  by  such  exceptional  cases. 

The  growth  of  tenant-cultivation  and  the  use  of  cash- 
rents  were  very  important  changes  in  the  constitution  of 
agricultural  society.  And  gradually  they  affected  assess- 
ment principles.  In  fact  we  may  reckon  four  stages  of 
assessment  rule  development.  The  first  was  marked  by 
the  attempt  to  value  produce,  which  I  have  alluded  to 
as  characteristic  of  the  early  working  of  Regulation  VII  of 
1822 ;  it  was,  in  fact,  a  clinging  to  the  idea  of  finding  out 
a  proper  share  of  the  produce  and  valuing  it  in  money.  The 
year  1833  marks  the  second  period,  when  the  produce 
idea  was  given  up,  and  an  attempt  was  made  to  obtain 
a  direct  cash  valuation  of  the  estates,  with  more  or  less 
reference  to  the  rental  value.  This  was  the  old  '  aggregate 
to  detail '  method,  and  consisted  in  roughly  calculating  out 
a  gross  rental  of  the  estate,  and  taking  two-thirds  of  it  as 
the  revenue. 

The  third  period  is  marked  by  a  great  improve- 
ment in  the  method  of  classifying  soils,  and  in  an 
attempt  to  fix  more  scientifically  the  rent-paying  capacity 
of  each  class.  This  I  may  call  the  stage  of  scientifically 
estimating  what  rent  ought  to  be,  and  taking  a  share 
— reduced  to  fifty  per  cent. — of  the  ideal '  rental.' * 

1  I  quote  the  following  from  an  paid  were,  in  theory  at  least,  dis- 
able article  in  the  Pioneer  (June  ai,  regarded.  The  main  feature  of  the 
1884).  Speaking  of  the '  ideal '  rent  Settlement .  .  .  was  that  the  process 
system,  the  author  says  : —  employed  in  the  preceding  Settle- 

'  The    individual   rents    actually  ment  was  exactly  reversed.     Rent 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  333 

The  fourth  and  last  stage  I  shall  speak  of  when  I  come 
to  mention  the  latest  policy  of  the  Imperial  Government 
regarding  future  revisions  of  Settlement, — viz.  those  now  in 
progress,  or,  speaking  generally,  since  1881.  It  will  be 
sufficient  here  to  state  briefly  that  it  abandoned  the  ideal 
rent  for  the  natural  or  actual  rent. 

The  abandonment  of  the  elaborate  method  which  is 
associated  with  the  honoured  names  of  C.  A.  Elliott  and 
other  eminent  Settlement  Officers  of  the  last  North -West 
Provinces  Settlement,  does  not  imply  any  disparagement 
of  the  skill  and  ability  of  its  authors, 

'  It  is  owing '  (writes  Mr.  Fuller,  himself  the  author  of  an 
improved  method  of  assessment  in  the  Central  Provinces)  '  to 
their  (the  Settlement  officers')  labours  and  to  their  ability  that 
assessments  were  made  which  were  an  immense  improvement 
on  what  preceded,  and  under  which  the  country  has  generally 
prospered.  But  the  circumstances  on  which  the  value  of  land 
depends  are  so  numerous,  so  diverse,  and  often  so  occult,  that, 
however  great  be  the  talents  or  energy  of  the  Settlement  officer, 
it  is  impossible  that  he  should  not  occasionally  slip  into  error : 
and  a  single  error  on  a  point  of  detail  may  vitiate  a  whole 
assessment.  It  is  notorious  that  past  assessments  have  from 
the  outset  pressed  unequally  on  the  people.  No  sooner  has 
a  Settlement  been  completed  than  it  has  become  a  matter  of 
common  report  that  such  and  such  a  village  has  fared  badly, 
whilst  others  have  got  off  very  lightly — the  all-sufficient  ex- 
planation to  native  minds  lying  in  the  temper  of  the  Settlement 
officer  (MMm  ki  mimj}-" 

rates  were  based  on  the  actual  rents  the   atrophied  relics   of  a  disused 

found  to  be  paid  by  cultivators  in  theory.     Each  then  of  these  three 

the  neighbourhood,  and  were  then  Settlements   rested   on   a  different 

applied  to  the  lands  of  each  village,  basis, — the    first    on    the    produce 

which  had  been  minutely  classified,  and  its  value  ;  the  second  on  gross 

so  as  to  correspond  with  the  various  rents  assumed  for  large  areas  ;  the 

rates  of  rent  which  were,  or  were  last  on  special  rents  paid  for  indi- 

supposed  to  be,  paid  for  each  kind  vidual  fields  ;  and  each  successive 

of  soil.  Crop  rates  were  still  worked  stage  was  an  approximation  to  the 

out  on  calculations  of  the  gross  pro-  true   theory  of   our   present  land- 

duce  and  its  value,  but  they  were  revenue,   namely,   that   instead   of 

not  professed  to  be  used  except  as  dealing  with  the  cultivator  we  deal 

checks  on  the  rates  based  on  actual  with  the  proprietor,  and  instead  of 

rents,  and  in  fact  they  were  hardly  taking  a  share  of  the  produce  we 

used   at    all.     They    were    merely  take  a  share  of  a  natural  rent.' 


334  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

§  3.    The  latest  system  of  Assessment. 

The  North- West  Provinces  districts  that  are  now  being 
settled  have,  of  course,  been  settled  several  times  before. 
Therefore,  in  most  of  them  very  little  in  the  way  of 
re-survey  or  record  of  rights  is  required.  But  the  revision 
of  the  assessment  is  now  conducted  solely  on  the  basis  of 
the  rents  actually  paid.  The  account  has,  of  course,  still 
to  be  completed,  by  applying  rent  rates  to  the  proprietors' 
sir  lands  (with  an  allowance  of  from  ten  to  fifteen  per  cent, 
below  full  tenant  rates) ;  by  applying  rents  to  lands  held  at 
favourable  rates,  or  at  no  rent  at  all ;  and  by  correcting  any 
manifest  defects  or  errors  in  the  rent-roll. 

Provision  is  also  made  for  cases  where  the  recorded 
rent-rolls  fraudulently  misrepresent  facts,  or  are  otherwise 
inaccurate  or  unreliable. 

In  short,  though  the  assets  are  now  to  depend  on  the 
actual  rental,  irrespective  of  allowance  for  extension  of 
cultivation,  or  anticipated  enhancements,  still  it  is  to  be  an 
actual  rental,  not  one  which  represents  imaginary  rents, 
below  what  are  paid,  or  excludes  land  from  the  account 
without  showing  any  rent  at  all. 

In  the  Panjdb,  the  latest  method  of  assessment  still 
remains  different  from  this.  We  cannot  make  use  of 
rentals  of  the  estates,  because  the  bulk  of  the  land  is  not 
rented, — and  what  is  rented  pays  '  batdi,'  or  rent  in  grain. 
At  the  same  time,  the  old  plan  of  assessing  the  aggregate 
revenue  first,  and  then  distributing  it,  and  the  subsequent 
practice  of  relying  on  the  valuation  of  one-sixth  of  the 
produce,  is  completely  given  up.  The  assessing  officer  has 
therefore  to  determine  for  each  class  of  soil,  in  each  assess- 
ment circle,  rates  per  acre,  which  are  direct  revenue  rates. 

These  have  to  be  sanctioned  before  being  made  use  of  in 
actual  assessment,  and  when  so  made  use  of  can  be  modi- 
fied to  meet  peculiar  requirements  of  individual  estates, — 
requirements,  that  is,  of  a  special  character,  and  not  already 
provided  for  by  the  grouping  into  circles  for  assessment 
purposes. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-RE\7ENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  335 

There  is  still  no  method  of  finding  out  the  rates  which 
dispenses  with  personal  opinion  and  sense  of  fitness  ;  but 
the  rates  that  are  proposed  can  start  with  the  basis  that 
there  are  existing  rates,  and  primd  facie  these  are  to  be 
raised  (or  it  may  be  lowered)  on  a  consideration  of  the 
history  of  the  circle  and  its  prevalent  prices  since  the  last 
Settlement. 

Then  again,  rates  that  first  suggest  themselves  are  tested 
by  a  variety  of  calculations ;  and  it  is  worthy  of  remark 
that  the  rules  of  1888  now  distinctly  direct  that  as  a 
test  of  rates,  an  average  tenant  holding  in  each  soil-class 
should  be  selected,  and  the  rent,  if  it  is  in  cash,  accurately 
ascertained  ;  or,  if  it  is  paid  in  grain,  then  the  grain  is  to  be 
valued  in  money  at  a  fair  average  price.  On  this  basis 
estimates  of  the  landlord's  share,  or  produce  rent  (and  the 
Government  half)  per  acre,  are  drawn  up  for  each  of  the 
different  soil-classes.  This  shows  that  circumstances  are 
beginning  to  admit  of  tenants'  rents  being  made  more  use  of, 
in  calculation ;  and  it  is  also  to  be  pointed  out  that  such 
estimates  have  one  great  value — they  afford  a  good  idea  of 
the  relative  value  of  different  soils  or  different  modes  of 
cultivation. 

But  perhaps  the  most  interesting  development  is  that  of 
the  assessment  method  devised  for  the  Government  Settle- 
ments in  the  Central  Provinces. 

It  may  be  observed,  that  in  the  North- West  Provinces, 
though  the  Settlement  officer  calculates  tenants'  rents  in 
order  to  obtain  his  valuation  of  estates,  in  theory  he  had 
nothing  to  do  with  fixing  rates  that  the  tenants  were 
actually  bound  to  pay.  That  was  supposed  to  be  done  by 
the  consent  of  the  parties,  and  by  recourse  to  the  Rent 
Courts  under  the  Tenant  Law.  As  a  matter  of  fact  how- 
ever, the  Settlement  officers  did  do  a  very  great  deal, 
though  informally,  to  help  the  people  to  a  settlement  of  the 
rents  consequent  on  the  new  assessment.  But  in  the  Central 
Provinces  the  law  has  so  limited  the  rights  of  the  pro- 
prietors of  villages  as  regards  the  old  tenants,  that  it  also 
was  necessary  by  law  to  provide  that  the  Settlement 


336  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

officers  should  formally  and  legally  determine  fair  rents. 
Hence  it  was  desirable  to  strike  out  a  method  which  should 
fix  tenants'  rents  equably,  and  at  the  same  time  enable  the 
Government  share  of  the  rental-assets  to  be  assessed  with- 
out further  trouble. 

Unfortunately  it  has  been  the  great  difficulty  of  all 
Settlement  calculations,  that  rates,  however  carefully  tested, 
will  fall  unequally.  The  surveyor  and  classifier  can  take 
note  of  palpable  differences  of  situation,  and  distinct  kinds 
and  varieties  of  soil ;  but  besides  these,  there  are  a  hundred 
other  circumstances  which  affect  value,  some  of  which  defy 
explanation.  It  was  desired  to  see  whether  some  steps 
could  not  be  taken  to  compare  the  rents  paid  in  one 
village  with  those  paid  in  another,  so  that  there  could  not 
only  be  a  positive  increase  (or  decrease)  where  needed,  but 
also  an  equalization  of  one  estate  with  another. 

Mr.  Fuller,  B.C.S.,  who  had  been  assistant  to  Sir  E. 
Buck  in  the  North -West  Provinces,  was  appointed  to 
direct  the  new  Settlements  in  the  Central  Provinces,  and 
he  devised  a  system  which  is  working  very  well.  This 
system  is  described  in  detail  in  the  proper  chapter  of  the 
sequel ;  here  I  can  only  generally  indicate  its  principle. 

The  actual  rents  paid  in  different  villages  on  different 
classes  of  soil  are  first  carefully  ascertained  ;  and,  so  far,  it 
can  at  once  be  seen  (individually)  whether  they  are  too 
low  or  too  high  ;  and  if  too  low,  up  to  what  they  can  fairly 
be  enhanced.  For  we  can  compare  the  rates  within  the 
village,  with  what,  under  the  circumstances,  they  might  be 
expected  to  be.  For  instance  :  the  present  rental  is  found 
to  be  only  very  slightly  in  excess  of  what  it  was  at  the 
beginning  of  the  expiring  Settlement:  yet  during  the 
period,  cultivation  has  extended  aoo  per  cent.,  and  prices 
(suppose)  have  doubled ;  here,  unless  there  are  special 
reasons,  the  rental  may  be  considerably  raised.  But  this 
does  not  enable  us  to  compare  the  rents  of  one  village  with 
those  of  another ;  in  order  to  do  this,  the  soils  of  both  must 
be  reduced  to  a  '  common  denominator';  for  we  could  not 
compare  the  results  (taking  an  all-round  rate  per  acre) 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  337 

unless  the  villages  were  alike  in  classes  of  soil,  and  in  the 
proportion  of  each  class  of  soil  in  each  village  area,  which, 
of  course,  is  rarely  or  never  the  case.  But  if  we  can 
ascertain  that  one  class  of  land  stands,  as  regards  its  pro- 
ductiveness, in  a  certain  relation  to  another,  then  we  can 
reduce  the  area  of  a  village  to  a  number  of  '  soil-units  '  of 
equal  value.  Suppose,  for  instance,  a  village  A  consists  of 
1000  acres  and  pays  a  total  rental  of  R.  1000,  and  that 
a  village  B  has  the  same  acreage  and  same  total  rental  :  — 

Acres. 

But  A's  area  consists  of  j  3°°  'bl<Jc,k  '  SQl1  j  =  x  Ooo 
(  700  '  red         ,,    \ 

B's  area  consists  of         \  6o°  \  bl*ck      "    }  =  1,000 
(  400  '  red          ,,    \ 

Now,  by  observation,  careful  experiment  as  to  actual 
produce  on  calculated  areas,  and  inquiry,  it  is  found  that 
the  productiveness  of  '  black  '  to  '  red  '  is  as  20  :  1  2  — 


Sothatin^!300X20= 

(  700  X  12  =     8,400 


14,400  soil-units  of  equal  value. 


A     •,  .     T.       (  600x20  =  12,000 
And  111  B       i 

(  400  x  12  =    4,800 


16,800         „  „  „ 

We  can  now  compare  how  the  equal  rental  of  R.  icoo 
falls ;  for  by  dividing  R.  icoo  by  the  total  soil-units  of 
each,  we  find  that  A's  rate  per  soil-unit  comes  out  rn  anna, 
while  .B's  comes  out  at  0-95  anna.  The  difficulty  is  to  work 
out  the  proper  '  soil-factor '  or  number  by  which  each 
acreage  of  class  of  soil  must  be  multiplied  to  reduce  it  to 
a  common  denominator  of  equal  productivity. 

But  this  factor  can  be  calculated  for  an  entire  tahsil  and 
can  then  be  used  by  slightly  modifying  the  results  to 
provide  for  special  and  local  features  in  individual  villages 
or  groups  of  villages. 

The  tables  prepared  for  the  villages  in  each  circle,  will 
show  the  actual  incidence  per  soil-unit ;  the  unit-rate  as  it 
ought  to  be  on  general  considerations,  in  comparison  with 

VOL.  i.  z 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

other  villages ;  and  the  actual  unit-rate  adopted  with 
reference  to  any  peculiarity  in  the  village  itself.  In  many 
tables  I  find  this  last  is  something  less  than  the  second, 
because  of  the  caste  or  condition  of  the  tenants,  or  some 
other  special  consideration  of  the  kind.  Thus,  for  instance, 
we  may  have  an  actual  incidence  per  soil-unit  of  0*65  anna ; 
but  with  reference  to  increase  in  assets  (extended  area  of 
cultivation,  rents  having  risen,  &c.),  the  incidence  might 
fairly  be  0*80 ;  but  from  considerations  of  the  actual  state 
of  the  tenantry,  the  Settlement  Officer  will  recommend  0-70 
as  the  rate  to  be  adopted.  Of  course,  given  this  rate  and 
the  soil-factors,  it  is  a  mere  matter  of  arithmetic  to  take 
out  the  actual  rent  per  acre  of  each  soil  in  the  village  as 
shown  in  the  map  and  field  index. 

§  4.    Element  of  intuitive  calculation  in  Assessment 

work. 

"With  all  these  different  methods,  it  is  apt  to  be  supposed 
that,  after  all,  Settlement  is  very  much  a  matter  of  indi- 
vidual taste  and  opinion,  and  that  the  elaborate  tables  and 
calculations  do  not  produce  much  but  expense  and  long 
report- writing.  There  is,  no  doubt,  in  every  assessment,  a 
point  where  it  comes  to  taking  a  certain  figure,  which  implies 
an  element  of  personal  judgment — the  intuitive  conclusion 
of  a  trained  mind  accustomed  to  the  work.  But  such 
conclusions  are  tested  after  they  originate,  so  that  they  are 
practically  satisfactory. 

All  Settlement  systems  of  a  modern  kind  depend  on 
having  an  accurate  survey  of  every  field — grouping  of 
villages  into  !  assessment  circles ' — or  something  equivalent 
— according  to  general  similarity  of  position  and  advantages, 
and  a  complete  classification  of  soils  whereby  every  field 
can  be  referred  to  a  certain  class,  for  which  an  appropriate 
rate  is  worked  out. 

What  that  rate  is  to  be,  is  calculated  under  the  different 
systems  in  different  ways.  In  a  country  rented  by  tenants,  it 
depends  on  the  rent  actually  paid,  correcting  the  record 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  339 

where  it  is  not  a  real  or  full  rent  that  is  shown ;  and  supplying 
a  proper  figure  where  the  land  does  not  pay  rent.  In  other 
places,  it  is  a  rate  derived  from  general  considerations  of  past 
payments  in  relation  to  subsequent  rise  in  prices  and  im- 
proved condition,  generally  checked  by  estimates  of  produce 
or  rental  receipts.  In  others  again  it  approximates  more 
to  a  rate  representing  the  half  of  the  actual  '  net  produce ' 
(produce  after  allowing  for  all  costs  and  profits  of  labour). 
In  most  systems  the  acreage  rate  represents  rather  the  net 
income,  than  an  actual  net  produce  valued  in  money  ;  and 
the  general  rule  is  that  from  45-55  per  cent,  of  the  calcu- 
lated net  income  is  the  Land-Revenue. 

Originally  the  person  responsible  for  the  revenue  was 
content  to  pay  ninety  per  cent,  and  retain  ten  per  cent. ; 
he  made  his  profit  in  other  ways.  Even  when  under 
British  law,  he  was  first  called  '  proprietor  ' — and  it  might 
seem  that  a  proprietor  was  hardly  to  be  so  called  if 
he  had  to  pay  so  heavy  a  share  to  the  State, — it  must  be 
remembered  that  the  proprietary  right  was  a  pure  gift  of 
which  one  person  (or  one  body]  was  not  to  get  the  whole 
benefit ;  and  further  that  the  '  assets '  of  which  he  gave  up 
ninety  per  cent.,  did  not  really  represent  anything  like  his 
whole  receipts.  As  the  systems  became  more  searching  in 
their  calculations,  the  percentage  was  reduced,  at  first  to 
sixty-six  per  cent,  or  two -thirds,  and  then  lower  still  *. 

But,  to  return  to  the  calculation  of  assets  or  the  rates 
which  represent  assets  per  acre.  There  must  necessarily  be 
a  point  where  estimation — guess-work  if  the  term  is  pre- 
ferred— comes  in.  No  rule  can  possibly  be  laid  down  as  to 
whether  a  certain  soil  should  pay  i  R.  or  i  R.  8  a.  or  i  R.  ica. 
per  acre  :  a  sense  of  fitness  under  all  the  conditions  of  the 
case,  arising  in  the  mind  of  a  practical  officer  who  has 
carefully  inspected  the  land  map  and  note-book  in  hand, 
must  begin  the  work ;  but  if  the  figure  is  not  justifiable,  its 
error  will  surely  appear  when  we  come  to  apply  the  rates 

1  And  where,  as  in  some  cases  in  only  a  nominal  proprietor,  and  glad 

Bengal,  it  still  remains  at  seventy  to  collect  at  a  remuneration  of  thirty 

per  cent.,  it  is  where  the  person  per  cent.,  while  the  tenantry  get  a 

holding  the    Settlement   is    really  larger  share  of  the  total. 

Z  2 


340  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

to  the  whole  village  or  circle,  and  compare  the  results  with 
existing  payments  and  test  them  in  various  ways.  And  in 
Bombay  the  test  is  mainly  applied  by  having  the  relative 
value  of  fields  fixed  on  certain  definite  principles,  so  that 
if  the  full  rate  is  at  all  accurate,  the  individual  valuation 
of  fields  is  almost  a  matter  of  arithmetic. 

All  systems  insist  on  the  rates  being  reported  and  justi- 
fied, before  actually  put  into  force ;  and  therefore,  though 
the  rates  may  be  initiated  to  some  extent  by  more  or  less 
arbitrary  methods,  they  are  not  used  till  their  resulting 
totals  are  tested  and  examined  on  data  which  are  quite 
sound  and  satisfactory,  while  the  results  are  made  to  conform 
to  principles  of  equitable  taxation  laid  down  by  Government. 

§  5.    '  Cesses' 

Properly  speaking,  we  are  concerned  only  with  the  '  land- 
revenue,'  but  it  may  be  convenient  to  explain  that  in  many 
Settlement  Records  another  charge  will  be  found  entered. 
The  co-sharer  in  a  village,  for  example,  is  entered  as  paying 
for  his  field  say  15  rupees,  of  which  13  R.  is  '  mal '  or  land- 
revenue,  and  2  R.  is  '  siwai '  or  cesses.  The  cesses  were  from 
an  early  date  levied  to  pay  for  certain  public  works  which 
benefited  the  locality  only,  and  were  not,  therefore,  properly 
a  charge  against  the  Imperial  Land-Revenue l. 

The  '  cesses '  are  levied  at  the  present  day  under  local 
Acts. 


SECTION  XI. — THE  MODERN  QUESTION  OF  A  GENERAL 
PERMANENT  SETTLEMENT. 

Before  I  pass  on  to  some  other  matters  of  importance 
connected  with  land-revenue  administration,  I  feel  that  it  is 
almost  unavoidable  to  give  some  further  detail  regarding 

1  The  land-revenue  proper  is,  for  army,  home  charges,  &c., — and  the 

budget  purposes,  divided  between  local  treasures  of  the  different  pro- 

the     Imperial     treasury — to     meet  vinces,  for  general  provincial  expen- 

Imperial  or  general  charges,  like  the  diture. 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  341 

the  proposal  to  assess  the  land-revenues  of  provinces  once 
and  for  all.  Probably  there  are  now  very  few  persons  of 
Indian  experience  who  are  likely  to  entertain  any  such  pro- 
position with  favour  ;  and  for  official  purposes  the  question 
is  dead  and  buried.  But  from  time  to  time  such  questions 
recrudesce  ;  and  dressed  up  in  showy  and  plausible  argu- 
ments, they  are  made  use  of  to  the  bewilderment  of  persons 
to  whom  the  facts  of  the  case  are  not  familiar.  I  believe 
that  a  few  pages  devoted  to  the  actual  history  of  the  ques- 
tion during  the  last  twenty  years,  and  to  a  plain  statement 
of  some  of  the  leading  considerations  on  the  merits  of  the 
discussion,  will  not  be  without  their  use,  nor  wholly  devoid 
of  interest,  especially  to  the  non-official  reader. 

§  i.    Official  History  of  the  Question. 

This  question  arose  for  the  second  time  with  reference  to 
the  Settlements  of  the  North- Western  Provinces 1. 

When  the  thirty  years'  Settlements  made  under  the 
Regulations  of  1822  and  1833  began  to  fall  in,  the  country 
was  still  suffering  from  the  effects  of  the  disorder  produced 
by  the  Mutiny,  and  by  the  famine  and  cholera  of  1860. 
Under  such  gloomy  circumstances,  the  districts  came  up  to 
be  re-settled  for  a  new  term.  The  report  on  the  famine  of 
1 860-61  by  Colonel  Baird  Smith,  struck  the  key-note  of 
praising  the  moderate  assessments  of  the  past  Settlements, 
and  treating  them  as  an  instalment  of  a  gift  which  would 
be  completed  by  making  the  moderate  assessment  permanent. 
The  light  assessments  had  enabled  people  to  bear  up  against 
the  famines  in  the  last  year  better  than  they  had  done  in 
the  famine  of  1837-38  ;  and  it  was  urged  that  if  the  assess- 
ment was  made,  not  for  thirty  years  but  for  ever,  it  would 
achieve  still  greater  success.  This  report  received,  at  the 
time,  a  good  deal  of  commendation.  There  is,  however,  no 

1  I  am   indebted  throughout  to  and   Co.).     A  collection   of  official 

Mr.  (now  Sir  A.)  Colvin's  admirable  papers    regarding    the   Permanent 

Memorandum  on   the   Revision  of  Settlement  was   also   reprinted    in 

Land  Revenue  in  the  North-Western  1879. 
Provinces,  1872  (Calcutta  :  Wyman 


342  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

sufficient  reason  to  assume  that  the  permanence  of  a  Settle- 
ment has  anything  whatever  to  do  either  with  the  improve- 
ment of  the  land  or  the  happiness  of  the  people.  And  there 
are  other  considerations  which  the  Report  ignored.  But  the 
pendulum  of  general  and  official  opinion  swings  in  a  long 
course  from  side  to  side  in  these  revenue-administration 
questions, — permanency,  tenant-right,  and  so  forth  ;  and  at 
that  period  it  was  again  on  the  descent  towards  the  Per- 
manent-Settlement side.  It  also  happened  that,  in  1861, 
attention  had  been  attracted  to  the  unexploited  waste  lands 
of  India.  Forest  conservancy  had  not  then  come  under  the 
public  notice,  and  even  if  it  had,  the  area  of  waste  available 
for  cultivation  was  large.  Lord  Canning,  then  Governor- 
General,  wrote  a  minute  on  the  subject ;  and  it  was  argued 
that  if  the  lands  were  sold  free  of  any  revenue  demand,  it 
would  encourage  their  occupation  and  draw  capital  to  this 
source  of  expected  profit. 

And  naturally,  from  the  question  of  occupying  waste  lands 
free  of  revenue  charge,  the  Govern  or -General's  remarks 
passed  on  to  the  possible  advantages  of  a  general  redemp- 
tion of  the  land-revenue  on  estates  already  occupied.  The 
redemption  was  to  be  effected  by  paying  up  in  one  sum  the 
prospective  value  of  the  revenue  demand.  On  this,  the 
Board  of  Revenue  in  the  North -West  Provinces  advocated 
a  permanent  settlement  (for,  of  course,  the  revenue  must  be 
permanently  assessed  before  it  could  be  redeemed).  The 
Secretary  of  State,  however,  in  1862,  rejected  the  policy  of 
a  redemption  of  land-revenue,  but  said  he  would  listen  to 
proposals  for  a  permanent  Settlement. 

It  needs  no  lengthened  explanation  to  understand  that  so 
long  as  a  district  is  not  fully  cultivated,  and  there  is  any 
serious  prospect  of  alteration  in  its  economic  position,  an 
assessment  hastily  made  permanent  must  be  ever  after 
regretted.  The  form  the  problem  took  in  1862  was — What 
are  the  conditions  which  must  be  fulfilled  seriatim  before 
a  district  can  be  fit  for  a  final  revision  of  assessment,  so  that 
there  need  be  no  further  change  ?  At  first  it  was  assumed 
that  when  a  careful  revision  of  the  existing  (and  then 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  343 

expiring)  rates  had  been  effected,  and  when  no  considerable 
increase  of  cultivation  in  future  was  probable,  a  permanent 
assessment  might  be  practicable. 

In  1 864  the  terms  were  fqrmulated  by  the  Government  of 
India  (and  were  modified  at  home  in  1 865).  The  condition  was 
laid  down  that  eighty  per  cent,  of  the  culturable  area  should 
have  been  brought  under  cultivation,  and  then  that  the  rate 
of  permanent  assessment  need  not  be  as  low  as  fifty  per  cent, 
of  the  net  assets  (the  rate  at  which  the  revenue  demand  had 
previously  been  fixed  by  the  ordinary  Settlement  rules). 
But  this  was  not  satisfactory ;  and  in  1867  another  condition 
was  added,  regarding  the  probability  of  canal  irrigation 
being  extended  to  the  lands  in  the  next  twenty  years.  This, 
of  course,  largely  alters  the  rate  of  produce  and  the  value 
of  the  land. 

Then,  it  seems,  officers  were  set  to  work  to  find  out  what 
districts  or  parts  of  districts  could  be  permanently  settled 
under  these  conditions.  But  in  1869  some  cases  came  up 
(in  the  course  of  the  inquiry)  in  which  it  was  demon- 
strated that — although  the  conditions  were  satisfied — there 
would  be  a  great  prospective  loss  to  Government  by  making 
the  assessment  permanent.  Accordingly  a  third  condition 
was  recommended.  The  Government  of  India,  in  concur- 
ring, went  so  far  as  to  say,  what  practically  amounted  to 
this,  that  a  permanent  Settlement  should  be  deferred  so 
long  as  the  land  continued  to  improve  in  value  by  any 
causes  which  were  not  the  direct  result  of  the  occupant's 
own  efforts. 

It  does  not  seem  to  have  occurred  to  the  supporters  of 
the  idea  of  a  permanent  Settlement,  that  it  would  be  possi- 
ble to  secure  all  or  nearly  all  the  advantages,  whatever  they 
are,  without  the  disadvantages  of  fixing  a  limit  which — no 
matter  what  new  combinations  the  future  may  produce — 
can  never  be  altered.  Still  less  did  it  seem  to  them 
necessary  to  be  very  cautious  (in  India)  when  we  prophesy 
what  will  be  the  results,  in  the  future,  of  any  given  pro- 
posal. For  instance,  let  us  refer  to  the  difficulty  which 
arises  when  a  cash  assessment  is  fixed  for  ever,  and  a  fall  in 


344  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

the  value  of  money  occurs.  The  reader  of  the  present  day 
will  peruse  with  something  like  amazement,  the  remark  in 
Sir  Charles  Wood's  despatch  of  1862,  that  the  'fall  in  the 
value  of  money  was  not  of  sufficient  moment  to  influence 
the  judgment  of  Her  Majesty's  Government  to  any  material 
extent.  Prices  were  unlikely  to  rise  greatly :  even  if  they 
should  rise,  the  Government  of  India  might  easily  find 
sources  of  income  other  than  the  land1.' 

But  to  continue :  the  practical  outcome  of  the  discussion 
at  the  time,  was  (as  I  have  said)  that  a  searching  inquiry 
into  the  condition  of  districts  was  to  be  made,  to  see  really 
what  districts  were  in  a  condition  that  would  satisfy  the 
requirements  of  the  case.  Before  this  was  completed,  the 
very  difficulty  which  Sir  Charles  Wood  treated  so  lightly, 
actually  overtook  us  ; — the  increasing  depreciation  of  silver 
had  begun  seriously  to  embarrass  the  Indian  Government ; 
and  the  financial  position  afforded  unmistakeable  proof  of 
the  danger  of  attaching  permanency  to  a  money-assessment. 
For  a  time  the  subject  dropped.  But  in  1882,  it  finally 
came  up  again  in  connection  with  the  Kesolution  which 
the  Government  of  India  issued  on  the  subject  of  reform 
in  the  procedure  of  Settlements.  The  key-note  of  this 
was,  the  possibility  of  securing  the  advantages  derivable 
from  a  permanent  Settlement,  without  abandoning  the  un- 
questioned claim  of  Government  to  share  in  the  increase 
resulting  from  improvements  made  by  itself,  and  from  a 
general  rise  in  prices. 

As  far  as  a  question  of  permanent  Settlement  (pure  and 
simple)  is  concerned,  the  Government  of  India  despatch 


1  As  a  matter  of  fact,  nothing  is  taking  a  share  from  the  produce  of 

more   difficult   than    to   '  find   the  land,  so  also  he  gives  him  a  share 

other    sources.'      While    provision  of  the  increase  of  the  merchant  and 

has  now  to  be  made  for  making  an  the  manufacturer.     (Chap.  vii.  127- 

increasing  charge  in  the  Budget  for  131  ;  x.  120,  &c.)     The  land-revenue 

loss  by  exchange,  the  subjects  of  becoming  more  and  more  in  effect  a 

taxation  are  extremely  limited.  The  tax  on  agricultural  income,  the  tax 

Income-tax,  or  a  tax  on  trades  and  on  other  incomes  is  its  direct  and 

professions,  is  the  main  alternative,  logical  counterpart.     However  this 

but    it  presents    great    difficulties.  may  be,  it  is  certainly  not  easy  to 

Nevertheless,  it  is  interesting  to  mark  find  other  sources  of  revenue, 
that,  as  Manu  contemplates  the  king 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  345 

elicited  from  the  Secretary  of  State  a  reply l  which,  after 
admitting  the  difficulty  of  finding  other  sources  of  revenue, 
noticing  the  change  that  had  come  over  the  financial  posi- 
tion, and  acknowledging  that  the  anticipations  of  benefit 
from  the  permanent  Settlement  in  Bengal  had  not  been 
realised,  concluded: — 

'  I  concur  with  Your  Excellency's  Government  that  the 
policy  laid  down  in  1862  should  now  be  formally  abandoned.' 

And  in  writing  to  the  North-Western  Provinces  Govern- 
ment the  Government  of  India  said  2 : — 

'  It  is  sufficient  for  present  purposes  to  announce  that  Her 
Majesty's  Secretary  of  State  has  now  definitely  agreed  with 
the  Government  of  India  in  rejecting  the  policy  of  a  perma- 
nent Settlement  pure  and  simple.' 

§  2.    General  reflections  on  the  principle  of  permanence. 

It  is  no  part  of  this  work,  intended  for  practical  purposes, 
to  enter  into  discussions  of  principles.  I  desire  to  give  the 
results  rather  than  the  details  of  controversies.  At  the 
same  time,  in  a  matter  like  this,  which  has  so  often  been 
misrepresented,  I  may  be  pardoned  for  adding  a  few 
remarks.  It  would  be  difficult,  in  a  thorough  and  unpre- 
judiced inquiry  which  went  beyond  mere  phrases,  to 
discover  any  real  argument  for  a  permanent  Settlement — 
I  mean  an  argument  in  which  the  perpetuity  of  the  assess- 
ment is  the  essential  point— except  the  one  that  all  future 
costs  of  re-settlement  and  all  harassment  to  the  people  would 
be  avoided.  All  other  arguments  (as  far  as  they  are  not 
merely  prophetic  of  imagined  results)  may  at  once  be 
admitted,  only  they  are  equally  true  of  any  Settlement  for 
which  a  fair  term  of  duration  is  provided.  And  as  regards 
the  one  argument  which  is  real,  the  benefit  is  surely  far 
outweighed  by  the  admitted  sacrifice  of  revenue,  when  it 

1  Despatch    No.   24,    dated   28th  2  No.  525  R.,  dated  gth  May,  1883. 

March,  1883. 


346  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

is  remembered  that  the  process  of  re-settlement  can,  by 
judicious  arrangements,  be  so  carried  out  as  to  be  very 
slightly,  if  at  all,  vexatious,  and  its  cost  reduced  to  a 
minimum. 

As  regards  the  'prophetic  arguments' — the  hoped-for 
creation  of  a  prosperous  middle  class,  the  improvement  of 
the  land  and  the  growth  of  other  sources  of  State  income, 
expected  from  the  permanent  assessment,  the  experience 
(under  most  favourable  conditions)  in  Bengal  and  Benares, 
shows  that  as  a  fact,  though  the  assessment  has  become  very 
light,  nothing  of  the  kind  has  happened1.  As  regards  the 
greater  encouragement  to  agriculture,  and  to  the  expendi- 
ture of  capital  on  irrigation  and  other  landlords'  improve- 
ments, as  a  matter  of  fact,  in  no  single  province  or  district 
has  a  permanent  Settlement  been  known  to  have  any  such 
effect. 

In  the  first  place  it  may  be  asked  (with  one  of  the 
Collectors  in  the  North  -Western  Provinces) — as  to  improve- 
ments made  by  landlords,  where,  as  a  rule,  are  they  ? 
Generally,  they  are  made  at  the  expense  of  the  cultivating- 
tenants,  at  any  rate  in  the  end.  And  certainly  where 
landlords  do  make  improvements,  little  difference  can  be 
detected  between  permanently-settled  and  other  estates. 
Here  and  there,  a  landlord  makes  improvements,  because 


1  Nothing  can  be  more  curious  Moreover,  under  native  custom, 
than  the  results  of  a  low  assessment,  properties  become  subdivided  and 
whether  fixed  for  ever  or  not.  In  again  subdivided,  till  their  value 
one  large  district,  at  least,  where  a  is  frittered  away  ;  the  money- 
low  assessment  was  secured  for  lender  steps  in,  and  land  again 
thirty  years,  the  result  has  been,  begins  to  aggregate  in  the  hands  of 
not  that  a  wealthy  class  has  arisen,  a  class  alien  to  agricultural  know- 
but  that  simply  all  restraint  has  ledge  and  interests.  All  these  eco- 
vanished,  and  the  poor  population  nomical  questions,  interesting  as 
has  multiplied  to  such  an  extent  they  are,  are  necessarily  beyond  the 
that  the  wealth  accumulated  is  not  scope  of  my  book.  I  must  only  add 
more  able  to  support  the  increased  the  notorious  fact  that  in  well- 
mass  of  people  than  the  former  re-  managed  Native  States,  where  the 
sources  were  to  feed  the  then  exist-  revenue  is  double,  perhaps  four 
ing  numbers.  In  other  words,  ten  times  as  high  as  in  the  British  dis- 
men  have  not  grown  rich  by  the  tricts,  the  people  are  apparently  as 
rise  of  their  income  from  R.  1000  to  prosperous  :  only  that,  to  be  sure, 
R.  10,000,  but  a  thousand  persons  their  power  of  transferring  their 
have  appeared  instead  of  ten,  to  land  is  very  limited,  and  there  are 
live  on  the  increased  amount.  no  pleaders  and  few  law  courts  ! 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  347 

he  is  an  enlightened  man,  but  it  depends  on  the  man.  not 
on  the  supposed  security1. 

Mr.  J.  R.  Reid,  Secretary  to  the  Government,  North- 
Western  Provinces,  giving  his  personal  experience,  wrote 
in  1873:— 

'  According  to  theory  one  should  find  estates  like  these  (per- 
manently settled)  in  the  most  flourishing  condition,  with  all 
manner  of  improvements  introduced,  and  landlords  very  well 
to  do,  and  most  liberal  to  their  tenants.  But,  in  fact,  in  riding 
through  these  villages,  and  through  the  parganas  generally, 
you  would  not  detect  anything  in  the  appearance  of  the  people 
and  land,  in  the  number  of  wells  and  other  means  of  irriga- 
tion, the  kind  and  look  of  the  crops,  the  size  of  the  houses,  the 
air  and  condition  of  the  people  and  cattle,  to  make  you  suspect 
that  the  (permanently-settled)  land-owners  enjoy  a  different 
tenure  from  their  neighbours  of  similar  caste 2  and  condition 
in  temporarily-settled  estates.  There  is  as  much  capital  laid 
out  and  industry  bestowed  on  the  land  in  the  one  set  of  estates 
as  in  the  other.' 

I  could  multiply  testimony  to  the  same  effect ;  but  the 
fact  does  not  really  admit  of  dispute. 

This  matter  of  improvements  is  connected  directly  with 
another  question,  which  is  not  usually  noticed  by  the  advo- 
cates of  a  permanent  Settlement.  Does  any  landholder 
really  believe  in  or  realize,  permanency  1  For  example, 
will  any  one  seriously  contend  that,  looking  at  all  the  ups 
and  downs  of  history,  a  Zamindar  in  1793  f^olized  that  the 
Government  would  last  for  ever,  or  even  for  a  long  period 
of  years  ?  Would  not  a  promise  of  fixity  for  thirty  or 

1  I  would   call  attention  to  the  upset  by  the  Special  Commission,  as 

curious  case  noted  in  the  chapter  on  an  unjustifiable  one.    Yet  the  Kajti, 

North- Western    Provinces  tenures,  during  the  years  he  held,  made  im- 

of  the  great  improvements  made  by  provements    on    the    most    liberal 

a  Kaja  of  Benares,  in  the  pargana  scale,  which  doubled  his  rental, 
of  Bara  (Allahabad),  of  which  he  2  He  mentions  similarity  of  caste  ; 

was  merely  the  auction-purchaser  because,  for  purposes  of  comparison , 

at  a  sale  for  arrears  of  revenue  in  if  the  caste  is  altogether  different, 

1820.     Not  only  was  there  no  kind  the  result  might  be  put  down  to 

of  permanence  about  his  Settlement,  that.      Some   castes   are   by   nature 

but  the   question   of  inquiry  into  good     thrifty     cultivators ;     others 

revenue  sales  was  then  in  the  air,  slovenly    and    bad  :    there    is    no 

and  this  very  sale  was  ultimately  ignoring  the  fact. 


348  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP    BEITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

twenty  years,  even  then,  have  seemed  to  him  a  period 
longer  than  he  could  count  on  ?  And  at  the  present  day, 
do  the  mass  of  unlettered  but  hard-working  petty  land- 
owners ever  think  of  anything  so  remote  as  fifty  years 
hence,  still  less  realize  the  idea  of  permanency,  and  act 
upon  it1? 

But  even  if  it  were  otherwise,  what  possible  right  has 
one  Government  to  bind  (and  seriously  embarrass)  its  suc- 
cessors for  all  time  ?  The  effect  of  a  permanent  Settlement 
is  practically  this,  that  the  Government  of  the  day  selects 
a  certain  class  of  estate  or  a  special  province,  and  says — 
'  You  shall  never  be  called  on  to  bear  more  than  a  certain 
share  of  the  public  burdens,  no  matter  what  your  neigh- 
bours pay.'  Of  course,  I  am  aware  that  other,  and  especially 
indirect,  taxes  may  be  imposed,  but  practically,  in  Bengal 
for  instance,  what  are  they  ?  It  is  a  fair  estimate  to  make, 
that  at  present,  for  no  conceivable  reason,  the  class  of 
Bengal  landlords  is  contributing  (proportionately)  to  the 
public  expenditure,  less  than  one-third  of  what  any  one 
else  pays2. 

On  the  whole,  therefore,  it  is  impossible  not  to  conclude 
that  in  theory,  as  binding  future  Governments  and  exempt- 
ing certain  classes  from  part  of  the  burthen  of  taxation, 

1  As  the  Collector  of  Gorakhpur  cumstances,  indispensable,  it  must 

remarks      '  Revenue-free   estates   i^in  be  paid  by  some  class  or  other,  and 

many  the  revenue  is  altogether  re-  no   historical  justification   can  get 

mitted,  be   it  remembered,  in  per-  rid  of  the  essential  injustice  of  an 

petuity)  are  as  secure  as  they  can  be,  arrangement  by  which  those  who 

but  I  do  not  find  that  this  security  benefit    most    by  the    administra- 

adds  to  their  selling  value.  Revenue-  tion  should  contribute  least  to  its 

free    and     revenue-paying     estates  cost.' 

alike  sell  according  to  their  imme-  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  as 

diate  profits.'  early  as  Col.  Wilks'  time  (The  History 

a  On  this  subject  I  may  quote  Mr.  of  Mysore  was  published  about  1817) 
Justice  H.  S.  Cunningham  in  an  this  aspect  of  a  Permanent  Settle- 
article  on  Indian  Finance  in  the  ment  was  not  unperceived.  Thus 
Asiatic  Quarterly  Review  (April  1888).  Col.  Wilks  wrote  (History,  p.  123), 
He  says  : —  '  AJI  English  Chancellor  of  the  Ex- 

'  The  question  has  sometimes  been  chequer  who    should    presume    to 

asked   whether  a    compact   so   in-  pledge  the  national  faith  to  an  un- 

herently   inequitable    as  the    Per-  alterable  tax,  might  captivate  the 

manent  Settlement,  can  be   main-  multitude,  but  would  be  smiled  at 

tained  under  the  altered  conditions  by  the    financiers  of  Europe  ;    yet 

of  succeeding  times  ...  A  certain  principles  do  not  alter  in  traversing 

expenditure  being,  in  existing  cir-  the  ocean.' 


CHAP.V.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  349 

and  not  applied  universally,  the  declaration  of  a  per- 
manently fixed  land-tax  is  inadmissible.  Further,  that  in 
practice,  a  general,  unchangeable,  assessment  has  no  advan- 
tages which  are  not  equally  to  be  secured  by  a  moderate 
assessment  for  a  fairly  long  term  of  years.  What  that 
term  should  be,  depends  on  a  variety  of  considerations, 
local,  as  well  as  of  principle  ;  and  though  a  certain  concur- 
rence of  practice  has  resulted  in  thirty  years  or  twenty 
years  as  an  usual  period,  Government  has  wisely  refused, 
by  either  legislative  enactment  or  otherwise,  to  stereotype 
any  rule.  The  circumstances  of  the  Central  Provinces  have 
only  recently  demonstrated  that  periods  from  twelve  to 
twenty  years  for  the  new  Settlements,  will  be  practically 
the  best. 

As  to  imaginary  or  anticipated  encouragements  and 
advantages  to  agriculture,  it  is  idle  to  refer  to  them  in 
the  face  of  nearly  a  century's  experience  of  what  has 
happened  in  provinces  where  the  experiment  has  been 
tried,  and  tried  under  very  favourable  circumstances.  It 
certainly  is  high  time  that  this  'policy'  should  now  be 
regarded  as  'formally  abandoned.' 


SECTION  XII. — THE  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE 
AND  REVENUE. 

Having  thus  sketched  the  development  of  the  provincial 
land-revenue  systems,  the  remainder  of  this  '  General ' 
chapter  will  deal,  without  reference  to  particular  pro- 
vinces (unless  they  are  expressly  named),  with  certain 
important  matters  of  modern  revenue-administration,  which 
have  of  late  years  come  into  prominence — chiefly  as  the 
result  of  the  inquiry  into  the  whole  subject  of  land-revenue 
administration  which  was  made  by  the  Famine  Commission 
in  1879.  It  is  hardly  needed  to  point  out  that,  except  in 
limited  tracts,  the  failure  of  the  summer  or  autumn  rains 
(as  the  case  may  be)  brings  famine  as  the  great  scourge  of 
agricultural  life  in  the  Indian  provinces.  Serious  famines 


35O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

in  1866  and  in  1877-78 — not  to  speak  of  others — led  to  the 
most  earnest  desire,  first,  to  perfect  a  system  of  organized 
relief  when  famine  actually  occurs,  and  for  this  purpose  to 
compile  '  Famine  Codes  '  giving  the  results  of  experience  as 
to  what  is  to  be  done  and  how  to  do  it ;  but  still  more  (in 
the  second  place)  to  see  what  could  be  done  to  put  the 
administration  in  a  state  of  preparedness  against  the  oc- 
currence of  bad  years.  To  effect  this  object  the  entire 
land  administration  machinery  had  to  be  overhauled,  and 
all  agricultural  conditions  reviewed.  If  I  were  asked  to 
summarise,  in  a  few  words,  what  has  been  the  most  useful 
outcome  of  the  reforms  recommended,  I  should  say, — the 
perfection  of  the  local  official  machinery  and  of  the  records 
of  fact  which  their  work  makes  available  for  administra- 
tive purposes. 

Without  this  knowledge  of  facts,  you  cannot  have  the 
difficulties  of  re-settlement  overcome  ;  you  cannot  have 
famine  warning;  you  cannot  have  any  agricultural  im- 
provement ;  and  you  cannot  have  good  revenue-adminis- 
tration. 

In  order,  therefore,  to  organize  agricultural  inquiry  and 
record,  and  to  improve  revenue-administration,  two  things 
were  necessary.  A  series  of  Provincial  Departments 
charged  with  this  special  business,  and  an  Imperial  Depart- 
ment to  guide  and  direct  the  general  aims  of  each  local 
centre  of  administration,  without,  of  course,  derogating 
either  from  the  responsibility  or  the  power  of  the  Local 
Governments.  Provincial  Departments  require  a  sys- 
tematizing and  controlling  head ;  their  necessary  supplement 
is  an  Imperial  department ;  and  it  may  be  justly  said  that 
one  is  of  little  use  without  the  other. 

I  do  not  undervalue  the  importance  of  the  labour  which 
has  given  us  a  Famine  Code ;  but  that  is  outside  the  scope 
of  this  manual.  And  therefore  I  may  seem  to  ignore  one 
part  of  the  Famine  Commissioners'  work,  and  only  put 
forward  what  they  intended  to  be  a  secondary  object. 

The  Famine  Commission  was  naturally  more  directly 
concerned  with  famine,  its  prevention  and  cure.  It  was 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  351 

therefore  proposed  that  the  Agricultural  Department  in 
each  province  should  have  three  primary  objects, — agri- 
cultural inquiry,  agricultural  improvement,  and  organiza- 
tion of  famine  relief.  But  it  is  obvious  that  there  are 
other  duties  which  the  Government,  looking  beyond  the 
single  subject  of  famine,  must  require.  In  the  first  place, 
famines  are  not  universal,  and  are  happily  only  occa- 
sional, even  in  provinces  subject  to  them.  There  are 
some  whole  provinces  (like  Assam)  and  parts  of  others, 
where  anything  like  real  famine  is  hardly  known  ;  never- 
theless, there  is  ample  scope  for  an  Agricultural  Depart- 
ment. Moreover,  '  improvements  in  agriculture  '  cannot  be 
effected  in  a  short  time.  Too  great  a  zeal  is  apt  to  cost 
much  and  come  to  very  little.  Before  we  can  'improve,' 
we  must  have  full  information  as  to  facts.  Agricultural 
inquiry  must  precede  agricultural  improvement. 

And  agricultural  inquiry  is  equally  important  for  famine 
purposes.  '  The  success  of  an  Agricultural  Department 
would  mainly  depend,'  said  the  Famine  Commission,  '  on 
the  completeness  and  accuracy  with  which  agricultural  and 
economic  facts  are  collected  in  each  village,  and  compiled 
in  each  subdivision  and  district  throughout  the  country. 
Without  a  perfect  system  of  local  information,  the  warnings 
of  approaching  troubles  are  lost  or  misunderstood ;  and  the 
liability  of  different  parts  of  the  district  to  calamity, — the 
weak  points,  on  which  a  watchful  eye  has  to  be  kept,  are 
not  known  ;  and  relief,  in  the  shape  of  remissions  and  sus- 
pensions of  the  revenue  demand,  even  when  there  is  no 
widespread  famine,  is  apt  to  be  given  imperfectly  and  with 
the  least  benefit.' 

The  branch  of  reform  which  it  comes  within  my  province 
to  speak  of,  is  therefore  one  which  is  by  no  means  of 
secondary  importance. 


352  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BEITFSH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

§  i.    The  Imperial  Department  of  Revenue  and 
Agriculture. 

An  Imperial  Department  of  Revenue  and  Agriculture 
had  for  some  years  past  been  in  contemplation ;  and  under 
Lord  Mayo's  viceroyalty  one  had  been  formed  in  1870. 
But  this  was  abolished  in  I8761,  partly  for  financial  rea- 
sons and  partly  because  the  measure  was  not  successful, 
owing  to  its  not  being  supported  by  corresponding  depart- 
ments in  each  province.  It  became,  in  fact,  only  an  addi- 
tional Secretarial  Department,  with  a  miscellaneous  burden 
of  public  business  ;  so  far  relieving  other  offices,  but  not 
effecting  its  own  special  object,  because  it  had  no  corre- 
sponding machinery  under  each  local  government  to  give 
effect  to  its  recommendations. 

Sir  John  Strachey,  however,  when  Lieutenant-Governor 
of  the  North -West  Provinces  in  1875,  formed  a  local 
department  on  a  new  basis.  The  principle  of  action  was 
that  which  I  have  already  briefly  indicated  as  the  necessary 
preliminary,  as  well  as  the  complement,  to  any  direct  method 
of  preventing  and  remedying  famines.  The  credit  of  clearly 
perceiving  this  principle  and  applying  it  in  practice,  is  due 
to  Mr.  E.  C.  (now  SIR  EDWARD)  BUCK,  then  serving  under 
the  North -West  Provinces  Government.  The  attention  of 
the  Revenue  officers  was  directed  first  to  the  perfecting  of 
the  Land-Records  and  Agricultural  Statistics,  while  agricul- 
tural improvement  was  kept  in  mind  as  a  secondary,  or 

1  The  causes  of  failure  are  briefly  Department  are — 

alluded  to  in  §  2  of  the  Resolution  Revenue. 

(Government  of  India)  of  8th  De-  Agriculture, 

cember,  1881.     An  undue  amount  Famine, 

and  variety  of  subjects  was  thrown  Fibres  and  Silk, 

on  the  new  Department ;  but  what  Cattle-Breeding       and       Cattle- 

really    prevented    it    effecting    its  Disease, 

special  object,  was  the  fact  that  no  Meteorology, 

agency  existed  in  the  provinces  with  Fisheries, 

similar  objects.  Minerals. 

It  was  not  till  the  discussion  of  Museums  and  Exhibitions, 

the  Famine  Commissioners'  Report,  Land-Trade      and     Agricultural 

in  1880,  that  the  scheme  was  again  Statistics, 

considered   under  better   auspices.  Surveys  (including  Geological). 

The  branches  of  work  actually  taken  Emigration, 

up  by  the  Revenue  and  Agricultural  General. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  353 

rather  as  a  subsequent,  object.  This  may  not  be  the  most 
popular,  but  it  is  certainly  the  only  practical  ideal  of  an 
Agricultural  Department  in  the  present  state  of  affairs. 
The  maintenance  of  maps  and  land-records  in  a  state  of 
continuous  correctness,  not  only  leads  to  economy  in  the 
future,  and  facilitates  re-assessment  of  the  revenue,  but 
provides  a  useful  basis  of  agricultural  statistics,  and  a 
knowledge  of  the  peculiarities  of  the  different  districts. 
Without  these,  agricultural  improvement  cannot  be  at- 
tempted ;  it  would  be  working  in  the  dark,  and  spending 
money  in  vain  on  experiments  that  had  no  basis  to  start 
from. 

The  success  of  the  system  in  the  North  -West  Provinces 
has  been  marked ;  and  when  action  was  taken  on  the 
Famine  Commissioners'  Report,  it  was  wisely  determined 
to  organize  for  each  province  a  department  on  the  same 
basis.  The  Imperial  Department  could  now  be  recon- 
structed with  every  prospect  of  permanent  utility,  and  the 
sanction  of  the  Home  Government  was  accordingly  given  ; 
naturally  Sir  EDWARD  BUCK  was  selected  to  be  the  first 
head l. 

The  Imperial  Department  pays  primary  attention  to  the 
Land  Administration,  and  to  improving  the  system  of 
assessing  and  collecting  the  land-revenue  in  each  province. 
But  the  department  is  not  unmindful  of  agricultural  im- 
provement, the  introduction  of  valuable  staples,  the  de- 
velopment of  trade  in  Indian  products,  and  the  conduct 
of  useful  experiments  in  cultivation.  It  will,  of  course, 
supervise  operations  connected  with  famines  when  they 
occur.  But  the  chief  feature  in  the  new  arrangement  has 
been  the  utilization,  under  efficient  control,  of  the  local 
agency  in  each  village,  for  the  purpose  of  maintaining 
maps,  statistics,  and  records,  correct  and  up  to  date  each 

1  The  head  of  the  Department  is,  to  spend  part  of  his  time  on  tour, 

officially,  one  of  the  Secretaries  to  and  thus  can  arrange  on  the  spot, 

the  Government  of  India  (Depart-  or   in   conference   with    the    local 

ment  of  Revenue  and  Agriculture).  authorities,     many     matters     that 

This  plan  was  preferred  to  appoint-  could  not  be  so  quickly  or  so  well 

ing  a  '  Director  '  of  the  Department.  disposed  of  by  correspondence. 
The  Secretary  is  enabled,  however, 

VOL.  I.  A  a 


354  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

year.  The  economy  thus  effected  in  the  cost  of  Settlements 
has  been  estimated1  to  have  already  secured  a  saving  of 
two  hundred  lakhs  of  rupees  ;  and  it  is  likely  to  realize,  in 
the  future,  an  annual  saving  of  from  twelve  to  sixteen  lakhs. 


§  2.    The  Provincial  Departments. 

In  order  to  emphasize  the  importance  of  that  part  of  the 
scheme  which  is  directed  to  perfecting,  and  keeping  correct, 
the  Agricultural  and  Land-Records,  it  was  officially  deter- 
mined that  the  heads  of  the  Provincial  Departments  should 
be  called  '  Directors  of  Land-Records  and  Agriculture  V 
The  departments  have  many  other  duties  which  I  cannot 
here  describe,  and  which,  of  course,  must  vary  according  to  the 
requirements  and  local  conditions  of  the  several  provinces. 
The  conduct  of  agricultural  experiments,  the  care  of  vete- 
rinary schools,  and  model  farms  (where  these  exist),  are 
among  the  most  obvious  3. 

The  Resolution  of  the  Government  of  India  (8th  Decem- 
ber, 1881,  on  Agricultural  Departments)  concludes  : — 

'  The  views  of  the  Government  of  India  may  be  summed  up 
by  saying  that  the  foundation  of  the  work  of  an  Indian  Agri- 
cultural Department  should  be  the  accurate  investigation  of 
facts,  with  a  view  of  ascertaining  what  administrative  course  is 
necessary  to  preserve  the  stability  of  agricultural  operations. 

1  See  the  Finance  Members'  Bud-  the  last  twenty  years,  had  an  almost 
get  Speech  ^1888,1  in  the  Gazette  of  continually       increasing      burden 
India.   The  lakh,  I  may  remind  Eng-  thrown  upon  him  ;  and  the  Land- 
lish  readers,  is  100,000, — a  lakh  of  Records    Department   gave    sorely- 
rupees  is  £10,000    conventionally,  needed  relief  and  help  in  a  matter 
i.e.  if  the  rupee  is  two  shillings.  of  peculiar  importance.     In  discuss- 

2  Resolution      i  Government      of  ing  the  financial  question,  such  a 
India^  Financial  No.  608,  dated  gth  consideration  is  necessarily  left  out 
February,  1887.  of  sight ;    but   if  the  Agricultural 

3  The   establishment  of  Agricul-  Departments  resulted  in  less  saving 
tural   Departments   had    not    long  than  is  actually  the  case,  the  enor- 
proceeded  before  a  financial  inquiry  mous  good  done  by  the   improve- 
was  made  as  to  whether  they  would  ment  of  land  records  would  amply 
be  successful.    Fortunately,  this  has  justify  their  existence.     I  know  of 
resulted   in   a  satisfactory  verdict.  no  one  administrative  measure  of 
But,  in  fact,  these  Departments  are  greater  benefit  to  the  country  than 
defensible  in  the  highest  degree,  on  the  establishment  of  these  Depart- 
their  own    merits.     The    '  District  ments. 

Officer '   has,  by  the  legislation  of 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  355 

.  .  .  The  primary  efforts  of  the  Department  should  ...  be 
devoted  to  the  organization  of  agricultural  inquiry,  which  has 
been  shown  to  comprise  the  duties  of  gauging  the  stability  of 
agricultural  operations  in  every  part  of  a  province,  of  classify- 
ing the  areas  of  the  province  according  to  the  results  of  careful 
investigation,  and  of  deciding  what  method  of  administrative 
treatment  is  suitable  to  each  so  as  to  maintain  agricultural 
operations  at  the  highest  standard  of  efficiency  possible  under 
present  conditions.  .  .  .  From  a  system  ...  of  inquiry  thus 
conducted  will  follow  the  gradual  development  of  agricultural 
improvement.' 


SECTION  XIII. — REFORM  IN  PROCEDURE  FOR 
RE-SETTLEMENTS. 

The  establishment  of  Agricultural  and  Land-Record  De- 
partments, it  is  hardly  too  much  to  say,  alone  rendered  the 
real  simplification  of  the  Settlement  work  of  the  present  and 
future  possible. 

Already,  by  Resolution  in  October  1881 1,  the  Government 
of  India  had  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  when  the  Set- 
tlements fell  in,  it  did  not  follow  that  a  re-settlement,  in 
any  shape,  was  to  be  undertaken  as  a  matter  of  course. 
The  sanction  of  the  Government  of  India  was  required  to 
new  Settlement  operations  ;  and  it  was  to  be  considered,  in 
all  cases,  whether  any  such  increase  in  the  revenue  was 
probable  as  would  make  it  worth  while  to  undertake  them. 
Four  points  were  especially  to  be  noted — the  probable  cost 
of  the  operations,  the  time  they  would  take,  the  increment 
of  revenue  expected,  and  the  incidence  of  the  existing  re- 
venue on  the  individual  landholders. 

If  there  could  be  no  increase  (or  less  than  one  which 
represented  a  profitable  rate  of  interest  on  the  total  anti- 
cipated expenditure),  revision  should  ordinarily  not  be 

1  No.  144,  dated  4th  October,  1881.       course  similar  principles  would  be 
It  did  not  apply  to  the  Governments      recognized  in  those  presidencies, 
of  Bombay  and  Madras  ;  though  of 

A  a  3 


356  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

undertaken,  unless,  indeed,  a  revision  was  needed  because 
of  the  inequality  of  incidence  of  the  last  assessment. 

§  i.    New  System  of  Land  Records  and  their 
Maintenance. 

But  this  '  Resolution '  only  touched  the  fringe  of  the  sub- 
ject. The  whole  question  of  re-settlements,  and  the  means 
of  reducing  their  cost,  and  depriving  them  of  all  their  in- 
conveniences to  the  district  population,  is  one  of  such 
importance  that  it  is  desirable  to  explain  at  some  length 
how  the  work  of  the  Land-Record  Departments  affects  it. 
The  sketch  given  in  preceding  sections  will  have  shown 
how  very  gradually  the  work  of  assessment  has  been 
reduced  to  a  method,  or  rather  to  different  methods,  suited 
to  the  varying  circumstances  of  each  province.  There  re- 
mained still  the  difficulty  that,  however  '  scientific '  the 
method,  hitherto  the  work  of  a  new  Settlement  has  been 
very  costly  and  very  troublesome  ;  and  the  more  elaborate 
the  method,  the  more  costly  and  prolonged  the  operations. 
The  difficulty  arose  from  the  fact  that  it  has  hitherto  been 
unavoidable,  in  making  a  Settlement,  to  have  a  special  staff 
of  Surveyors  and  Settlement  Officers,  with  all  their  subor- 
dinates and  office  staff,  to  record  facts,  compile  statistics, 
fair  out  records,  and  so  forth.  Such  a  staff,  in  the  nature  of 
things,  during  the  whole  of  its  stay,  harasses  the  people  not 
a  little l,  and  it  upsets  all  the  regular  work  in  '  tahsils '  and 
of  the  kdnungos  and  pattudris.  But  suppose  that  at  last 
the  work  is  at  an  end  ;  the  Settlement  records  are  all  faired 
out  and  bound  in  volumes,  and  the  maps  mounted;  the 
originals  are  deposited  in  the  Collector's  Revenue  Record 
Office ;  the  copies  disposed  of  at  the  tahsil  and  in  the  pat- 
wari's  office  or  '  patwar-khana '  in  the  village.  How  soon 
these  records,  correct  as  they  may  have  been  at  a  given 

1  To  say  nothing  of  the  petty  de-  necessary  to  pay  fees  and  douceurs  to 

mands    that    subordinate    officials  secure  more  or  less  imaginary  bene- 

always    make  when    they  are    in  fits.      It    is    impossible   wholly  to 

camp,  in  the  shape  of  supplies,  grass,  prevent    such    things,    when    the 

firewood,  and  such  like  ;  even  if  the  entire     population    practises    and 

foolish  landholders  do  not  think  it  tolerates  them. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EEVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  357 

date,  cease  to  correspond  with  facts  !  New  fields  are  added 
to  the  cultivated  area  out  of  the  waste ;  old  fields  change 
shape  or  boundary  ;  they  are  aggregated  or  divided.  New 
wells  are  sunk,  new  roadways  are  substituted  for  old  ones, 
and  many  other  such  changes  take  place.  Then,  again,  pro- 
prietors are  continually  altering ;  a  certain  number  of  sales 
are  notified,  and  the  usual  applications  for  mutation  of 
names  are  made  and  allowed ;  but  whether  the  fact  has 
ever  found  its  way  into  any  such  record  that  the  Settlement 
list  could  be  corrected,  is  another  matter.  The  result  of  all 
this  (and  much  more  could  be  said  if  space  permitted)  is 
that,  hitherto,  when  the  thirty  years  (let  us  suppose)  of 
Settlement  expired,  the  whole  of  the  records,  prepared 
originally  with  so  much  care,  have  proved  out  of  date,  and 
more  or  less  useless.  There  is,  then,  nothing  for  it  but  to 
re-survey  the  whole  area,  and  to  make  out  fresh  maps  and 
records,  putting  the  whole  district  once  more — for  several 
years — into  the  state  of  unrest  already  described,  to  the 
great  detriment  of  agriculture,  as  well  as  of  administrative 
and  social  well-being. 

If  only  the  separate  records  could  be  abolished ;  if  only 
a  certain  set  of  necessary  papers — the  large  scale-map  show- 
ing every  field  and  every  detail  of  the  estate,  the  index- 
register  to  this ;  the  list  of  proprietors,  their  shares  and 
interests,  and  the  revenue  they  pay  ;  the  list  of  tenants  and 
their  rents ;  and  any  such  supplemental  statistics  as  local 
rules  might  require, — if  only  these  could  be  placed  in  the 
hands  of  a  village  patwari,  tested  and  signed  as  correct  up 
to  a  given  date,  viz.  the  commencement  of  a  new  Settle- 
ment; and  if  thenceforward  these  maps  and  statements 
could  be  continually  corrected,  fresh  fields  plotted  in,  and 
statements  periodically  recopied  and  kept  up  to  date  ;  when 
the  term  of  Settlement  expired,  the  'Record-of-rights'  would 
be  found  as  correct  and  conformable  to  facts  as  when  it  began. 
Then  the  Collector  himself,  or  perhaps  a  specially-deputed 
officer,  could  soon  make  out  the  necessary  schedules  for 
revising  the  assessment,  and  the  '  re-settlement '  would  be 
over. 


358  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

But  to  secure  such  an  ideal  procedure,  several  things 
are  necessary.  First,  the  staff  of  village  patwdris  and 
inspecting  kdnungos  must  be  well  taught  and  made  com- 
petent to  do  the  survey  work  that  the  maintenance  of 
village  maps  involves.  Next,  their  work  must  be  con- 
tinually inspected,  tested,  and  corrected,  till  the  machine 
works  without  friction  and  failure. 

Next,  the  rules  for  assessment,  applicable  to  future  re- 
visions, must  be  reduced  to  the  greatest  simplicity. 

The  first  of  the  steps  above  indicated  has  everywhere 
been  taken.  Schools  have  been  opened  for  the  instruction 
of  patwdris  and  their  sons  in  surveying  and  other  neces- 
sary branches  of  education.  The  whole  staff  has  been 
graded  and  organized,  and  rules  made  for  its  appointment 
and  control. 

Speaking  generally,  each  patwdri  has  a  circle  of  three 
or  four  villages,  and  the  inspecting  officers  or  kdnungos  are 
continually  moving  about  and  testing  the  measurements 
and  the  accuracy  of  entries  in  the  books  made  by  the 
patwdri.  There  is  also  what  is  called  a  Registrar 
kdnungo,  at  the  head-quarters  of  the  tahsil  or  local  sub- 
division, who  keeps  the  books  and  compiles  the  village 
returns  into  corresponding  subdivisional  returns.  To  give 
a  general  idea  of  how  the  village  staff  is  manned  and 
supervised,  it  may  be  mentioned  that  in  the  North -West 
Provinces  (excluding  Oudh)  the  number  of  patwdris  is 
about  2o,oco,  the  field  inspectors  or  kdnungos  number  450, 
or  one  to  every  45  patwdris.  The  average  area  of  a 
patwdri' s  circle  is  1,130  acres  (cultivated),  so  that  the 
local  inspecting  officer  looks  after  above  50,000  cultivated 
acres ;  the  whole  establishment  costs  somewhat  more  than 
23-75  lakhs  of  rupees,  the  reorganized  establishments  and 
their  supervision  costing  about  two  lakhs  more  than  the 
old  establishment  of  patwdris  and  kdnungos. 

It  will  be  seen,  then,  how  this  improvement  will  in- 
creasingly render  possible  the  greatest  reform  of  all  in 
re-settlement  operations, — -namely,  the  carrying  out  of 
revision  operations  without  an  elaborate  re-valuation  of 


CHAP.  V.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTKATION.  359 

lands,  and  by  the  aid  of  the  ordinary  district  staff,  with 
the  smallest  possible  addition  of  special  establishments. 
Instead  of  having  elaborate  volumes  of  special  records, 
prepared  and  put  into  an  office  to  become  totally  useless 
at  the  end  of  thirty  years,  and  another  set  of  village  and 
pargana  accounts  increasingly  out  of  correspondence  with 
the  first,  we  shall  have  one  set  of  simple  maps  and  records 
attested  as  correct  for  a  given  date  and  thenceforward  kept 
up,  because  papers  in  exactly  the  same  forms  will  be  in  the 
hands  of  the  staff  to  be  continually  corrected  from  day 
to  day  1. 

I  need  only  add,  that  the  records  will  not  only  help  the 
work  of  revision  of  Settlement ;  they  will  affect  every 
branch  of  revenue-administration,  for  they  will,  in  time, 
put  us  in  possession  of  what  I  may  call  analytical  know- 
ledge of  the  districts ;  the  knowledge,  as  regards  each  estate 
and  group  of  lands,  whether  it  is  fully  developed,  well 
cultivated,  and  secure  from  famine,  or  only  partially  so, 
and  what  estates  must  be  treated  as  'precarious.'  This 
knowledge  will  be  the  very  key  to  famine  prevention  and 
relief,  as  well  as  to  management  of  estates  in  the  matter  of 
granting  timely  suspensions  and  remissions  of  revenue  in 
bad  years,  and  to  the  adoption  of  a  more  elastic  system  of 

1  This  is  what  Sir  Alfred  Lyall  consulted.    It  would  put  an  end,  in 

wrote  on  the  subject : —  districts  already  properly  settled,  to 

'  It  is  hoped  that,  under  the  re-  all  formal  and  minute  valuations  of 
gular  inspection  and  supervision  theland  ;  it  would,  in  great  measure, 
now  given  from  year  to  year  by  the  do  away  with  the  systematic  en- 
district  establishment,  and  subject  hancements  and  levelling  up  of 
to  certain  checks  and  corrections,  a  rents  that  formed  part  of  the  duty 
body  of  statistics  can,  during  the  of  the  Settlement  Officer,  and  by  the 
currency  of  existing  Settlements,  be  keeping  up,  along  with  the  other 
got  ready  for  each  estate,  upon  statistics,  of  a  careful  record  of  im- 
which,  without  minute  inquiry,  a  provements  made  by  landlords  and 
summary  and  fairly  accurate  esti-  cultivators,  the  profits  of  these  im- 
mate  of  the  rental  assets  might  be  provements  might  be  secured  to 
made.  This  system  would,  it  is  them.  The  body  of  statistics  under 
thought,  provide  the  best  possible  collection  from  year  to  year  could 
method  of  securing  for  Government  at  any  time  be  made  open  to  the 
its  full  share  of  enhanced  rentals.  scrutiny  of  the  proprietors  of  the 
It  would,  moreover,  provide,  from  land,  who  might  thereby  be  able  to 
time  to  time,  for  a  tolerably  equal  forecast,  with  a  certain  degree  of 
distribution  of  the  land-tax,  a  point  assurance,  the  revenue  for  which 
on  the  propriety  and  expediency  of  they  would  become  liable.' 
which  much  stress  is  laid  by  those 


360  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BEITISH    INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

fluctuating  assessments  for  precarious  tracts,  and,  ulti- 
mately, to  really  beneficial  schemes  of  agricultural  im- 
provement. 


§  2.    The  principles  of  reassessment  or  revision  of 
Land-Revenue. 

The  Government  of  India,  on  the  i7th  October,  1882, 
issued  a  Resolution  indicating  certain  principles  on  which 
re-assessments  should  be  made.     I  wish  to  state  the  plan 
propounded  as  a  whole,  but  at  once  premising  that  it  was 
a  tentative  proposal,   and    has   not   been   adopted    in   its 
entirety.      The  original  scheme  was  (i)  that  enhancements 
of  revenue  should  only  be  allowed  on  the  ground  of — 
(a)  rise  in  prices, 
(6)  increase  in  cultivation, 
(c)  improvements  made  at  Government  expense. 

This  proposal  eliminated,  as  a  general  rule,  all  fresh 
attempts  to  value  land.  The  fact  is,  the  majority  of 
districts  have  been  thoroughly  surveyed,  and  soils  classified ; 
and  if  the  local  establishment  do  their  duty  in  keeping  the 
Records,  and  the  maps  on  which  they  are  based,  up  to  date 
in  the  manner  above  described,  there  should  be  only  in 
exceptional  cases  any  necessity  for  further  valuation. 

The  '  rise  in  prices '  principle  (a)  was  to  be  applied  with 
two  very  important  limitations.  In  the  first  place^  to 
guard  against  the  effect  of  small  or  uncertain  fluctuations, 
small  rises  of  prices  were  to  be  disregarded ;  nor  need  the 
enhancement  be  in  full  proportion  to  the  rise,  but  so  as 
to  leave  a  margin  with  a  view  to  meeting  any  increase  in 
the  cost  of  agriculture,  and  of  providing  for  a  rise  in  the 
standard  of  living. 

In  the  second  place,  enhancement,  on  the  ground  of  rise 
in  prices,  was  also  to  be  limited  to  fifteen  per  cent,  on 
the  former  rate. 

For  the  purpose  of  calculating  prices,  years  of  scarcity 
•were  to  be  eliminated,  for  prices  are  then  abnormal.  Certain 
staples  and  certain  market  localities,  it  was  suggested, 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-BE  VENUE  ADHINISTEATION.  36 1 

might  be  taken  for  the  purposes  of  calculation,  and 
the  prices  of,  say,  the  decade  before  the  current  Settle- 
ment, should  be  compared  with  those  of  the  concluding 
decade. 

(2)  In  order  to  give   landowners   immediate   assurance 
of  their  future  position,  an   assessment  should,  except   in 
backward  districts,  be  declared  for  each  estate  as  soon  as 
possible,  which  the  Resolution  called  the    'initial  assess- 
ment/ which  should  not  be  altered  when  the  re-settlement 
began,  except  on  one  or  more  of  the  above  grounds. 

This  point  has,  however  (in  particular)  been  given  up,  as 
it  was  found  impracticable. 

(3)  That  measures  should  be  taken  to  secure  to  tenants 
the   same  protection   against   enhancement  of  their  rents, 
as    would    be    offered    to    landlords     in    respect    of    the 
revenue. 

These  proposals  were  generally  and  in  principle  agreed 
to  by  the  Governments  of  Madras  and  Bombay.  In  the 
North -Western  Provinces,  however,  they  met  with  elaborate 
criticism;  and  the  Secretary  of  State  1,  while  approving  the 
general  object  of  the  Resolution,  also  felt  doubts  about  the 
details. 

The  arguments  about  the  inequality  of  the  incidence 
of  the  re  venue- demand  under  existing  Settlements,  and 
therefore  the  difficulty  of  fixing  an  'initial  assessment,' 
may  be  passed  over,  as  this  portion  of  the  scheme  stands 
abandoned. 

The  principal  objection  in  the  North -Western  Provinces, 
was  on  the  question  of  enhancing  solely  with  reference 
to  rise  in  prices.  It  must  be  admitted  at  once  that  the 
application  of  the  principle  of  a  rise  in  prices  is  easier 
in  a  raiyaticdri  province,  or  in  the  Panjab,  where  the 
revenue  approximates  more  to  a  money  sum  representing 
a  share  in  the  produce  obtained  by  the  cultivating  pro- 
prietor. But  in  the  North -Western  Provinces  the  land 
is  cultivated  by  cash-paying  tenants,  and  the  revenue  is 
now  a  certain  share  of  the  rental ;  and  the  objection  was 

1  No.  24,  dated  sand  March,  1883. 


362  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

stated  that  in  the  North -Western  Provinces  'prices  do  not 
affect  rents  immediately  or  otherwise  than  at  long  in- 
tervals.' Under  any  circumstances,  the  prices  looked  to 
should  be  prices  at  the  pargana  capital,  where  produce  is 
sold  by  agriculturists ;  and  harvest  prices,  not  averages 
of  other  months,  should  be  taken.  It  was  also  urged  that 
rises  in  prices  could  not  be  counted  on  as  permanent,  and 
that  if  they  fell  naturally  after  a  revision  made  on  the 
strength  of  what  appeared  at  the  time,  there  would  be 
no  remedy  but  to  resort  to  remissions  of  the  revenue,  which 
would  be  unsatisfactory. 

There  were  minor  objections,  such  as  that  the  system 
would  benefit  different  tracts  unevenly,  and  that  in  con- 
sequence of  the  varying  proportion  of  staples  in  different 
tracts,  there  would  be  some  difficulty  in  adjusting  any 
calculation  of  what  the  rise  in  prices  was,  which  would 
be  fair  to  all.  The  Government  of  India  admitted  that 
any  rise  in  prices  counted  on  ought  to  be  widespread ;  that 
it  was  not  to  be  one  affecting  small  areas  but  whole 
provinces,  while  it  would  be  easy  to  allow  for  an  additional 
demand  on  any  particular  district  or  tract  where  a  new 
railway  or  canal  had  produced  a  durable  and  marked  local 
effect  on  prices.  It  was  also  admitted  that  the  difficulty 
about  existing  rents  not  following  prices,  was  a  serious  one; 
but  reference  was  made  to  a  possible  change  in  the  tenant 
law,  by  which  enhancements  would  necessarily  be  brought 
about  almost  wholly  with  reference  to  prices ;  and  if  so, 
revenue  enhancement  would  follow  the  same  rule T. 


1  Briefly,  I  may  explain  that  in  is,  by  competition,  paying  more  than 

the    North- West    Provinces,    occu-  the  '  prevailing  '  rates,  as  above  ex- 

pancy-tenants'  rents  are  in  practice  plained.     But  should   the    law   be 

enhanced  only  on  the  first  of  the  changed  to  allow  all  tenants  having 

grounds  allowed  by  the  law  (Section  held   any  land   in  the  village   for 

13,  Act  XII  of  1881)  ;  i.  e.  they  are  twelve  years,  to   claim  occupancy, 

enhanced   up   to   the   '  prevailing '  then   the    majority  would  become 

rate,  which,  in  effect,  is  the  rate  occupancy-tenants,    of    whom    the 

assumed  as  fair  by  the  Settlement  older    ones    would    soon     become 

Officer   in  his  calculations.     Occu-  equalised  as  to  rates,  and  the  new 

pancy-tenants  must  now  have  held  ones  would  be  already  paying  above 

the  same   land   in    the  village  for  these  rates  ;  so  that  the  application 

twelve  years,  therefore  they  are  a  for  enhancement    on   the    ground 

minority;  and  the  ordinary  tenant  that  the  'tenant  was  paying  below 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-RE  VENUE  ADMINISTEATION.  363 

It  is  unnecessary  to  go  into  the  subject  further,  as  there 
is  no  present  prospect  of  the  tenant  law  of  the  North- 
Western  Provinces  being  altered  so  as  largely  to  increase 
the  number  of  occupancy-tenants. 

§3.    The  present  state  of  the  question. 

In  a  despatch  of  i6th  August,  1884  (No.  16),  the  Govern- 
ment of  India  reviewed  the  objections  of  the  North- Western 
Provinces,  and  informed  the  Secretary  of  State  that  they 
had  abandoned  the  plan  of  framing  initial  revenue  assess- 
ments, and  they  continued  : — 

1  We  shall  have  no  objection  in  the  more  recently  assessed 
districts,  to  the  entire  exclusion  of  new  land  from  assessment 
on  any  estate  in  which  the  increase  could  be  proved  to  be  below 
a  certain  percentage.  We  would  divide  districts,  not  estates, 
into  two  classes  : 

'  (i)  those  in  which  the  revenue  is  fairly  adequate,  which 
would   include   the   majority  of  districts  assessed 
within  the  last  twenty  years  ;  and 
'  (2)  those  earlier  assessed  districts  in  which  rentals  have 

considerably  outgrown  the  revenue. 

'  The  latter  should  be  re-assessed  according  to  the  method 
proposed  by  Sir  A.  Lyall  (Lieutenant- Governor  of  the  North- 
Western  Provinces)  [i.  e.  the  latest  Settlement  rules  under 
which  the  actual  rent-rolls,  corrected  only  to  supply  positive 
errors,  and  to  give  rents  for  non-rented  land  liable  to  assess- 
ment, without  prospective  and  calculated  additions,  are  made 
use  of].  The  former  (should  be  re-assessed)  on  the  principles 
stated  in  our  first  despatch,  subject  to  the  modifications  now 
suggested ;  one  of  the  conditions  would  be  the  fifteen  per  cent, 
maximum  (enhancement).  The  rise  in  prices  would  be  deter- 
mined primarily  by  a  consideration  of  the  prices  in  the  whole 
province,  subject,  perhaps,  to  a  further  scrutiny  in  particular 
districts  of  the  effect  on  them  of  improved  communications. ' 

The  Secretary  of  State  replied  in  a  despatch  (No.  4, 
Revenue)  of  8th  January,  1885.  It  was  observed  generally 

the  "  prevailing  rate "  for  other  then  the  second  ground  allowed  by 
tenants  of  the  same  class,'  &c.,  the  tenant  law — rise  in  prices- — 
would  cease  to  be  operative,  and  would  be  the  chief  one. 


364  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

that  some  of  the  objections  to  the  original  scheme  were 
admitted,  and  that  others  depended  for  their  removal  on 
an  alteration  of  the  tenant  law,  which  was  not  regarded 
as  practicable ;  but  that  much  remained  which  might  be 
usefully  carried  into  practice.  As  the  despatch  gives  the 
final  orders  on  the  subject,  I  may  now  sum  up  both  the 
discussions  which  I  have  been  describing,  and  the  general 
subject  of  the  latest  rules  for  the  simplification  of  the 
procedure  in  the  re-settlements,  by  giving  the  actual  prin- 
ciples sanctioned : — 

(1)  The   permanent   Settlement   idea  is  formally  aban- 

doned ; 

(2)  the    State   shall   still   retain   its   claim  to  share   in 

'  the  unearned  increment '  of  the  value  of  land 
to  which  there  is  a  tendency  in  a  progressive 
country ; 

(3)  that  a  general  and  permanent  rise  in  the  prices  of 

produce  is  one  of  the  principal  indications  and 
measures  of  this  increment ; 

(4)  that    it    is    nevertheless    desirable    to    modify   the 

existing  system  of  revision  of  the  temporary  settle- 
ments of  land-revenue  with  a  view  of  rendering 
it  less  arbitrary,  uncertain,  and  troublesome  to  the 
people ; 

(5)  that  the  modification  should  be  effected  at  least  in 

the  following  particulars  : — 

(a)  repetition  of  field  operations  (survey,  valuation,  mi- 
nute inquiries  into  assets,  and  the  like)  which  are 
considered  to  be  inquisitorial  and  harassing  to  the 
people,  should  be,  as  far  as  possible,  dispensed 
with ; 

(6)  enhancement  should  be  based  mainly  on  considera- 
tions of  general  increase  in  the  value  of  land ; 

(c)  the  assessment  will  not  be  revised  merely  with  a 

view  to  equalizing  its  incidence  with  that  of  the 
assessment  of  other  estates ; 

(d)  improvements  made  by  the  land-holders  themselves 

should  not  be  taken  into  account  in  revising  as- 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-EE  VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  365 

sessments  ;  but  improvements  made  at  the  cost  of 
the  State  should  be  taken  into  account,  and  also, 
to  some  extent,  increase  of  cultivation. 

As  regards  more  detailed  rules,  the  Secretary  of  State 
observed : — 

'  It  is  not  desirable  that  I  should  attempt  to  lay  down,  for 
the  guidance  of  the  Local  Governments,  rules  for  the  revision 
of  Settlements.  But  I  may  state  the  general  principles  upon 
which,  in  my  opinion,  such  operations  should  be  conducted, 
subject  to  the  conditions  specified '  [viz.  the  Nos.  i  to  5  above 
given]. 

'  All  tracts  (whether  whole  districts  or  parts)  which  were  in 
a  backward  condition  [when  the  existing  assessments  were 
framed,  and  where  the  subsequent  process  of  development  has 
produced  inequalities  so  great  and  numerous  as  to  make  the 
application  of  any  general  uniform  rate  of  enhancement  un- 
advisable  and  unfair1]  will  be  excluded  from  the  scheme, 
because  the  present  assessment  would  evidently  afford  no 
proper  basis  for  the  future  assessment.  These  tracts  must  be 
left  for  regular  [re-]  settlement. 

'  As  regards  other  localities,  when  a  Settlement  is  about  to 
expire,  a  summary  inquiry  should  be  made  into  the  condition 
and  resources  of  the  tract  .  .  .  and  upon  the  results  of  this 
inquiry  the  Local  Government,  with  the  approval  of  the 
Government  of  India,  should  determine  the  general  rate  of 
enhancement  to  be  applied  to  the  tract.  The  factors  to  be 
taken  into  consideration  would  be,  general  rise  in  agricultural 
prices,  in  actual  rentals,  and  in  letting-value  and  sale-price  of 
land  ;  and  care  would,  of  course,  be  taken,  that  the  increment 
determined  on  should  be  such  as  would  not  unduly  raise  the 
revenue,  certainly  not  in  any  case  beyond  fifty  per  cent,  of  the 
"apparent  assets  "  [i.  e.  the  assets  obtained  by  consideration  of  the 
factors  above  mentioned,  of  which  the  '  actual  rental '  was  the 
amount  which  the  assessing  officer,  on  a  consideration  of  the 
estate  or  tract,  was  led  to  consider  the  proper  actual  rental 2]. 

1  This  explanation  was  approved  rental '  does  not  include,  be  it  re- 
by  the  Secretary  of  State  in  a  later  membered,  any  prospective  rise  in 
despatch.  rent  or  (in  this  class  of  estate)  any 

2  The   term   in   the   despatch   is  increase  in  the  cultivated  area  (Re- 
'  apparent   assets  '   which   was   ex-  venue  Despatch,  Secretary  of  State, 
plained  to  mean  what  I  have  put  No.  65,  dated  soth  July,  1885). 

in    brackets  ;    the  proper    '  actual 


366  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

'There  is  no  necessity  for  determining  beforehand  what 
shall  constitute  the  unit  of  area  ...  to  which  the  same  rate 
of  increment  will  apply.  That  must  depend  on  local  condi- 
tions. It  might  be  a  whole  district,  or,  when  the  conditions  of 
progress  vary,  different  sections  of  it.  Within  that  area,  the 
rate  of  increment,  as  determined  by  the  Local  Government, 
would,  as  a  rule,  be  applied  by  the  Settlement  officer  rateably 
all  round.  But  it  should  be  in  his  discretion  to  treat  special 
cases  exceptionally.  There  may  be  tracts,  or  groups  of  estates, 
to  which  a  rate  higher  than  the  average  rate  should  be  applied, 
— such,  for  example,  as  have  benefited  by  improvements  made 
at  the  expense  of  Government,  or  where  there  has  been  an 
unusual  increase  of  cultivation  or  rise  of  rental.  There  may 
very  probably,  on  the  other  hand,  be  estates  in  which,  from 
over-assessment  or  other  cause,  it  may  not  be  expedient  to  take 
the  whole  increase,  or  any  part  of  it,  or  in  which  possibly  even 
a  reduction  of  the  existing  demand  may  be  expedient.  And 
objecting  proprietors  might  have  the  option  ...  of  a  regular 
revision.' 

The  practice  now  is,  under  these  orders,  to  draw  up  a 
programme  of  Settlement  work  with  reference  to  super- 
vision of  survey  operations  and  other  considerations ;  and 
the  Government  lays  down  instructions  for  the  Settlement 
of  each  district1. 

1  For  example,   I   may   abstract  held  by  tenants  of  this  class  and 

the  '  Jalaun '  district   instructions  that  ;  what  is  to  be  done  when  a 

(December,  1884)  in  a  few  words:—  particular  village  has  a  fraudulent 

1.  No  new  survey  or  soil-classi-  or  wholly  inaccurate  rent-roll.    Ob- 
fication  or  records  (except  in  seven-  servations  are  added  about  fraud- 
teen  villages  for  special  reasons).  ulently  inadequate  rates  as  distin- 

2.  Revision   to  be   an  actual  re-  guished    from     those     allowed    at 
corded  rent-roll  corrected  (i)  to  put  favourable     rates     on      customary 
a    rent    on    '  sir '  ;  r  (2)   to    correct  grounds  ;    and   about   determining 
fraudulent  concealments   of  rent ;  the  area  that  is  really  '  sir.'     The 
(3)  correct  rent  for  fields  held  rent-  question  of '  imposing  fixed  maxima 
free  or  at  '  manifestly  inadequate '  of  enhancement '  is  reserved, 
rents.     The    actual    rentals  to    be  The   Government  of  the  North- 
average   of  six  years   (from  1878-  Western  Provinces  have  also  issued 
1883-4).     Instructions  go  on  to  ex-  general  rules  for  assessment  (under 
plain  how  the  rent-rolls  should  be  Act  XIX  of  i873\  which  I  have 
verified,   and   it  should  be   tested  spoken  of  in  detail  in  the  chapters 
what  area  really  is  '  sir/  and  what  on  the  North-Western  Provinces. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-BE  VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  367 

§  4.   Instalments  of  Land-Revenue. 

Another  subject  of  consideration  has  been  the  fixing  of 
the  most  convenient  dates  for  the  payment  of  the  Govern- 
ment revenue.  This  payment  could  not  be  conveniently 
made  in  one  sum  for  the  year,  nor  on  any  purely  calendar 
arrangement  of  quarter-days,  &c.  In  some  Settlements  it 
is  expressly  provided  that  it  shall  be  paid  in  a  certain  way. 
It  is  obvious  that  this  matter  requires  attention,  and  that 
the  power  of  the  people  to  pay  without  difficulty,  largely 
depends  on  the  suitableness  of  the  time  of  demand. 

In  places  where  the  revenue-payers  are  landlords  or 
employers  of  tenants,  their  power  of  payment  depends  on 
their  first  having  time  to  collect  their  rents.  And  in  its 
turn  this  depends  on  the  power  of  the  cultivators  to  find 
the  money  for  the  rents.  Rent,  again,  cannot  be  paid  till 
the  harvest  is  realized ;  and  this  condition  applies  also  to 
the  raiyat,  who  pays  revenue  direct  to  the  State,  and  to 
the  petty  cultivating  proprietor  who  does  the  same,  in- 
directly. 

Here  there  are  usually  two  harvests  to  be  considered ; 
some  pay  most  of  their  revenue  from  the  '  rabi,'  or  spring 
harvest ;  others,  from  the  autumn,  or  '  kharif '  ;  others 
part  from  both.  If  a  principal  part  is  demanded  when  the 
harvest  relied  on  is  not  yet  got  in,  the  payer  must  borrow 
the  money  at  high  interest ;  and  though,  when  the  produce 
is  presently  sold,  he  may  pay  back  to  the  money-lender  a 
portion  of  the  debt,  he  will  not  be  able  to  repay  the  whole. 
If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  date  for  payment  is  so  fixed  that 
the  cultivator  has  got  in  his  money  by  sale  of  his  produce, 
and  yet  the  village  headman  will  not  receive  it,  he  is  very 
likely  to  spend  this  sum,  or  lose  it  in  some  way,  before  the 
time  comes  for  the  revenue  payment J. 

1  In  a  very  able  paper  on  Instal-  system  that  by  concentrating  the 

ments  in  Berar,  Mr.  W.  B.  Jones  payments  of  land-revenue  on  one 

mentions  the  difficulty  of  getting  or  two  dates  it  adds  enormoiisly  to 

into  the  districts  the  requisite  the  difficulties  of  the  cultivator, 

amount  of  silver  money  to  pay  the  For  a  small  province  like  Berar  to 

revenue  : —  pay  thirty  lakhs  of  silver  rupees 

'  It    is    the  weak   point   in   our  into  the  treasury  on  the  isth  Janu- 


368  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

On  this  important  subject  the  Government  of  India 
issued  a  Resolution  (No.  15  R.,  dated  3rd  May,  1882). 

The  leading  idea  is  to  establish  a  '  normal  proportion 
between  the  amount  of  revenue  collected  and  the  amount 
of  produce  gathered  at  harvest'  —  to  establish  a  closer 
connection  between  current  liabilities  and  current  assets  1. 
And  it  is  not  only  for  whole  districts  that  this  has  to  be 
seen  to  ;  agricultural  circumstances  vary  within  much  more 
limited  tracts.  '  Attention  has  lately  been  drawn  to  the 
case  of  three  adjacent  villages,  in  one  of  which  the  cash  of 
the  agricultural  community  is  principally  obtained  from 
rice  at  the  end  of  the  rainy  season;  in  the  second,  from 
a  sugar-harvest  in  January  ;  in  the  third,  from  cereals  in 
spring.  Yet  for  all  these  villages  the  same  dates  were 
fixed  for  the  payment  of  rent  and  revenue.'  Attention 
was  also  drawn  to  the  matter  I  have  alluded  to  in  a  foot- 
note :  '  The  sudden  demand  for  large  quantities  of  silver 
money  on  certain  dates,  causes  prices  to  fall  (because 
of  the  withdrawal  of  silver)  while  the  rate  of  interest  rises  ; 
grain  has  to  be  thrown  into  a  slackened  market,  and  loans 
must  be  negotiated  on  usurious  terms.' 

The  result  has  been  to  call  for  an  inquiry  in  each  pro- 
vince as  to  the  practice.  The  North  -Western  Provinces 
Government  has  issued  rules  on  the  subject. 


ary,  and  thirty  lakhs  on  the  isth  mark    (Report,   Part   II,   Chap,   iii, 

March,   is   a   stupendous   financial  Sec.  3.  §  2)  :  — 

operation  —  an      operation      which  '  Where  one  crop   is  mostly  re- 

causes  violent   fluctuations  in   the  served  for  food,  and  another  mostly 

price  of  produce  —  fluctuations  which  sold,  if  the   circumstances   of  the 

give  the   baniya   (grain-dealer  and  people  require  it,  larger  instalments 

money-lender)     his    opportunities.  should  be  made  payable  upon  the 

If  we   could  but  make  these  vast  crop  which  is  raised  for  the  market, 

sums  flow  into  the  treasury  in  equal  and  smaller  instalments  upon  that 

monthly  amounts,  the  benefit  to  the  which  is  raised  for  food.    The  dates 

cultivating  classes  would  be  great  for  payment  should  also  be  fixed  so 

indeed.     For  they  would  then  be  as  to   allow  of  the  produce  being 

able  to  raise  the  loans  they  require  harvested  and  sold  before  the  in- 

to pay  the  revenue  at  the  true  mar-  stalment  is  collected,  so  as  to  avoid 

ket  rate.     As  things  now  are,  the  the    losses   which    the   landowner 

enormous     demand     which     takes  would  suffer  if  he  were  compelled 

place  all  at  once,  enables,  I  might  to  raise  money  on  an  unripe  crop, 

almost  say  compels,  the  baniya  to  or  sell  it  hastily  in  an  overstocked 

ask  exorbitant  interest.'  market.' 
1  The  Famine  Commissioners  re- 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  369 


SECTION  XIV. — REMISSION  AND  SUSPENSION  OF 
LAND-REVENUE. 

§  i.  Suspension — when  sufficient,  and  when  not. 

Another  subject  of  great  importance  is  the  granting 
of  relief  when  a  bad  year,  or  a  succession  of  bad  years, 
occurs. 

Ordinarily,  the  revenue  is  calculated  at  rates  which  are 
fair  for  the  average  of  years,  good  and  bad  together  ;  so  that, 
speaking  generally,  if  one  crop  fails  outright,  but  the  next  is 
good,  the  cultivator  ought  to  be  sufficiently  relieved  by  the 
suspension  of  the  demand  for  the  instalment  of  one  crop, 
payment  being  demanded  only  on  the  occurrence  of  the 
second  of  two  successive  good  harvests.  But  sometimes 
there  comes  a  more  serious  calamity,  and  suspended  revenue 
has  to  be  remitted  altogether.  This  causes  disturbance  in 
the  estimates,  which  is  often  embarrassing. 

§  2.    General  considerations. 

The  principle  of  the  Native  governments,  which  cared 
nothing  about  estimates  and  financial  equilibrium,  was 
always  to  be  elastic  ;  they  ran  up  the  nominal  revenue  to  a 
high  figure,  which  they  perhaps  rarely  exacted  to  the  full. 
But,  from  the  first,  our  system  has  been  to  fix  a  very 
moderate  revenue,  and  demand  an  exact  payment ;  failing 
this,  in  Bengal,  the  sale  of  the  estate  is  at  once  ordered,  and 
in  other  provinces,  various  coercive  measures. 

Fortunately  the  progress  of  the  country  has  been  such, 
that  the  land-revenue  is  collected  with  remarkable  facility, 
and  the  issue  of  coercive  processes  is  mostly  confined  to  the 
minor  forms — mere  notices  or  threats  to  the  careless,  rather 
than  serious  action  against  defaulters ;  but  still  there  is  a 
rigidity  about  our  system  that,  whatever  its  justification, 
is  not  always  acceptable  to  the  Oriental  mind *. 

1  The  following  remarks  in   the  '  Our  system  of  Settlement  and 

BANDA  Settlement  Report  (p.  150)       land-revenue  collection  is  logically 
by  Mr.  A.  Cadell  struck  me  : —  a   good   one,   and    is    theoretically 

VOL.  I.  B  b 


370  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

There  is  also  much  difficulty  in  dealing  with  districts — 
of  which  Gurgaon  in  the  Panjab  occurs  to  me  as  an  example 
— where,  sometimes  for  three  or  four  years  together,  if  there 
is  a  sufficient  rainfall,  the  qualities  of  the  prevalent  soils 
are  such,  that  excellent,  and  more  than  excellent,  crops  are 
obtained.  Then  come  a  series  of  bad  years :  the  rain  fails, 
and  lands  that  were  before  fertilized  by  a  deposit  of  soil 
washed  down  from  the  low  hills  (dahri),  are  left  untilled  :  or 
again,  if  rain  is  in  irregular  excess,  they  may  be  over-flooded 
and  water-logged.  Unless  we  adopt  variable  or  fluctuating 
rates,  any  fixed  assessment  can  hardly  work.  If  it  is 
very  low,  it  will  sacrifice  revenue  needlessly  in  good  years ; 
and  in  bad  years,  even  then  it  will  not  be  easily,  if  at  all,  paid. 
It  seems  hardly  possible  to  manage  such  areas,  except  on 
the  plan  of  allowing  the  Collector  a  power  of  immediate 
action  in  bad  years.  In  this  matter,  we  should  take  a 
lesson  from  the  best  Native  governments.  It  will  be  seen 
that  their  principle  was  always  to  keep  up  the  assessment 
pretty  high,  but  allow  of  an  immediately-acting  and 
thoroughly  elastic  system  of  easing  off  in  bad  years.  Our 
system,  it  is  true,  tends  to  make  the  land-revenue  par- 
take, somewhat,  of  the  nature  of  a  tax ;  and  rigidity  and 
certainty  are  the  necessary  features  of  a  proper  tax- 
administration:  they  have  their  advantage  in  compelling 
thrift  and  habits  of  forethought.  But  land-revenue  is 
not  wholly  a  tax,  and  cannot  be  effectively  treated  wholly 
on  the  principles  of  one. 

just  and  fair ;  we  fix  a  demand  to  collect  a  revenue,  in  itself  not 
based  neither  on  the  abundance  of  excessive,  through  good  years  and 
good  seasons  nor  on  the  poverty  of  through  bad,  has  been  the  great 
bad  ;  we  argue  that  the  proprietor  motive  of  the  irregularities  which 
who  gets  more  than  his  due  in  in  Bundelkhand,  more  than  else- 
bumper  seasons  can  afford  to  pay  where,  have  disgraced  our  adminis- 
more  than  his  half  share  of  the  tration.  Theorists  may  argue  that 
rental  in  unfavourable  years.  But,  if  men  do  not  put  by  money  in 
unhappily,  it  is  as  true  now  as  it  good  seasons  they  deserve  no  mercy; 
was  sixty  years  ago  when  Mr.  Holt  but  the  same  argument  pushed  a 
Mackenzie  made  the  remark,  that  little  further  would  condemn  the 
"  men,  especially  men  so  improvi-  improvident  to  death  as  well  as 
dent  as  the  natives  of  India,  do  not  ruin,  when  the  next  period  of  scar- 
live  by  averages  "  ;  and  the  attempt  city  arrives.' 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE  ADMINISTEATION.    371 

§  3.    Government  orders  on  the  subject. 

The  Government  of  India's  Resolution  issued  on  the 
subject  in  October,  1882,  was  intended  to  indicate  the  lines 
of  a  policy  rather  than  issue  hard-and-fast  orders.  It 
suggested  that,  in  order  to  enable  the  Government  officers 
to  know  how  to  act,  and  in  order  to  systematize  know- 
ledge, five  principal  measures  should  be  taken  in  hand  : — 

(1)  the  classification  of  agricultural  land  according  to  the 

security  or  insecurity  of  its  yield  ; 

(2)  the  adaptation  of  the  system  to  the  character  of  each 

class ; 

(3)  the  extension  of  relief  granted  to  landlords,  to  the 

tenant  class  also  ; 

(4)  an  investigation  into  the  outturn  of  every  harvest ; 

(5)  the   making  more    definite    the   authority   of    local 

officers  to  act  at  once. 

It  was  suggested  that  estates  (and  even  parts  of  estates 
might  require  to  be  noted  in  this  respect)  should  be  classi- 
fied into  those  (i)  which  are,  to  a  great  extent,  secure 
against  failure  of  crops,  by  having  a  fair  proportion  of 
their  area  irrigated ;  (2)  those  in  which,  in  abnormal  sea- 
sons, suspensions,  or  ultimately  remissions,  are  likely  to  be 
needed  (called  insecure  areas) ;  (3)  areas  in  which  cultiva- 
tion is  so  uncertain  in  its  result  as  to  render  an  annual 
adjustment  requisite  :  these  may  be  termed  '  fluctuating 
areas.' 

As  to  the  first  and  fourth  measures  noted  above,  it  is 
sufficient  to  remark  that  the  improved  land  records  and 
statistics,  subject  as  they  are  to  constant  inspection  and 
testing,  ought  in  time  to  secure  good  results,  whether  in 
the  form  of  village  and  pargana  note-books,  containing  an 
account  of  each  estate,  or  in  the  form  of  specially-coloured 
maps  and  tabulated  lists  of  villages  and  estates, — as  provin- 
cial circumstances  may  suggest.  The  second  head  indicates 
that  in  '  secure '  estates,  suspensions  or  remissions  would  only 
become  necessary  in  the  rare  case  of  some  special  plague 
of  locusts,  hail,  or  other  calamity.  '  Insecure  '  areas  would 

B  b  2 


3/2  .      LAND   SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH   INDIA.          [CHAP.  v. 

require  a  ready  power  of  suspension,  which  has  to  be 
systematized  by  indicating  the  duty  of  the  District  Officer 
and  the  Commissioner,  and  their  respective  powers  to  act 
on  their  own  authority ;  defining  the  cases  in  which  refer- 
ence to  the  chief  controlling  authority  and  to  Government 
is  requisite 1. 

Whether  suspension  is  temporarily  granted,  or  is  more 
formally  sanctioned  for  a  definite  period  under  orders  of 
higher  authority,  the  ultimate  grant  of  remission  depends 
on  the  orders  of  Government ;  and  where  the  remission 
aggregates  ten  per  cent,  of  the  entire  land-revenue  of  the 
province,  the  previous  sanction  of  the  Government  of  India 
is  required. 

§  4.    Fluctuating  Assessments. 

The  plans  for  '  fluctuating  assessment '  vary  according 
to  circumstances.  In  principle  they  proceed  more  or  less 
on  the  lines  of  assessing  at  fixed  average  rates  (for  different 
qualities  of  soil),  and  charging  those  rates  only  when, 
after  the  crop  is  or  ought  to  be  mature,  it  is  known  what 
acreage  was  actually  productive.  An  account  of  a  special 
'  fluctuating  system/  applied  in  the  recent  Settlement,  will 
be  found  in  the  chapter  on  Ajmer-Merwara. 

In  several  parts  of  the  Panjab,  including  riverain 
villages  liable  to  violent  and  extensive  changes  by  river 
action,  as  well  as  tracts  liable  to  flood  or  where  the  rainfall 
is  extremely  small  and  uncertain,  fluctuating  assessments 
are  also  employed.  Speaking  generally,  the  basis  of  the 
method  is,  to  fix  certain  differential  rates  for  classes  of 
land  bearing  crops,  which  rates  are  levied  on  an  annual 
(or  a  harvest)  measurement  of  the  land  which  actually  bore 
a  crop.  Partial  failure  in  the  yield  is  allowed  for  by 
deduction  in  the  total.  Newly  cultivated  land  is  always 

1  A  certain  graduated  scale  of  which  Collectors  and  other  officers 
powers,  according  to  the  greater  or  can  act  in  the  North -Western  Pro- 
less  fraction  of  the  crop  lost,  was  vinces  are  stated  in  the  special 
suggested,  but  is  too  much  in  detail  chapter  on  Administrative  busi- 
to  be  practised.  The  rules  under  ness. 


CHAP,  v.]  VIEW  OP  THE  LAND-EE VENUE  ADMINISTRATION.  373 

allowed  a  reduction  for  the  first  year  or  two.  In  some 
cases,  besides  the  fluctuating  rate,  a  small  fixed  acreage 
rate  is  levied  on  account  of  the  value  which  the  land  has 
as  waste  or  grazing  ground  even  when  not  cultivated. 

§  5.   Relief  to  Tenants. 

As  regards  the  benefit  of  revenue  relief  granted  to  land- 
lords being  passed  on  to  tenants,  that  is  a  matter  which  is 
provided  for  in  some  of  the  Tenant  Acts  1,  and  is  then  a 
question  of  law ;  otherwise  it  may  be  a  matter  of  conditions 
annexed  to  the  grant  of  the  relief. 

It  may  be  added  that  the  Secretary  of  State  has  decided 
against  the  principle  of  charging  interest  on  revenue  dues 
suspended. 


SECTION  XV. — CONCLUSION. 

Conspectus  of  the  Systems. 

I  conclude  this  introductory  and  general  sketch,  first 
with  a  diagram  which  will  recall  the  chief  features  of  the 
development  of  our  revenue  systems,  and  next  with  a  table 
taken  from  the  Government  of  India's  printed  '  Statistical 
Returns,  1886-87,'  which  will  give  some  idea  of  the  general 
effect  and  results  of  land-revenue  Settlements. 

As  an  appendix  to  the  chapter,  I  also  reproduce  an 
able  and  instructive  resume  of  the  financial  aspects  of 
Settlement  work  contained  in  the  Honourable  J.  Westland's 
Budget  Note  for  1888-892. 

1  See,    for  example,    Section    23,  it  is  customary  to  print  not  '  Ru- 
Act  XII  of  1881  ;  Act  IX  of  1883,  pees  '  but  '  Rx,'  i.  e.  ten  rupees,  and 
Sections  65  and  73.  then  to  omit  three  cyphers.     So  the 

2  I  may  remind  the  reader  that,  Rx  27  means  2,70,000  rupees, 
to  save  useless  printing  of  figures, 


374 


LAND    SYSTEMS   OF    BEITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 


(A.)— SETTLEMENT  WITH 
LANDLORDS,  OR  JOINT- 
BODIES. 

The  Bengal  system  of 
1790—93  (seeks  to  de- 
clare some  person  to 
be  landlord  or  pro- 
prietor, and  secure 
his  position,  between 
the  cultivator  and  the 
State). 


Permanent  Settlement  with 
Zamindars  as  propri- 
etors, (1793,)  with  no 
survey,  no  record  of 
rights,  and  no  de- 
fined method  of  as- 
sessment. 


Improved  system  of 
Regulation  VII  of 
1822  and  Regulation 
IX  of  1833 ;  non-per- 
manent Settlements 
with  survey  and  re- 
cord of  rights  and 
prescribed  method  of 
assessment. 


Settlement  with 
proprietary  joint 

communities, 
through   a   re- 
presentative ; 
North  -  "West- 
ern Provinces : 
the  Panj&b 
and  Ajmer. 


Settlement  Settlement  with 
with  Taluq-  mdlguzdrs  over 
ddrs  over  the  individual 
the  com-  occupants  of  vil- 
munities  ;  lages  ;  Central 
Oudh.  Provinces.  Te- 

nants' rents 
fixed  as  well  as 
the  proprietor's 
revenue  pay- 
ments by  the 
Settlement-of- 
ficer. 


( B. ") — SETTLEMENT 
WITH  RAIYATS  OR  INDI- 
VIDUAL OCCUPANTS. 

The  Bengal  system 
first  applied  to  Ma- 
dras, but  afterwards 
prohibited ;  still  sur- 
vives as  regards  some 
of  the  estates.  At- 
tempts in  some  dis- 
tricts to  make  joint- 
village  Settlements. 

I 

Madras  Raiyatwari 
system  (1820) ;  occu- 
pants regarded  as 
proprietors.  Settle- 
ment for  thirty 
years ;  uniform  sys- 
tem of  assessment 
with  annual  remis- 
sions. Re-settlements 
confined  by  rule  to 
alterations  resulting 
from  a  rise  in  prices 
— no  general  Revenue 
Code. 

I 

Bombay  Raiyatwari 
system  of  field  assess- 
ment ;  no  theory  of 
ownership ;  occupant 
has  right  defined  by 
law.  Settlement  for 
thirty  years  only : 
system  of  assessment 
uniform  and  defined 
by  rules.  A  complete 
Revenue  Code  en- 
acted. 

I 

Other  systems,  in 
principle  Raiyatwari 
(no  middleman)  of 
Assam,  Burma, 
Coorg,  &c. 


APPENDIX. 


Extract  from  the  Supplement  to  the  Gazette  of  India 

(March  $\st,   1888.) 

'Land-Revenue  during  the  twelve  months  ending  September 


(In  thousands  of  Ex.) 

1881. 

1882. 

1883. 

1884. 

1885. 

1886. 

1887. 

India 

99 

9i 

88 

96 

no 

no 

116 

Central  Provinces  . 

608 

609 

612 

613 

613 

615 

619 

Burma  . 
Upper  Burma 

1,036 

i,  060 

1,099 

1,166 

M33 

i,i37 
39 

1,222 
235 

Assam  . 

385 

379 

396 

404 

410 

420 

401 

Bengal  . 

3;687 

3,880 

3,801 

3,680 

39r5 

3,799 

3,736 

North-Western  Pro- 
vinces and  Oudh. 

5.653 

5,848 

5,782 

5,769 

5,8o9 

5,784 

5798 

Panjab  . 

2,112 

2  099 

2075 

2,058 

2..  1  53 

2,157 

2,146 

Madras  . 

4,777 

4,556 

4,721 

4,779 

4,492 

4,807 

4,864 

Bombay 

3,H9 

3,095 

3>o8s 

3,407 

33*6 

3,342 

3,373 

TOTAL     . 

21,476 

2I,6l7 

21,657 

21,972 

2i,95* 

22,210 

22  510 

See  Note     . 

665 

694 

677 

676 

734 

811 

880 

The  figures  in  the  lowest  line  are  the  alienated  Land-Revenue  of  Bombay,  which,  in  the 
system  of  accounts  of  that  province,  are  added  on  the  Revenue  side,  and  charged  again  as 
expenditure  under  Assignments,  Land-Kevenue,  and  Police.  The  amounts  are  neglected  in 
the  statement  itself. 

It  will  be  remembered  that  a  portion  of  the  total  receipts  of  Land-Revenue  is  in  the 
accounts  shown  under  the  separate  head  of  irrigation. 

'  33.  Although  the  growth  of  revenue  shown  in  the  above 
figures  has  been  very  steady,  it  can  hardly,  from  a  financial 
point  of  view,  be  said  to  be  satisfactory  in  amount.  It  has 
been  less  than  one  per  cent,  a  year,  and  is  on  the  whole  a  poor 
return  for  the  money  which  Government  has  spent,  in  the 
form  of  railways  and  of  canals,  in  improving  its  estate. 

'  But  the  fact  is  that  the  period  covered  by  the  above  state- 


376  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

ment  represents,  in  a  general  way,  the  close  of  the  thirty  years' 
Settlements  in  several  of  the  provinces,  and  the  Government  is 
only  now  beginning  to  reap  its  share  in  the  advance  of  the  past 
two  or  three  decades.  Settlement  operations  are  at  present 
being  carried  on  on  a  more  extensive  scale  than  at  any  previous 
time,  and  we  have  every  reason  to  expect  a  handsome  increase 
of  revenue  under  this  head. 

'  NEW  SETTLEMENT  SYSTEM. 

'  34.  During  the  last  four  years  (and  in  a  great  measure  in 
preparation  for  this  re-settlement  of  revenue)  a  very  great  im- 
provement has  taken  place  in  Northern  India  in  the  adminis- 
tration of  this  important  head  of  revenue  and  in  the  means 
adopted  by  the  Government  to  assess  and  settle  from  time  to 
time  that  share  of  the  produce  of  the  land  which  has  in  all  ages 
been  the  main  source  of  the  revenue  of  the  sovereign  powers 
in  India. 

'  As  no  systematic  review  has  recently  been  published  of  the 
position  and  prospects  of  this  our  most  important  head  of 
revenue,  I  propose  to  take  up  the  subject  in  some  detail,  both 
from  an  administrative  and  from  a  financial  point  of  view,  the 
materials  having  been  supplied  to  me  by  Sir  Edward  Buck,  the 
Revenue  Secretary  to  the  Government  of  India,  to  whom  per- 
sonally is  due  by  far  the  largest  share  of  the  credit  of  the 
improvements  effected. 

'  35.  The  system  of  land-assessment  has  hitherto,  in  every 
province,  involved  the  complete  survey,  field  by  field,  of  every 
village — an  operation  which  was  rendered  necessary  by  the 
absence  of  correct  maps  at  the  commencement  of  the  thirty-year 
period.  The  object  of  the  system  now  introduced  is  to  pre- 
serve, and  to  correct  up  to  date,  the  records  upon  which  the 
surveys  and  Settlements  are  based,  so  that  the  re-settlements, 
when  they  fall  due,  may  be  made  upon  existing  records,  and 
may  not  require  an  elaborate  investigation  de  novo.  The  maps 
which  have  been  provided  by  the  great  cadastral  survey  which 
has  now  almost  drawn  to  an  end,  are  in  future  to  be  corrected 
up  to  date  from  year  to  year  by  permanent  establishments  in 
which  the  patwaris  or  village  accountants  occupy  the  most 
important  place.  In  the  same  way  the  Settlements  now  being 
completed  have  involved  a  complete  revision  of  all  records-of- 
rights,  including  details  of  the  occupancy  of  every  field,  and 


CHAP.  V.] 


APPENDIX. 


377 


these  records,  like  the  maps,  are  in  future  to  be  maintained 
from  year  to  year  by  the  permanent  establishments.  The 
assessment  included  also  the  valuation  of  the  soil  and  produc- 
tive powers  of  every  field ;  but  the  valuation  made  during  the 
past  thirty  years  will  in  future  revisions  of  Settlement  be 
accepted  without  material  alteration.  Three  important  ele- 
ments of  expenditure  have  thus  been  eliminated  from  future 
Settlement  operations,  viz.  the  cost  of  periodical  field  surveys, 
of  revisions  of  records-of-right,  and  of  soil  valuations.  The 
introduction  of  the  new  system  is  made  possible  both  by  the 
more  complete  maps  and  records  which  have  been  supplied  by 
the  operations  of  the  past  thirty  years,  and  by  the  creation  of 
Agricultural  Departments  which  are  permanent  Departments 
of  Survey  and  Settlement. 

'  36.  An  examination  of  the  cost  under  the  old  and  new  sys- 
tems has  recently  been  made  in  pursuance  of  the  inquiries  of  the 
Finance  Committee  with  the  object  of  ascertaining  the  financial 
effect  of  the  new  arrangements  and  the  probable  cost  of  future 
Settlement  operations.  This  investigation  is  not  complete,  but 
it  points  to  a  maximum  expenditure,  in  future,  of  R.  100  a 
square  mile,  including  the  cost  of  additional  establishment,  and 
in  some  provinces  to  a  considerably  lower  figure.  The  com- 
parative results  are  shown  in  the  following  table,  in  which 
a  maximum  rate  of  R.  i  oo  is  applied  to  all  provinces  : — 


PROVINCE  (EXCLUDING  ASSAM). 

Rate  pei- 
square  mile 
under  the 
old  system  at 
rates  recently 
prevailing. 

Average 
expenditure 
per  annum 
at  rates  in 
preceding 
column. 

Average 
expenditure 
per  annum  at 
tlie  maximum 
rate  of  R.  100 
per  square 
mile. 

E. 

Rx. 

Rx. 

North-Western  Provinces  and  Oudh 

35o 

115,000 

30,000 

Panjab       ...... 

200 

50  ooo 

25.000 

Central  Provinces     .... 

220 

35>ooo 

15,000 

3  So 

n  ^oo 

S  ooo 

Madras      

440 

70,000 

15,000 

Bombay     ...... 

260 

65,000 

25,000 

TOTAL  . 

303 

352,500 

116,000 

showing  an  ultimate  annual  saving  of  Rx.  237,500. 


378 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 


'  The  above  table  is  based  on  an  estimate  of  the  maximum 
cost  which  may  be  incurred  in  the  revision  of  assessments 
when  the  new  arrangements  have  been  completely  established. 
In  the  meantime  some  saving  has  been  already  made  by  their 
partial  introduction  and  by  measures  which  have  recently  been 
taken  to  accelerate  the  current  revisions  of  Settlement.  Under 
the  programmes  which  have  been  arranged  in  recent  con- 
ferences with  the  local  authorities,  there  has  been  effected 
a  saving  either  in  the  expenditure  on  survey  and  Settlement, 
or  in  the  more  punctual  recovery  of  increments  of  new  revenue, 
which,  in  three  provinces — the  Central  Provinces,  Panjab,  and 
Madras — is  estimated  at  a  gross  amount  of  Ex.  2,000,000 
during  the  next  ten  years,  or  an  average  of  Rx.  200,000  a  year 
during  the  next  decade.  In  these  and  other  provinces  the 
new  increments  of  Land-Revenue  to  which  the  Government 
is  entitled  will  henceforth  be  assessed  and  collected  up  to  date, 
while  hitherto  they  have  in  many  cases  come  into  force  only 
several  years  after  the  date  of  the  expiry  of  the  old  Settlement. 

'37.  The  general  growth  of  the  Land-Revenue  is  exhibited 
in  the  following  table  : — 

Table  showing  growth  of  Land-Revenue  (including  Permanently- settled  Tracts,} 


(The  figures  are 
thousands  of  Ex.) 

North-Western 

Receipts, 
1856-57- 

Beceipts, 
1870-71. 

Average  an- 
nual growth 
(14  years). 

Percentage 
of  increase 
(14  years). 

M 

3  'o 

0  00 

|S 

Average  an- 
nual growth 
since  1856-57 
(30  years). 

Percentage 
of  increase 
(30  years). 

"3>__^ 

•§,8  J 

0    o\_8 

A  &1 

oo 

Average  an- 
nual growth 
since  1870-71 
(20  years). 

Percentage 
uf  increase 

(20  Vl'-Ill-Sl. 

Provinces  . 

3,920 

4,130 

15 

5 

4,390 

16 

12 

4,560 

21 

IO 

Oudh.    .     .     . 

970 

1,320 

25 

36 

1,410 

15 

45 

1470 

7 

ir 

Panjab   .     .     . 

1,840 

1,970 

10 

7 

2,150 

10 

17 

2,2IO 

12 

12 

Central      Pro- 

vinces .     .     . 

570 

600 

2 

5 

620 

2 

9 

650 

2 

8 

Bengal    .     .     . 

3,54° 

3,76o 

16 

6 

3,740 

7 

6 

3,800 

2 

i 

Madras  .     .     . 

3,800 

4.400 

43 

16 

4,860 

35 

28 

4,900 

25 

ii 

Bombay  (a) 

2,150 

2,950 

57 

37 

3,370 

4i 

56 

3,450 

25 

17 

Assam    .     .     . 

80 

210 

10 

162 

400 

ii 

400 

420 

10 

100 

Lower  Burma  . 

410 

600 

14 

46 

1,220 

27 

197 

1,230 

31 

105 

Minor        Pro- 

vinces .     .    . 

2O 

2O 

— 

— 

1  20 

3 

500 

1  2O 

5 

500 

17,300 

19,960 

190 

15 

22,280 

166 

29 

22,8lO 

142 

14 

(a)  Excluding  Alienations. 


CHAP.V.]  APPENDIX.  379 

'The  figures  show  actual  collections  both  of  Land-Revenue 
and  of  miscellaneous  items  classed  as  Land-Revenue,  e.  g.  sale- 
proceeds  of  waste  lands ;  water-rates  in  Madras ;  nominal 
revenue  assessment  on  lands  assigned  for  service  in  Bombay  ; 
capitation-tax  and  receipts  from  fisheries  in  Burma  and  Assam. 

'38.  Three  periods  are  taken,  viz.  : — (i)  the  first  fourteen 
years  after  the  mutiny,  during  which  the  growth  was  at  the 
rate  of  Rx.  190,000  a  year  ;  (2)  a  period  of  thirty  years  from 
the  mutiny  to  the  present  time,  during  which  the  growth  was 
at  the  rate  of  Rx.  166,000  a  year ;  (3)  a  period  of  twenty  years 
(partly  estimated)  from  1870-71  to  1890-91,  during  which  the 
growth  is  at  the  rate  of  Rx.  142,000  a  year. 

'39.  It  will  not  fail  to  be  seen  that,  while  the  fourteen  years 
preceding  1870-71  showed  an  annual  increase  of  Rx.  190,000, 
the  rate  of  increase  in  the  twe'nty  succeeding  years  has  averaged 
only  three-fourths  of  this.  The  reasons  for  this  are,  that  the 
first  period  was,  in  many  parts  of  India— Oudh  and  Orissa 
for  example — a  period  of  active  re-assessment  and  Settlement, 
and  that,  therefore,  during  the  second  there  was  less  of  the 
growth  of  revenue  which  comes  in  from  Settlement  operations  ; 
that  a  large  accession  of  land-revenue  occurred  after  the  mutiny 
in  consequence  of  confiscations  ;  and  finally,  that  there  was, 
between  1860  and  1870,  a  rapid  increase  in  the  cultivated  area 
of  the  provinces  of  Bombay  and  Madras,  in  which  the  system 
of  land-settlement  is  such  that  newly-tilled  land  comes  under 
annual  assessment,  and  in  which  the  demand  for  cotton  during 
the  American  war  gave  a  powerful  impulse  to  cultivation.  On 
the  other  hand,  a  corresponding  check  to  cultivation  occurred 
in  the  same  provinces  during  the  last  of  the  three  periods  in 
consequence  of  the  drought  of  1877-78. 

'  40.  Notwithstanding  these  causes  of  exceptional  growth  in 
the  beginning  of  the  post-mutiny  period,  it  may  reasonably  be 
expected  that  the  capital  outlay  which  the  Government  has 
recently  devoted  to  irrigation  and  railways  will,  during  the 
next  few  years,  bring  to  it  a  larger  return  from  the  land,  by 
reason  of  the  great  improvement  of  its  produce,  both  in  quan- 
tity and  value,  by  the  agency  of  canals  and  the  opening-out  of 
communications.  In  these  accessions  to  the  landed  income  of 
the  State  strict  regard  will  be  had  to  the  principles  which  have 
invariably  been  followed  by  the  Government  of  India  in  the 
assessment  of  the  land,  its  guiding  policy  having  always  been 
the  lenient  consideration  of  the  proprietary  classes.  During 


380  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [CHAP.  v. 

thirty  years  of  peace  and  progress,  the  rentals  of  tenants  have, 
through  the  cultivation  of  new  fields  or  the  imposition  of  new 
rents  by  landlords,  been  continually  expanding,  and,  in  some 
of  the  most  fertile  areas  of  India,  the  landlords  themselves 
have,  without  the  intervention  of  the  Government,  materially 
enhanced  the  rent  paid  to  them,  while  at  the  same  time  that 
proportion  of  it  paid  by  them  to  the  State  has  been  continu- 
ously reduced  to  lower  and  more  definite  limits.  In  the 
same  way,  a  lenient  consideration  is  extended  to  the  agri- 
cultural community  in  provinces  where  the  cultivators  or 
cultivating  proprietors  are  assessed  by  the  State  itself,  so  that 
in  these  also  the  percentage  of  produce  paid  as  land-revenue 
has  been  constantly  decreased. 

'  The  growth  of  land-revenue,  therefore,  which  is  to  be 
anticipated  will  be  a  growth  due  to  that  peace  and  prosperity 
which  directly  spring  from  a  lenient  and  careful  administra- 
tion rather  than  to  any  direct  action  of  the  Government  in  the 
direction  of  raising  rentals. 

'  A  brief  review  of  the  position  in  each  province  will  now  be 
given. 

'KEVIEW  BY  PROVINCES. 

'41.  North -Western  Provinces. — The  old  system  conies  to  a 
final  end  within  the  next  two  years.  The  greater  part  of  the 
province  is  held  by  tenants  on  small  holdings  of  a  few  acres 
paying  rent  to  landlords  who  are  charged  with  a  payment  of 
50  per  cent,  of  their  assets  to  Government.  The  advanced 
condition  of  the  province  led  the  Secretary  of  State  to  inquire, 
so  long  ago  as  1863,  whether  a  permanent  Settlement  could  not 
be  introduced  ;  but  a  final  consideration  of  the  subject  between 
1882  and  1884  ended  in  the  adoption  of  the  system  already 
described,  under  which  annually  revised  maps  and  records  are 
made  the  basis  of  assessment. 

'  The  rate  of  growth  of  land-revenue  in  the  North- Western 
Provinces  since  the  mutiny  year  has,  however,  been  moderate. 
In  the  first  fourteen  years  it  was  only  5  per  cent,  (say  '35  per 
cent,  per  annum),  but  it  has  in  the  current  period  of  twenty 
years  risen  to  10  per  cent,  or  "5  per  cent,  per  annum.  There 
was  in  the  North- Western  Provinces  less  room  for  extension 
of  cultivation  than  in  most  parts  of  India.  Lying  mainly  in 
the  fertile  alluvial  plain  between  the  Himalayas  and  the  high- 


CHAP,  v.]  APPENDIX.  38 1 

lands  of  Central  India,  the  province  attracted  a  large  population 
at  an  early  historical  period,  and  it  was  at  the  period  of  the 
mutiny  highly  assessed.  But  the  large  amount  of  State 
capital  spent  since  that  time  in  the  form  of  railways  and 
canals,  and  the  contemporaneous  rise  of  prices  has  given  a 
fresh  impulse  to  agricultural  wealth,  and  the  province  is  now 
in  many  districts  as  lightly,  as  it  was  formerly  heavily, 
assessed.  A  considerable  amount  of  relief  was  given  at  the 
commencement  of  the  thirty-years'  period  of  Settlement  now 
expiring,  by  the  reduction  of  the  standard  of  the  State  demand 
from  66  per  cent,  of  assets  to  50  per  cent. — a  change  which 
was,  however,  somewhat  counterbalanced  by  the  high  valuation 
of  assets  made  under  the  rules  which  governed  the  operations 
of  the  Settlement  Officers.  The  relief  is  now  made  complete 
by  the  elimination  of  soil  valuation  from  the  assessment  system 
which,  except  in  cases  of  suspected  fraud,  requires  that  the 
recorded  assets  should  be  accepted  as  a  basis  of  assessment. 
Rentals  are  in  many  districts  still  growing  at  a  rate  of  about 
i  per  cent,  per  annum,  and  in  certain  tracts  the  growth  is 
likely  to  be  so  great  that  even  under  the  lenient  system 
now  adopted,  some  difficulty  may  be  anticipated  in  taking  the 
Government  quota  in  full  at  the  next  Settlement  from  the 
landlords,  on  account  of  the  large  and  sudden  increase  which 
would  be  involved  in  such  an  assessment. 

'  42.  Oudh,  with  the  exception  of  a  closely  populated  tract 
between  Lucknow  and  Benares,  came  under  much  later  deve- 
lopment than  the  North -Western  Provinces.  Its  revenues  were 
not,  until  after  the  mutiny,  brought  under  the  effective  ad- 
ministration of  the  British  Government,  who  applied  to  it  the 
same  system  of  Settlement  as  that  which  prevailed  in  the 
North -Western  Provinces.  The  tenants  of  Oudh  have  less 
positive  rights  than  those  of  the  adjacent  province,  as  in  the 
latter  the  greater  number  are  more  securely  protected  by 
statutory  rights  against  unlimited  enhancement  of  rent. 
There  is,  therefore,  a  prospect  of  a  larger  growth  of  rental, 
and  also  of  revenue,  in  Oudh  than  in  the  North -Western  Pro- 
vinces. The  land  is  rich,  the  climate  favourable,  and  although 
since  1860  the  extension  of  cultivation  has  been  very  large, 
considerable  areas  still  remain  to  be  brought  under  the  plough. 
Competition  for  the  land  is  likely  to  increase,  and  with  it  the 
enhancement  of  the  rents  by  the  landlords,  who  have  in  Oudh 
practically  a  free  hand.  The  development  of  the  province 


382  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

under  British  rule  has  been  very  great,  and  is  still,  with  the 
extension  of  railways,  progressing  at  a  rapid  rate.  The  pro- 
vince will  come  under  re-assessment,  on  the  new  or  economical 
system,  between  1892  and  1906. 

'43.  In  the  Panjdb  there  is  a  large  proportion  of  dry  sandy 
soil  which  is  only  capable  of  development  under  the  influence 
of  irrigation.  Subsoil  water  is  generally  too  far  from  the  sur- 
face for  wells,  and  the  growth  of  revenue  depends  mainly  on 
the  expenditure  of  State  capital  on  canals.  The  revenue- 
payers  are  for  the  most  part  cultivating  proprietors  paying 
direct  to  Government,  no  part  of  the  produce  being  intercepted 
by  middlemen.  A  large  amount  of  State  capital  has  been  in 
recent  years  invested  in  the  province  in  railways  and  canals. 
Under  these  circumstances  the  growth  of  the  land-revenue, 
which  has  since  the  mutiny  been  slow,  should  now  progress  at 
a  rapid  rate. 

'  The  revision  of  Settlement  has,  under  the  old  system,  in- 
volved, as  in  the  North -Western  Provinces,  a  high  rate  of  expen- 
diture and  protracted  operations,  but  only  a  very  few  districts 
now  remain  to  be  completed  under  that  system,  and  measures 
have  recently  been  taken  to  expedite  their  assessment.  The 
whole  province  will  then  come  under  the  operation  of  the  new 
rules  which  require  the  Settlement  to  be  based  on  annual  maps 
and  records. 

'  44.  The  Central  Provinces  have  shown  a  very  small  develop- 
ment of  land-revenue  since  the  mutiny.  They  have  been  to 
a  great  extent  cut  off  from  the  railway  system  and  have  at  the 
same  time  been  lightly  assessed.  The  revision  of  Settlement 
takes  place  during  the  current  decade  commencing  with  the 
first  year  of  the  present  Provincial  Contract,  1887-88,  and 
it  is  estimated,  after  nine  years,  to  yield  an  increase  of 
Ex.  180,000.  Owing  to  the  backward  state  of  the  province,  the 
low  rates  now  paid  to  Government,  and  the  new  development 
of  the  railway  system  which  is  taking  place,  it  has  been  deter- 
mined to  make  the  new  Settlements  for  terms  varying  between 
twelve  and  twenty  years,  so  that  the  reassessment  of  the  pro- 
vince will  recommence  shortly  after  the  termination  of  the 
existing  revision. 

'  The  revision  of  Settlement  is  being  made  at  present  partly 
on  the  old  and  partly  on  the  new  system,  but  at  a  low  cost  not 
exceeding  R.  100  a  square  mile.  The  same  necessity  for  a  com- 
plete series  of  maps  and  records  has  existed  in  this  as  in  other 


CHAP,  v.]  APPENDIX.  383 

provinces,  but  owing  to  the  circumstance  that  the  revision  of 
annual  records  was  commenced,  with  the  creation  of  the 
Agricultural  Department,  five  years  before  the  old  Settlements 
began  to  expire,  there  has  been  more  time  than  elsewhere  to 
utilize  the  village  and  district  establishments  in  the  work  of 
preparing  for  Settlement.  Arrangements  were  made  under 
which  a  large  number  of  parties  of  the  Survey  of  India  have 
covered  the  surface  of  the  provinces  with  a  network  of  trian- 
gulation  available  both  for  topographical  and  revenue  purposes. 
These  are  filled  in  by  the  village  officers  under  the  supervision 
of  the  local  Eevenue  officers,  and  they  provide  sufficiently  good 
maps  as  a  basis  for  future  revisions  of  assessment.  The  re- 
vision of  the  record  is  also  primarily  effected  by  the  permanent 
establishments,  leaving  only  the  valuation  of  soils  and  general 
supervision  to  be  effected  by  'a  special  staff.  At  the  close  of 
the  present  revision,  nine  or  ten  years  hence,  the  new  system 
will  be  introduced  and  the  cost  be  brought  considerably  below 
the  new  maximum  of  E.  i  oo  a  square  mile. 

'  The  land  is  held,  as  in  the  North- Western  Provinces  and 
Oudh,  by  cultivators  of  small  holdings  paying  rent  to  pro- 
prietors from  whom  the  Government  takes  revenue.  But 
whereas  in  those  provinces  the  landlords  have  the  power, 
which  is  freely  used,  of  raising  rents  contemporaneously  with 
increase  of  competition  and  rise  of  prices,  they  have  no  such 
power  in  the  Central  Provinces.  The  growth  of  rent  and, 
therefore,  of  revenue,  entirely  depends,  except  in  land  newly 
taken  into  cultivation,  on  the  periodical  assessments  of  rent 
made  by  the  Government  at  the  time  of  Settlement.  The 
existing  rents  are,  in  most  parts  of  the  province,  an  unusually 
small  fraction  of  the  total  value  of  the  produce  ;  while,  in  con- 
sequence of  the  rising  prices  due  to  the  extension  of  the  rail- 
way system,  the  disproportion  is  continuously  becoming 
greater.  The  area  of  culturable  land  still  to  be  brought  under 
the  plough  is  exceptionally  large.  The  province  is  one,  there- 
fore, from  which  a  material  growth  of  land-revenue  may  be 
looked  for. 

'  45.  Thus  far  the  provinces  dealt  with  are  those  popularly 
known  as  the  '  temporarily- settled  zamindari '  or  '  landlord  ' 
provinces.  I  will  next  refer  to  Bengal,  which  is  recognized 
generally  as  a  'permanently-settled  landlord  province.'  But 
there  are  in  Bengal  not  less  than  about  14,000  square  miles 
which  belong  to  the  temporarily-settled  landlord  class  and  of 


384  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        .[CHAP.  v. 

which  the  old  Settlements  will  shortly  fall  in.  In  respect  of 
this  tract  preparations  are  now  being  made  for  punctual  assess- 
ment on  much  the  same  plan  as  in  the  Central  Provinces, 
and  at  equally  moderate  rates  of  cost,  by  the  Agricultural 
Department  of  the  province. 

'  The  area  in  question  comprises  large  tracts  in  Orissa  and 
Chittagong,  and  several  Government  estates.  It  will  hereafter 
come  entirely  under  the  new  system.  An  increment  of  land- 
revenue  of  20  per  cent,  would  in  this  area  be  equivalent  to 
a  fixed  addition  of  ten  lakhs  a  year  to  the  annual  demand. 

'  46.  The  province  of  Madras  must  be  divided  into  two  sec- 
tions— the  permanently-settled  zamindari  or  landlord  area, 
and  the  temporarily- settled  raiyatwari  or  tenant-proprietor  area. 
The  first  is  about  48,000  square  miles  and  the  second  about 
93,000  square  miles,  or  roughly  one-third  and  two-thirds 
respectively.  The  Settlement  on  the  old  system,  which  re- 
quired a  complete  series  of  field  maps  and  a  valuation  of  soils, 
is  now  drawing  to  a  close  and  is  being  hastened  by  assistance 
lent  to  the  local  Survey  Department  by  the  Government  of 
India.  In  a  few  years  the  whole  province  will,  in  accord- 
ance with  the  intention  which  for  some  time  has  been  declared 
by  the  Madras  Government,  be  permanently  relieved  of  special 
Settlement  and  Survey  establishments. 

'  The  growth  of  land-revenue  in  the  tenant-proprietor  tracts 
takes  place  in  two  different  directions.  There  is  the  periodical 
growth  due  to  the  increase  of  rent-rates  at  the  end  of  every 
thirty  years'  period,  and  the  annual  growth  due  to  the  gradual 
increase  of  the  area  brought  under  cultivation.  For  in  Madras 
all  tenant  proprietor  waste  land  has  an  annual  rate  attached  to 
it  at  the  time  of  assessment  which  is  applied  and  collected 
whenever  the  land  is  occupied.  The  periodical  growth  (that 
is,  the  increase  of  rates  between  the  last  Settlement  and  the 
one  now  being  completed)  is  roughly  estimated  at  from  5  to  7 
per  cent,  and  the  annual  increment  due  to  increased  cultivation 
at  Ex.  10,000  per  annum.  The  rate  of  increase  under  this  latter 
head  will  necessarily  fall  off  as  less  land  becomes  available. 

'47.  In  Bombay  the  same  general  conditions  prevail  as  in  the 
raiyatwari  or  tenant-proprietor  area  of  Madras.  The  growth 
rate,  however,  is  not  checked  by  the  presence  of  permanently- 
settled  land,  and  has,  as  in  the  temporarily- settled  section  of 
Madras,  a  double  growth,  the  one  being  due  to  the  periodical 
increase  of  rent-rates  every  thirty  years,  and  the  other  to  the 


CHAP,  v.]  APPENDIX.  385 

annual  occupation  of  fresh  land  at  the  revenue-rates  which 
were  attached  to  it  at  Settlement. 

'The  whole  province  has  in  recent  years  undergone  a  thorough 
and  searching  revision  of  assessment  which  is  now  drawing  to 
a  close.  This  revision  has  been  in  the  hands  of  a  separate 
Survey  Department  which  will  within  five  or  six  years  be 
gradually  broken  up  and  absorbed  in  the  new  establishments, 
and  the  province  will  then  come  permanently  under  the  new 
system.  It  may  be  noticed  here  that  both  in  the  Madras  and 
Bombay  Presidencies  the  holdings  or  small  farms  of  tenant- 
proprietors  have  had  their  boundaries  fixed  once  and  for  ever 
by  the  Survey  Department,  and  that  instead  of,  as  in  other 
provinces,  the  map  requiring  annual  revision  in  order  to  keep 
it  in  accord  with  changing  boundaries,  it  is  here  necessary  to 
maintain  the  boundaries  in  accordance  with  the  map  as 
originally  made.  This  duty,  as  well  as  that  of  the  mainten- 
ance of  the  statistical  record,  is  on  the  close  of  Settlement 
operations  in  each  district  made  over  to  the  Agricultural 
Department. 

'  The  growth  of  land-revenue  has  been  more  satisfactory  in 
Bombay  than  in  any  province.  It  began  in  a  marked  degree 
with  the  impetus  given  to  cotton  production  at  the  time  of  the 
American  War,  and  has  been  continued  under  the  influence  of 
rising  prices,  extended  cultivation  (and  in  Sindh,  extended 
irrigation),  supplemented  by  a  careful  system  of  assessment. 

'  48.  In  Assam  the  very  backward  state  of  the  province  and 
the  absence  of  communication  with  the  seaboard  in  the  years 
immediately  succeeding  the  mutiny,  have  made  the  growth  of 
revenue  in  the  later  years  appear  to  be  exceptionally  rapid. 
A  part  of  the  province  (about  9,000  square  miles)  is,  however, 
under  the  permanent  Settlement  system  of  Bengal,  and  the 
growth  of  revenue  depends  on  the  remaining  area  which  is 
temporarily  settled,  chiefly  with  tenant-proprietors,  at  rates 
which  are  practically  fixed,  as  there  is  hardly  any  compe- 
tition for  land  on  account  of  the  great  extent  of  waste  area 
which  can  be  taken  up.  The  most  fully- occupied  portion  has 
been  revised  on  the  system  employed  in  other  temporarily- 
settled  provinces,  and  this  revision  is  nearly  completed.  The 
remainder  will  probably  be  surveyed  and  settled  on  a  cheaper 
system  under  the  direction  of  the  Agricultural  Department, 
and  the  whole  province  will  thereafter  come  under  the  new 
arrangements.  As  in  Bombay  and  Madras,  there  is  an  annual 

VOL.  I.  C  C 


386  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [CHAP.  v. 

growth  (estimated  at  from  Ex.  8000  to  Ex.  10,000  per  annum) 
which  is  almost  solely  due  to  new  occupation,  as  there  is  here 
no  periodical  growth  due  to  increase  of  rates. 

'  49.  Lower  Burma  has  been  undergoing  for  some  years  a 
regular  revision  of  Settlement,  of  which  about  one-fifth,  or 
nearly  i  o,  ooo  square  miles,  is  completed.  Each  district,  when 
it  leaves  the  Settlement  officer's  hands,  is  made  over  to  the 
permanent  care  of  the  Agricultural  Department,  which  will 
henceforward  be  responsible  for  maintaining  the  maps  and 
records.  The  land  is  held  by  tenant-proprietors,  and  there  is 
again  in  this  province  a  double  growth  due  to  annual  increase 
of  occupation  and  to  periodical  increase  of  rates.  The  annual 
assessments  are  complicated  by  the  release  of  all  fallow  land 
from  payment  of  any  but  a  nominal  revenue,  but  there  is 
a  steady  extension  of  cultivation  which,  supplemented  by  the 
effect  of  a  careful  survey  and  assessment,  has  resulted  in  a 
growth  of  from  two  to  three  lakhs  a  year  on  a  comparatively 
small  total  revenue.  Lower  Burma  is  practically  a  large  rice- 
field  formed  by  the  alluvial  deltas  of  the  river  systems,  and  at 
present  it  yields  only  i  per  cent,  of  other  produce.  About 
37,000  square  miles,  or  84  per  cent,  of  its  cultivable  area,  are 
still  uncultivated,  and  there  is  room  for  further  growth  both 
by  extension  of  cultivation  and  by  the  improvement  of  the 
agricultural  system  through  the  introduction  of  other  crops. 
The  soil  is  rich. 

'  50.  Upper  Burma  is  composed  of  high- lands,  the  agricultural 
value  of  which  is  under  examination.  The  land-revenue  is, 
like  that  of  all  border  provinces  on  first-occupation,  initially 
small ;  but  there  is  an  equal  promise  of  the  same  steady  growth 
in  the  future  which  has  taken  place  elsewhere. 

'51.  The  increase  of  revenue  in  minor  provinces  under  the 
direct  control  of  the  Government  of  India  is  mainly  due  to  the 
re-assessment  of  the  little  district  of  Ajmer  and  the  addition  of 
Quetta. ' 


BOOK  II. 

THE  LAND-REVENUE   SYSTEM   OF 
BENGAL. 


CHAPTEK  I.  THE  PERMANENT  SETTLEMENT. 

„        II.  THE  TEMPORARY  SETTLEMENTS. 

„        III.  THE  LAND-TENURES. 

„        IV.  THE  KELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT. 

,,        V.  THE  KEVENTJE  OFFICERS. 

VI.  LAND-EEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE. 


C  o  2 


CHAPTER    I. 

GENERAL   HISTORY   OF    THE    PERMANENT    '  ZAMINDARI ' 
SETTLEMENT   OF   BENGAL. 

SECTION  I. — INTRODUCTORY. 

§  i.    Early  History  of  the  Presidency. 

THE  limits  of  this  work  make  it  necessary  for  me  to 
plunge  somewhat  abruptly  into  the  history  of  the  Bengal 
Settlement.  But  in  this  chapter,  and  in  that  which  after- 
wards describes  the  Revenue  Officers  and  their  duties,  I 
shall  go  into  more  detail  than  elsewhere,  regarding  the 
early  history  of  our  administration.  The  reason  for  this 
will  be  already  apparent  from  the  introductory  chapter 
(Book  I.  Ch.  V.)  in  which  I  have  explained  how  the 
Bengal  system  is  the  parent  of  all  others.  To  this  day 
the  district  staff, — the  Collector  and  his  assistants, — by 
whatever  other  titles  they  may  be  locally  known,  exist  on 
the  model,  and  with  many  of  the  characteristics,  of  the 
original  Bengal  institution.  And  the  principles  which 
underlie  the  Bengal  Settlement  have  not  been  without  their 
influence  on  the  later  systems  which  in  many  respects 
depart  widely  from  the  old  Bengal  ideal.  The  strong  con- 
viction of  the  advantages  of  a  recognized  landlord  with 
a  secure  title,  which  moved  the  Government  to  make,  and 


39O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.       [BOOK  II. 

to  congratulate  itself  upon,  the  Zamindari  Settlement  of 
Bengal,  resulted  indeed  in  a  reaction  which  produced  (after 
no  little  conflict)  the  raiyatu'dri  systems  of  Madras  and 
Bombay ;  but  it  survives  in  the  modified  systems — lying 
midway,  as  it  were,  between  raiyatwdri  and  Zamindari — 
that  prevail  in  Upper  India. 

Still  our  detail  must  be  of  a  practical  character,  and  I 
must  therefore  pass  over  many  interesting  phases  of  the 
history  of  the  administrative  system  developed  by  the 
East  India  Company  when  it  was  changed  from  a  trading 
corporation  into  the  ruler  of  a  great  Empire l. 

I  will  only  briefly  recall  certain  salient  points. 

BENGAL,  which  in  the  end  became  the  first  among  the 
provinces,  was  at  the  outset  the  lowest  in  rank  as  well  as 
the  latest  in  origin.  The  '  President '  at  the  factory  of  Surat 
was  originally  the  chief  representative  of  the  Company  in 
the  East.  Madras  was  erected  into  a  Presidency  in  1653, 
and  Bombay — though  still  subordinate  to  Surat — in  1668. 
The  Bengal  Presidency  was  not  formally  constituted  till  the 
next  century  had  begun. 

Our  trade  with  Bengal,  no  doubt,  was  established  much 
earlier.  It  began  practically  with  the  factory  at  Balasur 
in  1643.  But  our  permanent  establishment — following  on 
the  grant  made  in  gratitude  for  some  remarkable  cures  in 
the  Imperial  family  effected  by  Surgeon  Gabriel  Boughton 
— may  be  said  to  date  from  1652.  Sultan  Shuj'a  (one  of 
the  sons  of  Shah  Jahan)  was  local  ruler  or  Subadar  of 
Bengal,  and  was  favourable  to  the  English  and  allowed  a 
factory  to  be  opened  at  Hughli.  But  that  privilege  was 
liable  to  all  the  changes  and  caprices  of  Oriental  rule ; 
and  it  so  happened  that  Shah  Shuj'a's  successor  took  a 
dislike  to  the  traders,  with  the  result  that,  after  the  affair 
of  Job  Charnock  in  1686,  the  settlement  was  put  an  end  to. 
But  this  was  only  for  a  time ;  four  years  later,  a  reconci- 
liation was  effected  (as  the  loss  from  the  cessation  of  our 

1  A  succinct  sketch  will  be  found  ministration  Repwt  for  1872-73  ;  and 
in  Phillips,  Lecture  vii.  Also  in  the  in  Kaye,  pp.  57-108  :  and  Field, 
Historical  Summary  of  the  Bengal  Ad-  chapter  xix. 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PEEMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  39! 

trade  was  considerable),  and  Charnock  returned  and  founded 
Calcutta  in  A.r>.  1690.  Permission  was  obtained,  in  1698, 
to  buy  out  the  rights  of  the  landholders  in  the  vicinity 
of  Calcutta ;  the  Company  thus  became  holder  of  estates, 
spoken  of  in  the  official  language  of  the  day,  as  '  in- 
dependent taluqs.'  In  1699  Sir  Charles  Eyre  was  sent 
out  to  build  the  fort  which  was  called  after  the  reigning 
sovereign,  and  has  given  the  name  to  the  Presidency— 
'Fort  William  in  Bengal.'  In  1707  this  Presidency  was 
formally  recognized1.  After  this,  nothing  that  is  here 
noteworthy,  occurred  till  the  outbreak  which  culminated 
in  the  'Black  Hole'  tragedy,  and  the  battle  of  Plassey 
(Palasi),  on  the  23rd  June,  1757-  Affairs  then  took  a  new 
turn ;  instead  of  the  Company's  officers  being  the  humble 
dependants  of  the  Mughal  power,  they  became  the  real 
arbiters  of  affairs.  The  local  governors  or  Subadars,  were 
in  fact  created  by  the  authority  of  Clive.  By  treaty  the 
Company  then  became  '  Zamindar '  of  the  town  of  Calcutta 
and  the  territory  around  known  as  'The  24-Pergunnahs.' 
Afterwards  the  grant  was  made  revenue-free 2. 

In  1760  the  'Chaklas'  or  districts  of  Bard  wan,  Midnapore 
(Mednipur),  and  Chittagong  (Chattagraon)  were  granted 
revenue-free.  Lastly,  in  1765  (i2th  August),  the  grant  of 
the  '  Diwani,'  or  right  of  civil  and  revenue-administration 
of  Bengal,  Bihar,  and  Orissa,  was  made  to  the  Company,  on 
condition  of  payment  to  the  Emperor  of  a  fixed  sum  of 
twenty-six  lakhs  annually,  and  of  providing  for  the  expense 
of  the  '  Nizamat,'  i.  e.  the  criminal  and  military  administra- 
tion 3. 

1  See   Harington,  vol.  i.  2  ;   and  when  no  revenue  had  to  be  paid  to 

Phillips,  p.  231.     Kaye  gives  1715  the    Imperial  treasury,   but  every- 

as  the  date,  pp.  67  and  76.  thing  was  managed,  and  all  dues 

a  For  the  Sanad  see  Aitchison's  appropriated,  by  the  grantee. 

Treaties,  vol.  i.   15.     The   nature  of  *  The  Diw;ini  means  the  office  or 

the    Zamindar's    office    under    the  jurisdiction     of    Diwun — the    civil 

Mughal    government    has    already  minister,    as   the   Nizamat  was  of 

been    sketched    (see   p.    184)  ;    and  the  '  Nazim,'  or  military  governor. 

we  shall  presently  study  the  subject  Hence  the  term   '  Diwani '  is  still 

more   in   detail.      But    this    grant  used    to    mean    '  civil '   as    in   the 

shows  it  was  a  position  which  then  phrase    Diwani    'Adalat,    or    Civil 

implied   something  very   like    the  Court ;    and    '  Nizamat '   was    long 

landlord's    right;    and    doubly   so  used  to  mean  'criminal,' the  chief 


392  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  II. 

This  put  the  Company  into  virtual  possession  of  the  three 
provinces, — the  Orissa  of  1765  including  only  the  present 
Midnapore  district,  with  part  of  Hughli,  not  the  whole  of 
the  country  now  called  by  the  same  name. 


§  2.    Commencement  of  British  Rule. 

For  some  time  no  interference  with  the  native  officials 
was  contemplated l.  It  was  soon  found,  however,  that  the 
uncontrolled  acts  of  local  officials  under  a  corrupt  and 
effete  system,  produced  results  little  short  of  intolerable. 
In  1769,  'Supervisors'  were  appointed  in  the  hope  of  im- 
proving the  administration.  They  were  directed  to  acquire 
information  as  to  the  revenue-history  of  the  province,  going 
back  for  the  purpose  to  a  given  era  when  good  order  and 
government  had  been  universal ;  they  were  to  inquire  into 
the  real  limits  of  'estates'  held  by  the  Zamindars,  the 
quantity  of  land  they  ought  to  have  revenue-free,  and  the 
real  'rents'  or  payments  which  the  actual  cultivators  of 

Criminal  Court  being  called  Nizamat  pany's  servants  to  the  offices  of  Col- 

'Adalat.     Now  the  term  '  Faujdari '  lectors,  or  indeed  to  do  any  act  by 

is  used  for  Criminal  Courts.     But  any  exertion  of  the  English  power 

both  terms  indicate  that  the  military  would   be   throwing  off  the 

and  criminal  jurisdictions  were  con-  mask,  would  be  declaring  the  Coni- 
sidered  as  one  and  the  same.  The  pany  Suba  of  the  province.  Foreign 
grant  of  the  Diwani  did  not  theoreti-  nations  would  immediately  take 
vally  give  the  whole  rule  of  the  umbrage,'  &c. — See  Kaye,  p.  78. 
country,  but  it  did  practically.  (See  Mr.  Kaye  is,  I  think,  much  too  severe 
this  explained  in  Cowell's  Tagore  on  this  policy :  there  was  very  little 
Lectures  for  1872,  pp.  26,  27.)  'gorging  ourselves  on  the  revenue 
1  Motives  of  policy,  natural  but  and  leaving  the  responsibility.'  As 
short-sighted,  impelled  Clive  to  to  the  revenue,  no  system  could 
leave  the  actual  administration  in  well  have  brought  in  less  to  the 
the  hands  of  the  old  native  function-  Government ;  as  to  the  form  of  ad- 
aries  to  be  carried  on  in  the  name  ministration,  Clive  had  to  consider 
of  the  Subadar.  In  1767  Clive  wrote  the  susceptibilities  of  the  French — 
to  the  Select  Committee  : — 'We  are  a  very  present  danger  ; — and  it  was 
sensible  that  since  the  acquisition  with  no  desiretoshirk  responsibility 
of  the  Diwani,  the  power  formerly  that  the  government  was  let  alone, 
belonging  to  the  Suba  of  these  pro-  but  in  a  perfectly  genuine  belief 
vinces  is  totally,  in  fact,  vested  in  that  the  native  rule  was  best,  as  it 
the  East  India  Company ;  nothing  was  most  politic.  The  Company 
remains  to  him  but  the  name  and  had  only  a  staif  of  merchants  and 
shadow  of  authority.  This  name,  writers,  barely  enough  to  manage 
however,  and  this  shadow  it  is  in-  their  commerce,  and  quite  unequal, 
dispensably  necessary  that  we  should  as  Mr.  Verelst  wrote,  to  civil  ad- 
venerate  To  appoint  the  Com-  ministration. 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  393 

the  soil  ought  to  make  in  each  estate.  Various  other  im- 
provements were  hoped  for ;  and  especially  illegal  revenue- 
free  holdings  were  to  be  properly  assessed  and  made  to 
pay.  The  cultivators  were  to  be  protected  from  the  ex- 
actions of  the  Zamindars,  and  leases  or  '  pottahs '  (pattas), 
specifying  exactly  what  each  man  had  to  pay,  were  to 
be  granted 1. 

The  intention  thus  to  supervise  and  control  the  native 
revenue-administration  was  no  doubt  excellent,  but  it 
entirely  failed  of  realization:  and  on  the  28th  August, 
1771,  the  Court  of  Directors  at  home  announced  their 
intention  '  to  stand  forth  as  Diwan,  and  by  the  agency  of 
the  Company's  servants  to  take  upon  themselves  the  entire 
care  and  management  of  the  revenues.'  In  India  a  pro- 
clamation to  this  effect  was  issued  on  iSth  May,  1772,  and 
Clive  took  his  seat  as  Diwdn,  or  Minister  of  State  charged 
with  the  Civil  and  Revenue  administration  of  the  Province, 
at  the  annual  ceremony  (punya)  for  settling  the  year's 
revenue,  held  near  Murshidabad.  That  was  the  beginning 
of  our  direct  revenue-control. 

But  the  idea  of  a  Settlement  and  a  recognition  of  the 
proprietary  right  in  land,  had  not  yet  occurred  to  the 
Company's  government.  This  is  hardly  to  be  wondered 
at.  The  whole  theory  of  Indian  land-revenue  was  abso- 
lutely strange  to  the  English  authorities.  They  could  not 
tell  who  owned  the  land  and  who  did  not ;  nor  in  what 
category  to  place  the  different  native  officials  they  found 
in  the  districts.  Everything  had  to  be  learnt  by  slow  ex- 
perience. There  was  no  guide  to  the  system,  and  no  prin- 
ciples of  law  to  which  it  could  be  referred ;  nor  were  the 
Company's  servants  fitted  by  their  training  and  antecedents 
to  prescribe  systems  or  devise  administrative  forms.  As 
Mr.  Kaye  says,  '  The  Company's  servants  were  dead  hands 
at  investments,  but  they  know  nothing  of  land-tenures.' 

1  This  proposal  should  be  noted,  ing  how  the  belief  originated,  which 

as  showing  that  from  the  first,  the  was  not  abandoned  till  many  years 

idea  of  protecting  the  rights  of  the  after,  that  those  rights  would   be 

cultivators  was  in  the  mind  of  our  efficiently  protected  by  the  issue  of 

administrators  ;  and  also  as  show-  definite  written  leases. 


394  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

§  3.    Sketch  of  the  early  Revenue  system. 

In  1772  the  affairs  of  India  had  for  the  first  time  attracted 
such  attention  as  to  be  mentioned  in  a  Royal  Speech  to 
Parliament;  the  result  was  that  the  'Regulating  Act'  of 
1773  was  passed,  and  this  (insufficient  in  detail  as  it  after- 
wards proved)  established  the  Governor-General  and  Council 
in  Bengal  with  a  power  of  supervision  over  the  other  Presi- 
dencies, and  laid  the  foundation  of  a  system  of  Courts  of 
Justice,  as  well  as  of  a  series  of  written  and  published 
Regulations  for  the  guidance  of  the  authorities  in  India. 

Warren  Hastings  became  Governor -General  in  1772, 
and  under  him,  reforms  were  at  once  undertaken.  The 
mercantile  element  in  the  Company's  service  was  gradually 
replaced,  or  supplemented,  by  men  who  could  become  civil 
administrators,  and  the  Collectors  and  assistants  were  given 
more  reasonable  salaries  instead  of  being  expected  to  eke 
out  a  merely  nominal  subsistence  allowance  by  profits  of 
private  trade,  and  by  other  more  questionable  means.  It 
was  not  to  be  expected  that  while  such  changes  were  in 
progress,  a  Revenue  Settlement  system  could  all  at  once 
come  into  view.  The  plan  first  adopted  was  to  give  out 
the  revenues  in  farm  for  five  years.  Each  '  pargana '  was 
separately  farmed ;  unless  indeed  the  pargana  gave  more 
than  one  lakh  (ioo,coo)  of  rupees  revenue,  in  which  case  it 
was  divided.  '  Collectors  '  were  for  the  first  time  appointed 
(instead  of  Supervisors)  to  receive  the  revenue1.  A  native 
Diwan  was  associated  with  them,  and  they  were  superin- 
tended by  Revenue  Councils  at  Murshidabad  and  Patna. 

The  existing  Zamindars  (who  managed  the  revenue 
under  the  Native  rule)  were  not  necessarily  to  be  displaced 
by  this  arrangement;  but  they  often  refused  to  contract 
for  the  total  sums  demanded,  so  that  other  farmers  were 
appointed,  and  in  some  cases  injustice  was  done. 


1  In    the    chapter    on    Revenue  tails  about  the  five  years'  system  of 

business  and  officials,  the  history  of  1772  will  be  found  in  Field,  pp.  477 

the  Collectors,  Commissioners,  &c.,  et  seq. 
will  be  more  fully  gone  into.     De- 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  395 

Stringent  orders  were  given  to  prevent  the  farmers 
robbing  the  cultivators  or  raiyats,  and  to  make  them 
adhere  to  the  'hast-o-bud1,'  or  lists  showing  the  rents 
which  it  was  customary  for  the  raiyats  to  pay,  and  to 
prevent  illegal  cesses  being  collected. 

Notwithstanding  the  best  intentions,  and  that  the  members 
of  the  Central  Revenue  Committee  went  on  circuit  to  arrange 
details,  the  new  farming  system  proved  a  failure,  as  such 
systems  always  do.  They  required  the  utmost  honesty  in 
the  lessees,  and  that  honesty  did  not  exist.  They  required 
also  that  the  amounts  bid  for  should  be  really  fair,  and  fixed 
with  reference  to  the  real  resources  of  the  estates ;  they  also 
required  local  supervision  based  on  a  minute  knowledge  of 
details,  neither  of  which  requirements  can  be  said  to  have 
been  attainable.  The  leases  were  arranged  too  much  in  the 
auction-room 2 ;  the  data  for  real  assessments  were  wanting. 
And  if  the  total  amounts  could  not  be  checked,  any  de- 
tailed watchfulness  over  village  collections  was  impossible  ; 
officers  were  too  few,  their  knowledge  too  imperfect,  and 
the  local  machinery — the  kdnungo  and  the  patwdrt,  which 
our  best  modern  systems  have  developed  and  instructed — 
were  either  wholly  wanting,  or  existed  only  in  name, — the 
holders  of  the  offices  being  persons  under  the  absolute 
control  of  those  whose  object  was  to  deceive3.  But  perhaps 
the  greatest  cause  of  the  failure  of  the  farm  system,  was 
the  widespread  and  decimating  famine  of  1770,  on  account 
of  which  enormous  remissions  of  revenue  had  to  be  made  4. 
It  was  not  without  reason  that  the  Court  of  Directors  wrote 
in  1773  (speaking  of  the  failure  of  the  system  of  Supervisors 

1  Literally  (Persian) '  is  and  was ' ;  the  cancelment  of  the  lease  should 
in  fact,  the  actual  and  customary  follow  extortion  ;  but  there  was  no 
rent-roll  without  arbitrary  additions  one  to  enforce  these  provisions.  See 
to  it.  Field,  p.  481. 

2  The  farmers  in  many  cases  were  3  See  pp.  256,  284. 

mere  speculators  who  bid   up  the  *  What  that  famine  was  in  one 

leases,  hoping  to  get  an  uncontrolled  district — Birbhum — has   been    told 

power    to    take   what    they   liked.  in  piteous  and  graphic  language  in 

Excellent  orders  were  issued  to  pre-  Hunter's  Annals  of  Rural  Bengal.     As 

vent  this.     Nothing  was  to  be  taken  to  the  remissions,  see  Kaye,  p.  168, 

from  the  raiyat  beyond  what  was  in  note, 
his  patta,  and  a  heavy  penalty  and 


396  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

before  1772):  'Every  attempt  for  the  reforming  of  abuses 
has  rather  increased  them,  and  added  to  the  miseries  of 
the  country  we  are  anxious  to  protect  and  cherish.'  As  a 
partial  remedy  it  was  determined,  under  instructions  from 
the  Court  of  Directors,  to  abolish  the  agency  of  Collectors, 
and  try  again  the  '  Amil '  or  Native  local  Collector  of  the 
first  Mughal  system.  Had  a  strong  district  staff  kept 
watch  over  these  agents,  the  results  might  have  been 
different ;  but  unfortunately,  the  local  Collectors  were 
abolished  and  the  only  direct  supervision  was  given  by 
Councils  placed  at  distant  points  of  the  province.  For  this 
purpose  the  country  was  divided  into  six  divisions  with  a 
Provincial  Revenue  Council  for  each.  Five  of  these  sat 
at  Bardwan,  Patna,  Miirshidabad,  Dinajpur,  and  Dakha 
(Dacca).  The  central  Revenue  Committee  at  Calcutta, 
which  had  a  general  control  over  the  whole,  also  undertook 
the  direct  management  of  the  sixth  division,  which  was 
the  Orissa  of  those  days. 

When  the  period  of  five  years'  farms  was  about  to  expire, 
Warren  Hastings  was  carefully  considering  what  system 
should  next  be  followed.  But  unfortunately,  at  this  time, 
the  opposition  of  Francis,  and  the  unseemly  strife  which 
resulted  from  the  imperfect  constitution  of  the  Governor- 
General's  office  in  relation  to  the  Council,  were  at  their 
height l ;  otherwise  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  Hastings' 
advice  was  good.  To  gain  information  about  the  land 
tenures ;  to  protect  the  raiyats,  whom  he  perceived  to  be 
the  real  ultimate  producers  of  revenue ;  not  to  commit 
himself  to  Settlement  with  any  class  for  a  long  period, 
without  fuller  knowledge  ; — these  were  the  points  on  which 
he  insisted. 


1  Francis  at  that  time  had  the  ludicrous  discomfiture  of  his  foe 
benefit  of  John  Shore's  advice,  \vho  (Kaye,  p.  170).  It  is  satisfactory  to 
wrote  his  minutes  for  him.  '  The  know  that  Shore  lived  to  repent  of 
Councillor  seasoned  those  minutes  his  association  with  Francis,  and 
with  the  necessary  amount  of  became  the  friend  of  Hastings,  as  he 
acrimony,  and  then  served  them  up  afterwards  was  President  of  the 
as  his  own.'  When  Shore  fell  sick,  Revenue  Board  and  the  trusted 
Francis,  it  is  said,  was  silent,  and  adviser  of  the  Marquis  of  Corn- 
Hastings  smiled  grimly  at  the  wallis. 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  397 

It  was  not,  however,  till  the  death  of  Colonel  Monson 
had  given  Warren  Hastings  a  majority,  that  (in  1776)  his 
designs  could  be  given  effect  to.  Meanwhile  the  farming- 
leases  expired,  and  the  Court  of  Directors  did  not  exactly 
agree  to  any  plan  sent  home,  while  they  did  not  offer  any 
substitute  of  their  own,  beyond  directing  annual  leases  to 
the  Zamindars  whenever  possible.  These  instructions  are, 
however,  noteworthy,  because  in  them  for  the  first  time  it 
was  ordered  that  if  the  Zamindars  fell  into  arrears  they 
should  be  liable  to  be  '  dispossessed,  and  their  Zamindaris, 
or  portions  of  them,  shall  be  sold  to  make  up  the  defici- 
ency V 

Meanwhile,  under  Hastings'  orders,  a  commission  was 
issued  to  three  officers  to  travel  about  and  collect  further 
information.  They  made  their  report  in  March  1778. 
During  this  period  annual  Settlements  were  made,  i.  e.  in 
J777>  I77^J  1779,  and  1780.  In  1781  several  'Regulations' 
were  enacted2.  Notably,  the  six  Provincial  Committees 
were  abolished,  and  a  Metropolitan  '  Committee  of  Revenue ' 
(four  members,  of  which  the  chief  was  Shore,  afterwards 
Lord  Teignmouth)  was  appointed.  This  Committee  at  once 
proceeded  to  report  on  a  mode  of  Settlement,  and  recom- 
mended that  the  plan  'most  convenient  and  secure  for 
Government,  and  the  best  for  the  raiyats  and  country,  is} 
in  general,  to  leave  the  lands  with  the  Zamindars,  making 
the  Settlement  with  them.' 

Meanwhile  the  annual  Settlements  were  continued.  We 
now  come  to  the  eventful  year  1786,  when,  in  the  autumn, 
the  Swallow  arrived  bringing  Lord  Cornwallis,  and  with 
him  John  Shore,  who  had  been  appointed  (as  just  stated) 
to  the  Board  of  Revenue.  It  should  be  noted,  that  in  this 
year  it  was  found  (as  might  have  been  expected)  that  the 


1  Kaye,  p.  172.  afterwards    reconstructed    as    the 

2  The  reader  will   recollect  that  Bengal  Code  in  1793,  were  not  in 
the   provisions   for  Regulations  in  exact    accordance    even    with    the 
the  Act  of  1773  were  insufficient.  powers  given,  so   they  had   after- 
The   defect  was  partially  removed  wards  to  be  finally  legalized  by  the 
by  an  Act  in  1781  ;  but  even  then  Act  of  1797  (37  Geo.  III.,  sec.  142). 
the  Regulations  made,  which  were 


398  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

Collectors  were  indispensable,  and  they  were  reappointed 
to  the  number  of  thirty-six  (afterwards  reduced  to  twenty- 
three).  In  this  year,  also,  the  Central  Committee  became 
the  Board  of  Revenue. 

I  should  also  mention  that,  in  1782,  a  definite  attempt 
was  made  to  regulate  the  holding  of  lands  revenue-free,  and 
to  '  resume '  or  charge  with  revenue,  those  that  were  held 
without  authority:  the  office  for  registration  and  inquiry 
was  called  the  '  ba'zi-zamin-daftar '  (office  for  certain  lands). 

The  yearly  Settlements  (latterly  with  Zamfndars  always, 
unless  expressly  disqualified)  continued  till  1789. 

Two  things  will  here  strike  the  reader ;  one  is  how  little 
in  a  hurry  Lord  Cornwallis  was  to  take  action.  The  other 
is,  how  all  attempts  to  dispense  with  the  Zaminddr  failed, 
and  that  in  spite  of  repeated  efforts  to  be  free  of  him. 

It  is  also  instructive  to  note  how  little  use  central  control 
proves  when  the  local  agency  is  defective. 

The  Board,  far  removed  from  the  actual  scene  of  opera- 
tions, knew  nothing  of  the  real  state  of  affairs,  and  the 
diwans  and  local  officers  combined  with  the  Zamindars  and 
others  to  deceive  them. 

§  4.    A.D.  1786. — Plans  of  Lord  Cormuallis. 

Before  Lord  Cornwallis  arrived.  Barliament  had  passed 
the  Act  24  George  III.,  cap.  25,  in  1784.  And  Lord  Corn- 
wallis came  out  with  instructions  for  carrying  this  Act 
into  effect. 

The  law  indicated,  as  the  means  for  ensuring  a  proper 
Settlement,  an  inquiry  into  the  real  '  jurisdictions,  rights,  and 
privileges '  of  Zamindars,  Taluqdars,  and  Jagirdai's  under 
the  Mughal  and  Hindu  governments,  and  what  they  were 
bound  to  pay ;  it  also  directed  the  redress  of  the  grievances 
of  those  who  had  been  unjustly  displaced  in  the  course  of 
the  earlier  tentative  and  imperfect  revenue  arrangements. 
The  Court  of  Directors  suggested  that  the  Settlement  should 
be  with  the  '  landholders,'  but  at  the  same  time  'maintain- 
ing the  rights  of  all  descriptions  of  persons.  As  for  the 


CHAP.   I.] 


THE    PEEMANENT    SETTLEMENT. 


399 


revenue,  it  was  desired  that  there  should  be  a  durable 
assessment,  based  on  a  review  of  the  Settlements  and  actual 
collections  of  former  years.  It  was  thought  that  the  various 
inquiries  which  had  been  ordered  ever  since  1765  would 
have  resulted  in  a  sufficient  knowledge  of  the  paying  capa- 
city of  the  estates,  and  therefore  a  Settlement  for  ten  years 
was  ordered.  The  Court  then  thought  that  a  fixed  period 
of  ten  years  would  be  better  than  promising  a  '  dubious 
perpetuity '  ;  but  they  directed  that,  on  completion  of  the 
arrangements,  the  whole  matter  should  be  fully  and  minutely 
reported  on,  so  that  they  might  have  an  opportunity  of 
settling  the  whole  question,  without  necessity  for  further 
reference  or  future  change. 

As  I  have  said,  while  these  arrangements  were  in  pro- 
gress, the  Settlements  continued  to  be  annual,  and  Lord 
Cornwallis  was  so  little  in  a  hurry  to  carry  out  any  scheme 
of  his  own,  that  he  continued  seeking  for  fuller  knowledge. 
'No  efforts,'  says  Mr.  Cotton,  'were  spared  to  increase  the 
store  of  information.'  The  vast  body  of  opinions  thus 
collected  was  declared  by  the  celebrated  Fifth  Report  to  be 
'  too  voluminous  to  lay  before  the  House  V 

§  5.    Issue  of  Regulations  forming  a  legal  basis  for 
a  Decennial  Settlement. 

Meanwhile,  the  rules  for  the  decennial  Settlement  were 
being  elaborated.  They  were  issued  on  the  completion  of 
Mr.  Shore's  celebrated  Minutes  of  1788,  and  of  June  and 
September,  1789^  The  rules  for  settling  Bengal,  Bihar, 
and  Orissa  (as  then  constituted)  were  separately  issued 
between  1789  and  I79O3. 


1  See  Cotton's  Memorandum  on  the 
Revenue  History  of  Chittagong  (Calcutta, 
1880),  p.  50.  Unfortunately,  how- 
ever, they  consisted  chiefly  of 
opinions  and  masses  of  detail  about 
accounts,  which  did  not  in  the  least 
suffice  to  solve  difficulties  when  it 
came  to  a  question  of  assessing  in- 
dividual lands  or  estates,  still  less  of 
fixing  the  raiyats'  payments  on  an 
equitable  basis. 


2  The  Minutes  of  1789  are  printed 
in  the  appendix  to  the  Fifth  Report. 
but   not   the   elaborate   Minute    of 
1788   with    its   appendices,   giving 
Shore's  information  about  the  rise 
and  growth  of  the  Zamindari  title, 
and  its  becoming  proprietary.    This 
latter  is  consequently  given  in  ex- 
tenso  in  Harington,  vol.  iii.  (and  in 
the  Reprint). 

3  As  to  the  rules,  see  Harington, 


4OO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

When  Lord  Cornwallis  commenced  the  codification  of  the 
Regulations  in  1793,  these  rules  (amended  and  completed) 
formed  one  of  the  forty-three  Regulations  passed  on  the 
same  day,  and  have  since  been  borne  on  the  Statute-book 
as  Regulation  VIII  of  1793. 

This  is  the  law  under  which  the  '  decennial  Settlement ' 
of  Bengal  was  made. 

§  6.    Result  reported  to  the  Home  Authorities. — The 
Permanent  Settlement. 

When  the  inquiries  had  been  completed,  report  was  made, 
as  ordered,  to  the  Court  of  Directors  at  home.  Lord  Corn- 
wallis was  for  making  the  Settlement  permanent  at  once. 
But  the  Court  of  Directors,  knowing  that  Shore  and  other 
able  advisers  deprecated  the  immediate  declaration  of  per- 
manence, deliberated  for  two  years,  and  it  was  not  till 
September,  1792,  that  they  sent  a  despatch  consenting  to 
the  proposal.  On  receipt  of  this,  Lord  Cornwallis,  by  pro- 
clamation of  22nd  March,  1793,  declared  the  decennial 
Settlement  to  be  '  permanent.'  This  proclamation  was  also 
included  in  the  Statute-book  of  1793,  as  Regulation  I  of 
that  year l. 

The  student  will  then  bear  in  mind  that  the  Bengal 
Settlement  has  two  main  features,  which  must  not  be 

vol.  ii.  p.  171.     The  dates  were  : —  Court  of  Directors  to  'declare  the 

Bihar   .  .  i8th  September,  1789.  jumma  which  has  been  or  may  be 

Orissa  .  .  25th  November,  1789.  assessed  upon  their  lands  .  .  .  fixed 

Bengal..  loth  February,  1790.  for  ever,'  went   on   to   say:    'The 

Having  undergone  alteration  and  Governor-General    in    Council   ac- 

received  additions,  they  were  issued  cordingly  declares  to  the  Zamindars, 

with  translations  on  23rd  November,  independent   taluqdars,  and   other 

1791,  and  in  this  form  are  given  at  actual  proprietors  of  land,  with  or 

length  in  Colebrooke's  Digest  of  the  on  behalf  of  whom  a  Settlement  has 

Regulations,   vol.   iii.   p.   308.      Still  been  completed,  that  at  the  expira- 

further  improved,  they  were  ulti-  tion  of  the  term  of  the  Settlement 

mately  legalized,  as  above  stated,  in  [ten  years]    no   alteration   will   be 

Regulation  VIII  of  1793.     It  is  to  made  in  the  assessment  which  they 

the   provisions   as  they  appear   in  have  respectively  engaged  to  pay, 

Regulation  that  reference  is  made  but  that  they  and  their  heirs  and 

in  the  text.  lawful  successors  will  be  allowed  to 

1  The  proclamation,  after  reciting  hold  their  estates  at  such  assessment 

that  the  Governor-General  in  Coun-  for  ever.' 

cil  had  been    empowered    by  the 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  40! 

confused.      Either  one  might  have   been  adopted  without 
the  other.     They  were — 

(1)  That  the  Zamindars  were  settled  with  ;  and  as  they 

could  not  fulfil  their  obligations  to  the  State,  nor 
take  an  interest  in  their  estates  without  some 
definite  legal  status,  they  were  declared  proprie- 
tors of  the  areas  over  which  their  revenue-collec- 
tion extended.  That  proprietary  right,  however, 
was  a  limited  one ;  it  was  subject,  on  the  one 
hand,  to  the  payment  of  revenue  to  Government, 
and  to  liability  to  have  the  estate  sold  at  once  on 
failure  to  pay;  and  it  was  subject,  on  the  other 
hand,  to  the  just  rights  of  the  old  and  original 
cultivators  of  the  soil,  the  raiyats,  dependent 
taluqdars,  and  others.  The  Zamindar  was  accepted 
as  the  person  to  be  settled  with,  not  as  a  matter  of 
chance,  but  as  one  of  deliberate  policy,  and  on 
administrative  grounds. 

(2)  The  other  main  feature  was  that  the  assessments 

fixed  in   the  manner  presently  to  be  described, 
were  declared  to  be  unalterable  for  ever. 
From  these  two  features,  the    Settlement   of   1793  has 
acquired   the  name  of  the    PERMANENT    Settlement,  also 
(sometimes)  that  of  the  ZAMINDAEI  Settlement  of  Bengal. 


§  7.    General  reflections  on  the  Settlement  of  1789-93. 

Let  me  here  pause  to  correct  one  of  the  common 
misapprehensions  about  the  Permanent  Settlement  with 
Zamindars.  Let  me  ask  whether  it  was  possible  for  the 
English  administrators  to  do  anything  else  than  acknow- 
ledge them  ? 

In  the  first  place,  I  have  already  explained  in  a  general 
way  (and  shall  give  some  further  details  in  the  sequel),  that 
some  of  the  Zamindars  were  old  Rajas  who  had  a  very  close 
connection  with  the  land,  and  on  whom  the  people  greatly 
depended. 

VOL.  i.  I)  d 


4O2  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOKII. 

In  the  next  place,  there  was  the  strong  practical  argu- 
ment that  every  attempt  to  dispense  with  the  Zamindars 
had  been  a  failure  ;  injustice  had  been  done,  and  the  Statute 
of  1784  had  insisted  on  the  'ancient  immunities  and 
privileges '  of  the  Zamindars  being  respected.  All  previous 
experience  had  shown  that  it  was  impossible  to  dispense 
with  their  agency1.  Even  when  each  enormous  district 
(as  it  then  was)  had  its  one  European  Collector,  it  would 
have  been  quite  impossible  for  him  to  deal  with  thousands 
of  detailed  holdings ;  how  much  more  would  this  apply 
before  that  date,  when,  as  from  1772-79,  there  had  been 
only  councils  or  committees  for  controlling  revenue  matters 
— at  one  time  six  of  them  for  all  the  districts  included  in 
Bengal,  Bihar,  and  what  was  then  Orissa  ! 

Against  these  forcible  facts  it  was  of  little  use  to  take 
the  opinions  of  experts  and  historians2  as  to  what  were 
the  origin  and  design,  or  the  limitations,  of  the  office  of 
Zamindar.  The  theory  is  probably  much  clearer  to  us,  with 
all  the  authorities  at  hand,  than  it  was  to  the  Collector  of 
1789;  but  what  he  was  concerned  with  was  not  the  true 
theory  of  origin,  but  the  practical  position  at  the  end  of  the 
eighteenth  century. 

There  was  no  hand-book  of  ancient  law  to  guide  the 
Collectors  in  understanding  the  history  of  landholding,  to 
direct  their  attention  to  the  origin  of  villages,  the  units 

1  This    is   very   instructive.     In  the  trouble  of  going  into  any  detail. 

Akbar's   time,    the   whole  country  This    was    the    system    our    early 

was  divided  out  into  '  Sirkars.'  and  administrators  found  already  long 

these  into  parganas,  each  with  its  established.     In  the  position  they 

vigilant  revenue  'amil,  and  the  par-  were  placed  in,  it  was  utterly  im- 

ganas    even    had   recognized    sub-  possible  for  them  to  have  restored 

divisions     under     petty     revenue  the  '  Akbarian  '  method,  as  we  have 

officers.     As    long  as    this  system  now  restored  it  in  Northern  India, 

was  kept  working  by  a  powerful  The  '  tahsildars,'  and  all  the  host  of 

Government,  the  revenue  was  not  local   officials  trained  and  able  to 

intercepted,   the    people  were    not  carry  out  such   a  system,  are   the 

oppressed.     The   moment  the   Go-  product  of  a  century  of  British  rule, 

vernment  became  too  weak  to  con-  In  1 789  no  such  persons  could  have 

trol  the  machinery,  the  subdivisions  been  found. 

disappeared,  and  then  the  revenue  2  This  was  freely  done.     See  the 

could  only  be  collected  by  the  agency  series    of    questions    and    answers 

of  great  farmers,  who  undertook  to  appended  to  Mr.  Shore's  Minute  of 

pay  a  fixed  sum  for  a  certain  portion  1788. 
of  territory,  saving  the  Government 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  403 

composing  the  great  estates,  or  to  explain  what  those 
aggregates  of  cultivators  meant,  in  the  light  of  a  compara- 
tive study  of  early  customs  and  institutions.  Their  only 
conception  of  landholding  was  embodied  in  the  English 
landlord  with  his  tenants.  And  it  is  impossible  to  deny 
that  the  Zamindar  was  more  like  a  landlord  than  anything 
else1.  True  it  was  that  the  tenants'  holdings  were  not 
valued  like  English  farms  and  offered  to  tenants  at  the 
consequent  rent,  to  be  taken  or  left  at  the  tenants'  pleasure. 
Even  in  England  tenants  had  been  on  farms  for  genera- 
tions. The  superficial  differences  were  not  greater  than 
what  differences  of  race  and  climate  would  account  for ; 
and  the  deeper  but  minuter  differences  were  unperceived, 
because  land-tenures  had  not  been  cleared  up  as  they  have 
now.  The  Zamindar  was  more  oppressive  than  an  English 
landlord,  therefore  measures  of  protection  were  required 
for  the  tenantry  :  that  seemed  the  chief,  if  not  the  only 
thing. 

Grievous  as  the  failure  of  the  Permanent  Settlement  has 
been,  its  failure  is  not  due  to  the  fact  that  Zamindars  were 
confirmed,  or  that,  in  the  unavoidable  necessity  of  defining 
and  securing  their  position  in  English  legal  documents, 
they  were  called  and  made,  landlords.  The  evil  consisted 
in  this,  that  their  right  was  not  limited  with  regard  to  all 
the  older  raiyats,  leaving  new-comers  to  be  in  principle 
(with  such  detailed  conditions  as  might  be  advisable) 
contract-tenants.  The  other  evil — that  of  assuming  to 
a  legislature  the  power  of  binding  all  future  lawgivers, 
and  permanently  exempting  a  certain  class  of  proprietors 
from  their  due  share  of  the  State  burdens  at  the  expense 
of  other  people  and  provinces — that  is  a  matter  quite 
unconnected  with  the  grant  of  proprietary  rights  or  the 
protection  of  tenants. 

I  shall  point  out  in  due  course,  the  ample  evidence  there 
is,  that  from  1769  onwards,  the  rights  of  the  raiyats  were 

1  At  any  rate  he  must  have  ap-       not  explain  itself  to  the  Company's 
peared  to  combine  the  landlord  and       servants  of  1 789. 
collector  in  a  fashion  which  could 

D  d  2 


404  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  11. 

never  intended  to  be  forgotten ;  but  it  is  easy  for  us  now, 
after  half  a  century  of  inquiry  and  discussion  about  tenant 
right,  and  with  the  experience  gained  in  many  provinces 
and  their  Settlements,  to  criticise  our  predecessors  of  1790. 
At  that  time  no  one  knew  what  practical  steps  to  take. 
Collectors  knew  that  village  rolls — '  hast-o-biid,'  '  raibandi,' 
or  whatever  other  name  they  were  known  by — existed, 
showing  the  sums  payable  by  raiyats;  but  how  these 
sums  were  ascertained  and  how  far  they  could  be  altered 
periodically,  and  on  what  principles  if  any,  they  did 
not  know.  '  Pargana  rates '  were  talked  of  rather  than 
actually  adopted  or  enforced ;  for  re-assessments  were 
periodically  made,  or  rather,  virtual  additions  to  the  old 
rates  were  covered  by  the  irregular  expedient  of  '  cesses ' 
and  '  benevolences '  (abwab,  &c.).  With  this  knowledge,  it 
is  hardly  wonderful  that  they  should  have  thought  the  one 
and  sufficient  remedy  to  be  the  compulsory  issue  of  'pot- 
tihs'  or  leases  to  the  tenants,  setting  forth  what  the 
payment  was,  and  hoping  that  vague  traditional  '  pargana 
rates'  would  be,  or  could  be,  respected.  It  was  not 
foreseen  that  the  '  pattas '  would  not  be  generally  granted, 
and  that  no  machinery  existed  for  seeing  that  they  were 
granted ;  still  less  was  it  suspected,  that,  as  afterwards 
proved  to  be  the  case,  the  patta  would  be  turned — when  used 
at  all — into  an  engine  of  extortion. 

Another  point  must  be  mentioned,  and  that  is  that  the 
Zamindari  Settlement  was  not  Lord  Cornwallis's  idea.  It 
was  distinctly  ordered  in  April,  1786,  by  the  home  authori- 
ties :  it  was  advocated  by  all  the  chief  revenue  authorities 
in  Bengal.  Shore,  though  he  deprecated  the  hasty  assess- 
ment of  the  amount  of  land-revenue  in  perpetuity,  never 
hesitated  in  recommending  the  grant  of  a  secure  estate  to 
the  Zamindar.  Mr.  Thomas  Law,  Collector  of  Bihar,  was 
indefatigable  in  writing  in  favour  of  a  Zamindari  Settle- 
ment. Mr.  Brook  of  Shahabad  was  also  urgent  in  its  sup- 
port. The  Settlement  was  then,  as  Mr.  Kaye  says  truly, 
the  work  of  the  Company's  Civil  servants.  No  doubt  it 
fell  in  with  Lord  Cornwallis's  views,  because,  as  I  have 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  405 

said,  no  one  at  that  time  could  have  thought  of  imagining 
a  theory  of  village  communities  or  of  village  Settlements. 
It  was  not  till  some  years  after,  that  the  existence  of 
villages,  with  all  their  customs  in  full  force,  in  Benares, 
attracted  the  attention  of  Mi1.  Duncan,  the  Resident,  in 
1795-6.  Even  then  it  is  only  necessary  to  read  the  report 
to  see  how  completely  the  landlord  theory — as  the  only  one 
realized — was  in  the  mind  of  the  writer l. 

When  Lord  Cornwallis,  supported  by  the  general  opinion, 
had  made  up  his  mind — and  he  deliberated  carefully  from 
1786  to  1793 — that  the  Zaminddri  Settlement  was  the 
right  thing,  he  further  considered  that  it  would  be  useless 
unless  the  assessment  was  also  declared  Permanent. 

In  this  one  point  Lord  Cornwallis  may  be  charged  with 
haste — he  might  have  let  the  originally  ordered  ten  years 
run  out,  and  then  see  what  it  was  best  to  do.  His  arguments 
in  favour  of  permanency  of  the  assessment — some  of  them 
based  on  grave  mistakes  of  fact 2— hardly  answered  the 
objections  of  Mr.  Shore. 

It  is  worthy  of  note  here,  that  while  Shore  thought  it 
right  to  declare  the  Zamindars  proprietors,  he  held  that 
time  would  be  required  to  settle  what,  under  the  circum- 
stances, was  really  meant  by  the  proprietary  right  con- 
ferred3. He  did  not  observe  any  specific  rules  for  the 
security  of  the  raiyats ;  he  well  knew  '  the  difficulty  of 
making  them,  but  some  must  be  established.  Until  the 
variable  rules  adopted  in  adjusting  the  rent  of  the  raiyats, 
are  simplified  and  rendered  more  definite,'  he  added,  'no 
solid  improvement  can  be  expected  from  their  labours 
upon  which  the  prosperity  of  the  country  depends.'  With 
true  foresight  Mr.  Shore  further  predicted  that  'if  the 


1  Instances  of  this  will  also  be  everything — of  supposing  that  the 

seen   even   in   the    minutes    made  raiyats  paid  rents  by  agreement  with 

thirty  years  later,  when  the  North-  the  Zamindars.     See  Field,  p.  490. 

Western    Provinces    villages    were  &c.,   quoting   the   minute    of   i8tli 

beginning  to  be  understood  ^  Re  venue  June,  1789,  and  Lord  Cornwallis'* 

Selections,      North- Western      Pro-  reply, 

vinces,  1818  22  .  *  Mr.  Shore's  own  words  will  be 

*  As,  e.  g.,  what  Dr.  Field   calls  found  quoted  further  on. 
the  'cardinal'  mistake— it  vitiates 


4-06  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

Zamindars  were  left  to  make  their  own  arrangements 
with  the  raiyats  without  restriction,  the  present  confusion 
would  never  be  adjusted.'  The  system,  in  short,  had  not 
defined  the  relation  of  the  new  '  landlord  '  to  his  '  tenant ' ; 
would  it  not  be  better  to  introduce  a  new  system  by 
degrees  than  to  establish  it  at  once  beyond  the  power  of 
revocation  ? 

On  the  other  hand,  it  may  be  urged  that  probably  the 
consideration  which  most  weighed  with  Lord  Comwallis, 
was  one  that  would  not  take  long  to  mature.  He  was 
certain  he  had  done  the  right  thing  in  making  the  Zamin- 
dar  proprietor ;  he  believed  that  legislation  would  protect 
the  raiyat;  but  that  if  the  Settlement,  as  a  whole,  was 
not  closed  for  ever,  a  revision  might  occur,  which  would 
shake  the  Zamindar's  position,  and  so  at  any  moment,  all 
his  benevolent  work  might  be  undone.  In  this,  of  course, 
he  was  wrong :  reassessment  based  on  just  principles  of 
growth  in  the  cultivated  area  and  rise  in  prices,  has 
nothing  to  do  with  unsettling  fixed  rights  of  property,  any 
more  than  a  revision  of  income-tax  renders  the  capi- 
talist's position  as  a  man  of  property  insecure.  But  that 
was  not  understood.  It  will  be  remembered  that  the 
Zamindar's  revenue,  as  fixed  in  1793,  was  not  a  light  one 
under  the  circumstances.  It  was  certainly  supposed  that 
many  of  the  raiyats  would  pay  fixed  rents :  and  it  was 
thought  that  if  the  Zamindar  was  to  be  secure  and  pros- 
perous, his  revenue  could  not  be  raised.  True,  he  would 
cultivate  more  waste  which  would  bring  in  new  rents ; 
and  in  some  undefined  way,  some  rents  would  rise  by 
improved  cultivation 1,  but  that  would  only  be  his  legiti- 
mate profit ;  he  would  become  rich  and  would  then  import 
luxuries,  live  at  ease,  and  enrich  the  treasury  by  the  indirect 
taxation  he  would  pay  on  import  of  commodities  2. 

1  And  so  they  would.     It  was  a  not  raised.      Whatever    the    truth 

question  of  paying  rent  in  kind.    A  may  be,    expressions  occur  in   the 

bad  tenant  gets  three- hundred  seers  early   minutes  alluding  to  a  rise  in 

of  wheat  off  an  acre,  and  the  land-  rental,  just  as  often  as  those  which  imply 

lord  gets  one  half.    A  good  one  gets  fixity  of  rents. 

five    hundred,    and    the     landlord  2  '  Every  man,'  wrote   Mr.  Law, 

benefits  thereby,  though  the  rent  is  '  will  lay  out  money  in  permanent 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  407 

All  this  seemed  at  the  time,  and  backed  by  Mr.  Law's 
glowing  periods  about  the  gratitude  of  ancient  Zamindar 
and  jagirdar  families  restored  to  opulence,  to  point  conclu- 
sively to  the  permanence  of  the  assessment,  as  well  as  the 
security  of  the  landlord's  title. 

Unfortunately,  facts,  as  they  afterwards  developed,  could 
not  be  foreseen;  the  necessity  for  punctual  payments  in- 
volved a  severe  law  for  recovery  ;  the  sale  lavjs  had  from  the 
first  suggested  themselves  without  question  ;  and  indeed  the 
law  would  have  acted  with  much  diminished  harshness  if  it 
had  not  been  for  the  characteristics  of  the  landlords.  They 
were  indolent  and  extravagant ;  they  did  nothing  for  the 
land ;  and  even  when  there  was  no  glaring  personal  defect, 
the  climate  and  the  habits  of  the  country  unfortunately 
suggested  that  the  proprietor  should  save  himself  trouble 
by  farming  out  his  estate  to  any  one  who  would  give  him 
the  largest  profit  over  and  above  his  revenue-payment. 
And  as  the  proprietor's  farmer  in  time  grew  rich, — what 
with  freedom  from  war,  and  security,  and  the  daily  in- 
creasing value  of  land, — so  he  too  farmed  his  interest  to 
others,  till  farm  within  farm  became  the  order  of  the  day, 
each  resembling  a  screw  upon  a  screw,  the  last  coming 
down  on  the  tenant  with  the  pressure  of  them  all.  But 
who  could  have  foretold  this  in  1790  ? 

We  must  now  return  to  the  direct  narrative  of  the  pro- 
gress of  the  Settlement. 

§  8.    Procedure  of  Settlement. — Absence  of  a  Survey. 

One  of  the  first  things  that  will  strike  the  student  is 
that  the  Settlement  was  made  without  ascertaining  the 
boundaries  of  the  estates  and  without  a  survey.  The  cost 

structures,  as  such  works  enhance  raise  a  class  of  native   gentlemen 

the  value  of  his  estate  and  promise  proprietors,  who  will  gradually  have 

future  benefit.  If  a  scarcity  happens  established     themselves     in     good 

the  landholders  will  forego  demands,  houses  with  the  various  comforts  of 

and  encourage  cultivation  to  pre-  life.'     (See  Kaye,  p.  178.)     See  also 

serve  their  tenants,  who  become  a  par.  32  of  Revenue  letter  to  Bengal, 

part   of  their    necessary   property.  ist  February,  i8ir  ;  Field,  p.  544. 
The  increasing  independence  will 


408  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

of  survey  would  have  then  been  great,  and  the  requisite 
establishment  such  as  could  hardly  have  been  contem- 
plated with  equanimity;  moreover  there  were  visionary 
advantages  in  abstaining  from  measurement  and  inquiry 
which  then  commanded  much  attention. 

The  direct  consequence  of  admitting  the  Zamindar  to 
the  position  of  an  English  landlord,  was  a  desire  to  leave 
him  in  the  enjoyment,  as  far  as  possible,  of  the  independ- 
ence dear  to  an  English  landholder.  What  need  was  there, 
the  rulers  of  those  days  thought,  to  harass  the  proprietor 
we  have  established  and  now  wish  to  encourage,  by  survey- 
ing or  measuring  his  lands  and  making  an  inquisition  into 
his  affairs  ?  Fix  his  revenue  as  it  has  all  along  been  paid, 
or  .correct  the  recorded  amount  if  it  is  wrong ;  sweep  away 
illegal  taxes,  resume  what  land  is  unfairly  held  without 
paying  revenue,  and  then  leave  the  proprietor  in  peace. 
If  some  neighbour  disputes  his  boundary, — if  there  is  room 
to  believe  that  he  is  encroaching, — let  them  go  to  law  and 
decide  the  fact. 

Besides  this  feeling,  there  was  another,  which  at  fir&t 
made  a  survey  unacceptable.  Strange  as  it  may  appear  to 
European  ideas,  measurement  was  looked  on  with  great 
dread,  both  by  Zamindar  and  raiyat.  Whenever  the  raiyat 
had  to  pay  a  very  heavy  rent,  or  the  Zamindar  to  satisfy 
a  high  revenue  demand,  both  were  glad  to  have  a  little  (or 
often  a  good  deal)  more  land  than  they  were  in  theory 
supposed  to  pay  on. 

It  was  always  found  an  effective  process  under  the 
Mughal  rule,  to  threaten  a  raiyat  with  the  measurement  of 
his  lands  ;  for  his  '  rent '  was  fixed  at  so  much  for  so  many 
bighds.  If  this  rent  was  oppressive,  as  it  often  was,  his 
only  chance  of  meeting  that  obligation  was  that  he  really 
held  some  bigJids  in  excess  of  what  he  paid  for,  and  this 
would  be  found  out  on  measurement.  But  that  was  not 
the  only  danger  ;  the  landholder  well  knew  that  even  if  he 
had  no  excess  whatever,  still  the  adverse  measurer  would 
inevitably  make  out  the  contrary.  By  raising  the  '  jarib,' 
or  measuring  rod,  in  the  middle,  and  by  many  other  such 


CHAP.  I.] 


THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT. 


409 


devices,  he  would  make  the  bighd  small,  and  so  produce 
a  result  showing  the  unfortunate  raiyat  to  be  holding 
more  than  he  was  paying  for ;  and  increased  rent  for  the 
alleged  surplus  was  immediately  exacted.  In  the  same 
way  the  Zamindar,  even  though  the  Settlement  law  was 
explicit,  thought  it  on  the  whole  safer  to  have  the  details 
of  his  estate  as  little  denned  (at  least  under  the  eyes  of  the 
Collector)  as  possible. 

Of  course,  the  want  of  survey  and  boundary  demarcation 
led,  as  we  shall  afterwards  see,  to  great  difficulties ;  and 
various  enactments  have  been  since  passed  to  provide  a 
proper  register  of  estates  and  a  survey  to  ascertain  their 
true  limits  ;  but  it  is  not  difficult  to  understand  why  a 
survey  was  not  at  first  thought  of.  At  that  time  nearly 
all  the  occupied  parts  l  of  the  districts  were  divided  out 
into  '  Zamindaris.'  In  a  few  instances  in  Bengal,  but  more 
commonly  in  Bihar,  the  estates  were  called  'jagir,'  and 
some  estates  were  held  by  grantees  called  '  taluqdars.'  But 
whatever  the  title,  the  actual  allotments  of  land  forming 
the  settled  estates  were  those  mentioned  in  the  native 
revenue  records.  As  before  stated,  there  were  no  maps  or 
plans  or  statements  of  area ;  the  boundaries  of  the  estate 
were  vaguely  described  in  words,  and  a  list  of  the  villages 
included  was  given ;  but  the  limits  of  these  were  very 
imperfectly  known,  especially  where  a  large  portion  was 
waste.  Each  Zamindar  held  a  warrant,  or  '  sanad,'  under 
which  the  Emperor  or  his  deputy  had  created  the  '  estate  ' ; 
and  that  specified  the  revenue  that  was  to  be  paid,  and 
declared  the  Zamindar's  duties  ;  but  the  limits  of  the  estate 
were  only  indicated  by  the  string  of  names  of  villages  or 
parganas. 


1  I  say  '  occupied  parts,'  for  at 
that  time  a  majority  of  the  districts, 
especially  those  near  the  hilly  tracts, 
"  had  large  areas  still  waste,  but  never- 
theless forming  part  of  the  Zamin- 
d&ri,  or  at  least  claimed  as  such. 
Lord  Cornwallis  stated  that  one- 
third  of  the  Company's  possessions 
was  waste  at  the  time  when  the 


Settlement  work  began.  The  object 
of  the  Settlement  of  1793  was  to 
recognize  all  the  land,  waste  or  cul- 
turable,  in  each  Zamindari,  as  the 
property  of  the  Zamindar ;  but  no 
doubt  at  that  time  there  was  very 
little  certainty  as  to  what  was 
really  included  in  the  estate.  See 
Fifth  Report,  vol.  i.  p.  18. 


4-IO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

§  9.    The  Property  made  transferable. 

It  is  hardly  needed  to  remark  that  the  'property'  granted 
to  the  Zamindars  was  made  transferable,  which,  it  was 
expressly  stated,  it  previously  had  not  been.  The  8th 
Article  of  the  proclamation  sets  forth — 

'That  no  doubts  may  be  entertained,  &c.,  the  Governor- 
General  in  Council  notifies  to  the  Zamindars,  &c.,  that  they 
are  privileged  to  transfer  to  whomsoever  they  may  think  proper, 
by  sale,  gift,  or  otherwise,  their  proprietary  rights  in  the  whole 
or  any  part  of  their  respective  estates  without  applying  to 
Government  for  its  sanction  to  the  transfer  ;  and  that  all  such 
transfers  will  be  held  valid,  provided  that  they  be  conformable 
to  the  Muhammadan  or  Hindu  law  .  .  .  and  that  they  be  not 
repugnant  to  any  regulations  now  in  force  which  may  have 
been  passed  by  the  British  Administrations,  or  to  any  regu- 
lations that  they  may  hereafter  enact1.' 

§  10.   Selection  of  Zaminddrs. — Joint  Estates. — Refusal  of 
Settlement. 

Some  curious  restrictions  were  at  first  placed  on  the 
selection  of  persons  to  be  Zamindar-proprietors.  It  was 
at  one  time  attempted  to  exclude  from  Settlement  not  only 
minors  and  females  incompetent  to  manage  their  estates, 
but  also  persons  of  '  notorious  profligacy '  or  '  disqualified 
by  contumacy.'  These  grounds  of  exclusion,  being  of 
course  impracticable  to  prove  satisfactorily,  and  being  sure 
to  give  rise  to  great  scandals,  owing  to  the  necessity  of  an 
inquiry  in  Court,  were  ultimately  given  up 2.  As  regards 
estates  of  minors  and  others  unable  to  take  care  of  their 
own  rights,  they  were  placed  under  the  Court  of  Wards,  and 
managed  on  behalf  of  the  incompetent  owners. 

When  there  were  several  shareholders  in  an  estate,  there 
was  at  first  a  rule  to  make  them  elect  a  manager.  This 

1  The  subject  is  further  mentioned  attempted  to  lay  down  the  method 
in  the  preamble  to  Reg.  II  of  1793.  of   charging,  defending,  and  esta- 

2  See  Reg.  VII  of  1796.      Reg  X  blishing  such  objections, 
of  1793  (Section  5,  clause  4)    had 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  4 1  I 

failed,  and  after  a  time  the  law  was  altered,  and  they  were 
left  to  manage  as  they  pleased,  but  were  held  jointly  and 
severally  responsible  for  the  revenue.  The  law,  however, 
permitted  a  partition  and  a  complete  severance  of  responsi- 
bility if  the  sharers  wished  it. 

When  there  were  cases  of  doubtful  or  disputed  boundary, 
possession  was  looked  to  ;  and  if  possession  could  not  be 
ascertained,  the  estate  was  held  by  the  Government  officers 
(held  '  kbas '  as  the  revenue  phrase  is)  till  the  dispute  was 
legally  settled. 

If  the  Zammdar  declined  Settlement  (i.e.  objected  to  pay 
the  amount  assessed  and  the  proper  authorities  refused  to 
reduce  it)  the  lands  were  farmed  or  held  khas,  and  the 
ex-proprietor  got  a  '  malikana,'  or  allowance  of  10  per  cent, 
on  the  Government  assessment. 

I  may  add  that  such  refusals  were  rare,  for  though  some 
refused  the  terms  for  the  decennial  Settlement,  they  accepted 
when  the  proclamation  of  perpetuity  was  issued. 

§  ii.    Dependent  and  independent  Taluqddrs. 

The  Regulation  prescribed  that  the  Settlement  was  to 
be  made  with  '  Zamindars,  taluqdars,  and  other  actual  pro- 
prietors ' ;  that  implies  that  the  Zamindars  were  not  the 
only  persons  entitled  to  be  recognized  as  proprietors. 

I  have  mentioned  that  there  were  grantees  of  the  State 
called  taluqdars.  These  were  sometimes  separate  grants, 
outside  and  'independent'  of  the  Zamindar's  estate1,  in 
which  case  they  paid  revenue  direct  to  the  treasury.  Some- 
times, being  of  an  inferior  order,  they  were  found  inside  the 
estate,  and  were  then  'dependent'  on  the  Zammdar,  and 
paid  through  him.  Rules  were  laid  down  for  determining 
when  the  taluqd&r  was  to  be  settled  with  separately  as 
proprietor,  and  when  he  was  considered  as  subordinate  to 
the  Zamindar. 


1  Called  also '  Huziiri'  taluqas,  i.e.  authority ;  or  ;  kharija,'  i.  e.  outside, 
paying  revenue  direct  to  the  Huzur,  or  without,  the  Zamindsiri  estate 
or  headquarters  of  the  Government  and  control. 


412  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

This  was  a  matter  of  no  little  importance.  Every  one 
who  could  get  himself  treated  separately,  became  an  inde- 
pendent proprietor  with  his  revenue  settled  for  ever.  A 
taluqdar  who  could  not  establish  his  right  to  be  separate, 
though  he  might  have  substantial  privileges  as  to  his 
tenure  and  the  non-enhancement  of  his  rent,  still  was  only 
a  subordinate — a  raiyat,  or  as  he  is  now  called,  a  '  tenure - 
holder.' 

The  Kegulation  also  mentions  that  there  were  taluqdars 
who  had  purchased  or  obtained  their  title  by  gift  from  the 
Zamindar.  These  were  independent ;  so  were  persons  who 
held  grants  direct  from  the  Government,  also  taluqs  which 
had  been  created  before  the  Zamindari.  A  rule  was  also 
made  that  if  the  Zamindar  was  proved  to  have  exacted 
more  than  was  due,  any  taluqdar  might  ask  that  his  estate 
should  be  separated.  On  the  other  hand,  leases  granted  for 
clearing  waste,  and  called  '  jangalburi-taluqs/  were  treated 
as  only  subordinate. 

As  to  the  origin  of  these  various  taluqs,  I  must  defer 
details  till  we  come  to  Chap.  III.  Sec.  iii,  where  the  matter 
is  regarded  from  the  tenure  point  of  view,  whereas  here  we 
are  dealing  with  the  question  of  Revenue  Settlement  only. 

There  were  also  grants  known  as  '  afma  '  (of  which  here- 
after). If  these  had  been  granted  free  of  all  payment,  they 
were  treated  as  independent  properties  ;  but  if  only  granted 
at  a  quit-rent,  or  with  the  annexed  condition  that  the 
holder  was  to  clear  the  waste,,  they  were  subordinate 
tenures. 

When  the  taluqs  were  granted  by  the  Native  Govern- 
ment under  the  denomination  of  '  muqarrari '  or  '  istimrari ' 
(or  both  terms  t6gether),  they  were  independent.  Of  these 
terms,  the  former  means  'fixed'  as  regards  the  rent  or 
revenue,  and  the  latter  '  firm  '  or  '  in  perpetuity '  as  regards 
the  tenure. 

Such  a  grant  implied  that  whether  the  grantee  were  or 
were  not  proprietor,  the  whole  rent  or  assessment  would  go 
to  him,  and  only  the  fixed  (muqarrar)  proportion  be  passed 
on  by  him  to  the  Treasury.  This  sum  of  course  was  much 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  413 

less  than  the  full  assessment.  Here  clearly  the  grantee  was 
independent  of  any  Zamindar.  If  his  grant  was  not 
istimrari,  in  perpetuity,  but  only  for  life,  then  on  its  expiry 
the  succeeding  holder  would  still  be  entitled  to  separation,  as 
clearly  he  had  not  had  anything  to  do  with  the  Zamindar, 
but  only  with  the  authority  which  made  the  grant. 

It  will  be  remembered  that  there  are  tenures  under  these 
same  names  '  muqarrari,'  &c. — but  granted  by  the  Zarain- 
ddr,  not  by  the  State:  in  that  case  they  are  only  sub- 
ordinate tenures,  though  the  rents  may  be  '  fixed,'  and  the 
right  to  hold  be  '  in  perpetuity.' 

The  Collector's  duty  is  limited  to  determining  the  ques- 
tion whether  the  'taluq'  ought  to  be  independent  or  not. 
He  had  nothing  to  do  with  the  validity  of  the  title  itself  if 
that  was  disputed 1. 

It  was  hoped  that  the  process  of  inquiry  would  be  ter- 
minated with  the  Settlement,  but  it  seems  that  for  some 
years  after,  people  kept  on  filing  applications  for  separate 
recognition,  and  it  became  necessary  to  give  a  year's  grace 
for  such  applications,  after  which  no  further  requests  would 
be  listened  to  2. 

These  remarks  will  not  make  clear  the  nature  of  the 
tenures  spoken  of,  but  they  are  intended  to  indicate  how 
that  besides  '  Zamindaris,'  there  were  many  other  estates 

1  Of  course  if  a  Zamindari  estate  wards   made   to    the    Civil    Court, 
was   held  jointly  and  the   sharers  When  the  Zamindar  had  previously 
separated,  each    would    become    a  engaged    for    the    revenue    of    his 
separate  independent  proprietor.  Zamindari,  including  the  taluqs,  he 

Mortgagees  in  possession  were  was  allowed  an  abatement  to  the 

settled  with,  the  mortgagee  taking  amount  separately  assessed  on  the 

the  place  on  redemption.  latter  as  previously  stipulated  with 

The  Settlement  was  also  always  him.  Of  course,  all  this  applied 

made  with  the  person  in  possession  ;  a  only  to  taluqs  existing  or  created 

claimant  out  of  possession  must  go  before  the  Settlement.  Any  new 

to  the  Civil  Court,  and,  if  successful,  taluq  would  only  be  treated  as  sepa- 

the  Settlement  would  be  trans-  rate  if  properly  registered  and  ap- 

ferred  to  him.  plied  for  under  Regulation  XXV  of 

2  Harington  mentions  that  about  1793,  which  provided  for  the  par- 
three  thousand  taluqs  were  separated  tition  of  Zamindari  estates  and  the 
by  him  in  the  Zamindari  of  Rajshahi  allotment  of  the  jama  on  the  divided 
alone.     A    summary    inquiry  was  portions.      If  this   was   not   done, 
made  in  every  instance  as  directed,  Government  would  take  no  notice  of 
in  the  presence  of  the  Zamindar's  the  taluq,  if  the  estate  were  sold  for 
raldl   (law  agent),   and  one   appeal  arrears.     See  also  Fifth  Report,  vol.  i. 
only  is  known  to  have  been  after-  p  34. 


41 4  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

which  were  treated  as  entitled  to  separate  Settlement,  and 
their  holders  to  be  (equally  with  the  greater  Zamfndars) 
'  actual  proprietors.' 

§  12.    Basis  of  the  Assessment. 

The  Settlement  rules  of  1789-93  laid  down  separate 
principles  of  assessment  for  Bengal,  for  Bihar,  and  for 
Orissa.  In  Bengal  and  Orissa  the  actual  revenue  of  the 
preceding  year,  or  some  year  nearly  preceding  (which  was 
to  be  compared  with  the  accounts,  and  tested  by  the  in- 
formation which  the  Collector  had  acquired),  was  to  furnish 
the  standard  of  assessment.  In  Bihar,  the  standard  was  to 
be  the  average  produce  of  land  in  any  ordinary  year,  which 
would  give  a  fair  and  equitable  assessment.  If  any  land 
had  paid  the  same  revenue  for  twelve  years  past,  that  was 
to  be  accepted  as  the  Settlement  rate. 

With  the  single  exception,  then,  of  Bihar,  where  in  many 
cases  former  accounts  were  not  forthcoming,  and  where 
consequently  an  estimate  of  the  produce  of  an  ordinary 
year  had  of  necessity  to  be  made,  there  was  nothing  required 
as  the  basis  of  assessment,  but  a  reference  to  old  accounts, 
with  such  adjustment  and  consolidation  of  separate  items 
and  abolition  of  objectionable  ones,  as  the  declared  prin- 
ciples of  the  Government  rendered  necessary. 

I  may  repeat  that,  in  order  to  determine  the  assessment 
of  each  estate,  no  inquiry  was  made  (as  under  the  later 
Settlement  procedure)  either  what  the  value  of  the  estate 
was,  or  what  the  produce  was.  or  what  the  '  rents '  were  as 
paid  by  the  raiyats.  Reference  was  simply  made  to  the 
old  records  of  the  lump  assessments  under  the  native 
rulers ;  and  these  were  roughly  adjusted  in  cases  where 
such  adjustment  was  needed,  and  the  Zamindar  or  other 
owner  was  directed  to  pay  this  sum. 

The  following  description  occurs  in  an  article  in  the 
Calcutta  Review  by  Mr.  Thornton,  reprinted  in  1850: — 

'  The  Collector  sat  in  his  office  in  the  sudder  (headquarter) 
station,  attended  by  his  right-hand  man,  the  kaniingo,  by 


[CHAP.  I.  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  415 

whom  he  was  almost  entirely  guided.  As  each  estate  came 
up  in  succession,  the  brief  record  of  former  Settlements  was 
read,  and  the  dehsunny  (dah-san,  ten  years)  book,  or  fiscal  register 
for  ten  years  immediately  preceding  the  cession  or  conquest, 
was  inspected.  The  kaniingo  was  then  asked  who  was  the 
Zammdar  of  the  village.  .  .  .  Then  followed  the  determination 
of  the  amount  of  revenue.  On  this  point  also,  reliance  was 
chiefly  placed  on  the  daul,  or  estimate,  of  the  kamingo,  checked 
by  the  accounts  of  past  collections  and  by  any  other  offers  of 
mere  farming  speculators  which  might  happen  to  be  put 
forward.' 

Such  an  assessment  must  have  been  almost  pure  guess- 
work ;  for,  as  the  Fifth  Report 1  says, — 

'  The  lights  formerly  derivable  from  the  Kamingo's  office 
were  no  longer  to  be  depended  on  :  and  a  minute  scrutiny  into 
the  value  of  lands  by  measurements  and  comparison  of  the 
village  accounts,  if  sufficient  for  the  purpose,  was  prohibited 
by  orders  from  home.' 

The  Report  goes  on  to  explain  how  Mr.  James  Grant's 
Analysis  of  the  Finances  raised  expectations,  and  how 
Mr.  Shore's  Minute  (June  18,  1789)  removed  many  miscon- 
ceptions ;  and  it  continues  : — 

'  A  medium  of  the  actual  produce  to  Government,  in  former 
years,  drawn  from  the  scanty  information  which  the  Collectors 
had  the  power  of  procuring,  was  the  basis  011  which  the  assess- - 
ment  of  each  estate,  whether  large  or  small,  was  ultimately 
fixed.' 

By  such  a  process,  the  assessment  was  not  so  likely  to  be 
fixed  at  an  excessive  rate,  as  the  rights  of  individuals  to 
share  in  the  profits  left  by  its  moderation,  were  to  be  over- 
looked. 

Scrutiny  was,  as  I  have  said,  prohibited,  for  fear  of 
making  the  Zamindars  distrust  the  promise  of  a  Permanent 
Settlement,  and  think  that  the  information  supplied  would 
be  used  to  enhance  the  revenue  afterwards.  The  evidence 
adduced  by  Dr.  Field  2  proves  that,  even  so  far  back  as  the 

1  Vol.  i.  p.  22.  2  Field,  p.  469  note. 


41 6  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BE1TISH    IXDIA.         [BOOK  irf- 

time  of  Warren  Hastings,  the  orders  to  collect  information 
contemplated  that  it  should  be  general ;  there  was  not  to  be 
any  '  vexatious '  extraction  of  details.  The  influence  of  this 
fear  can  still  be  clearly  traced  in  Regulation  VIII  of  1800 
(Sees.  3  and  7) — the  first  Regulation  for  compiling  a  formal 
register  of  revenue-paying  and  revenue-free  estates  (for  the 
Collector's  purposes).  The  Regulation  explains  how  the 
information  is  to  be  acquired,  and  prohibits  inquiry  into> 
rents  and  measurements  of  individual  'malguzari'  (revenue-* 
paying)  lands. 

It  is  evident  also  from  what  Hastings  wrote  in  1776,  that 
the  revenue  accounts  exhibited  by  the  kanungos  were  gene-, 
rally  believed  to  be  much  better  kept  and  more  reliable  than 
they  really  were.  It  was  believed  that  we  had  only  to  go  to 
the  pargana  abstracts  (checking  them,  when  necessary,  by 
reference  to  the  village  rent-rolls)  to  get  all  possible  in- 
formation. But,  in  fact,  nothing  about  the  real  value  of 
estates  was  found  out ;  only  the  attempt  was  made  to  dis- 
tinguish the  revenue  figures  from  the  abwabs  or  cesses 
which  had  overlaid  them1. 

§  13.    Origin  of  the  Revenue  Accounts  and  Registers. 

Before  we  can  understand  the  nature  of  the  pargana  and 
village  accounts  of  revenue  which  existed,  we  must  take 
a  brief  retrospect  of  what  the  native  system  had  been  in 
Bengal. 

In  a  general  chapter  (V)  we  have  already  gained  some 
knowledge  of  the  Mughal  system  of  administration,  and  also 
of  the  Settlements  made  under  Akbar.  It  may  therefore  be 
at  once  stated  that  it  was  under  Raja  Todar  Mai  that  the 
first  Settlement  of  Bengal  was  made  about  1582  A.D.  The 
assessment  was  exclusive  of  Orissa,  and  some  of  the  terri- 
tories in  Eastern  Bengal  that  were  only  added  to  the  pro- 
vince at  a  later  date. 

We  have  no  evidence  of  any  formal  change  in  this  assess- 

1  See  Field,  pp.  483-4.  Whole  sets  of  accounts  were  often  fabricated 
to  suit  particular  piirposes. 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  417 

ment  till  A.U.  1658,  when  Shuj'a  Khan.  Subadar  of  Bengal, 
revised  it  by  raising  the  total  from  nearly  107  lakhs  of 
rupees  to  about  131  lakhs.  The  next  rise  was  under  Ja'far 
Khan  (surnamed  Murshid  Quli  Khan).  This  revision  i^ 
curious,  because  it  exhibits  one  of  those  changes  which  are 
always  observable  in  the  Mughal  kingdoms.  An  energetic 
ruler  soon  feels  the  loss  to  the  treasury  which  contracts 
with  Zamindars  and  others  cause.  They  save  trouble, 
but  they  intercept  too  much  of  the  income.  Ja'far 
Khan,  therefore,  put  aside  the  Zamindars  and  collected 
by  his  own  'amils  and  officers1.  About  this  time  other 
countries  in  Orissa  and  Eastern  Bengal  were  annexed, 
and  came  under  assessment..  Shuj'a-ud-din,  who  succeeded, 
raised  the  assessment  in  1728,  to  over  142  lakhs.  But  in 
his  time  (as  indeed  in  his  father's)  the  impost  of  abwabs 
or  '  extras  '  had  begun.  We  then  find  the  assessment  con- 
tinually raised:  the  last  assessment  before  cession  to  the 
British  power,  was  Qasim  'Ali  Khan's,  which  was  said  to 
be  over  256  lakhs ;  but  there  is  some  doubt  whether  this 
amount  was  ever  realized2.  It  was  calculated  that  the 
regular  assessment  had  increased  about  33  per  cent.,  but 
that  the  increase  of  the  Zamindars'  exactions  from  the 
raiyats  could  not  be  less  than  50  per  cent. 

There  can  be  no  doubt  that  for  many  years  of  the  later 
rule,  assessments  were  habitually  increased,  not  by  a  Settle- 
ment or  any  new  land  valuation,  but  by  imposing  cesses 
which  were  openly  added  to  the  payments  required  from 
the  Zamindars  or  other  collectors.  The  local  kanungos 
doubtless  long  preserved  the  original  or  last  regular  land- 
assessment, — spoken  of  as  the  'tumar'  or  ''asl';  as  well  as 
the  subsequent  reassessments ;  and  they  had  also  the  'taksim ' 
or  division  of  the  total  sum  over  the  villages.  But  the 
progress  of  events  destroyed  the  practical  use  of  such 

1  He  employed  Hindus  always  as  whole    history   of   tho    assessment 

his   Revenue   officers.     He  divided  is  stated  in  Shore's  Minute,  §§  13  39 

the  country  into  thirteen  collector-  and   §  63  (Fifth  Report,  i.  p.  103,  et 

ates  called  '  Chakla,'  and  the  officers  seq.). 

put  in  charge  afterwards  became  2  Minute,  i8th  June,  1789,  §  141. 
Zamindars  in  many  instances.  The 

VOL.  I.  r  6 


41 8  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BE1TISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

accounts.      Warren  Hastings,  no   doubt,  was   quite   right 
when  he  wrote — 

'  Under  the  old  Government,  the  distribution  was  annually 
corrected  by  the  accounts  which  the  Zamindars  or  other  col- 
lectors of  the  revenue  were  bound  to  deliver  into  the  office  of 
the  Jcdnungo  or  king's  Register,  of  the  increased  or  diminished 
rents  of  their  lands  and  of  the  amount  of  their  receipts  :  but 
the  neglect  of  these  institutions,  the  wars  and  revolutions 
which  have  since  happened  in  Bengal,  have  totally  changed 
the  face  of  the  country,  and  rendered  the  tutndr  rent-roll  a 
mere  object  of  curiosity.  The  land-tax  has  therefore  been 
collected  for  these  twenty  years  past  (i.e.  since  1756)  upon 
a  conjectural  valuation  of  the  land  formed  ty  the  amount  of 
receipts  of  former  years,  and  the  opinions  [estimate  or  ldaul']  of 
officers  of  the  revenue ;  and  the  assessment  has  accordingly  been 
altered  almost  every  year/ 

This  account  is  also  borne  out  by  the  Fifth  Report 1. 

Hence  in  the  decennial  Settlement,  as  Mr.  Thornton  de- 
scribed, the  estimates  were  really  based  on  the  payments 
made  by  Zamindars  in  past  years,  increased  or  diminished 
according  to  the  opinions  of  such  local  experts  as  were  at 
hand. 

It  will  appear  hereafter  how  very  uncertain  were  the 
raiyats'  payments,  owing  to  this  system.  The  idea  that 
the  whole  body  of  raiyats  had  any  guarantee  under  native 
rule  for  payment  at  fixed  rates  for  ever,  or  that  the 
law,  when  the  Permanent  Settlement  was  made,  could  have 
easily  denned  such  rates  and  made  them  permanent  too,  is 
quite  untenable.  The  custom  varied  from  place  to  place 
and  pargana  to  pargana,  according  to  the  character  and 
influence  of  the  revenue-collectors. 

I  do  not  say  that  it  would  not  have  been  impossible  to 
ascertain  the  traditional  '  tiimar  '  rates  of  Akbar's,  or  some 
other  later  Settlement,  but  would  those  rates  have  been 
reasonable  at  the  close  of  the  century "? 2  Had  the  task  been 

1  Vol.  i.  p.  19,  at  the  bottom.  dealings  with  the  raiyats  at  p.  171. 

2  Mr.  Phillips  gives   a  perfectly       For  whatever  the  Zamindars'  sanads 
accurate  account  of  the  Zamindars'       required,  the  raiyats  were  annually 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  419 

seriously  undertaken,  it  would  have  been  necessary,  as 
was  found  in  the  Central  Provinces,  to  fix  the  raiyats 
rates  on  the  basis  of  local  inquiry  by  a  Settlement  officer 
after  a  survey  and  registration  of  fields ;  and  such  a  pro- 
ceeding no  one  could  have  dreamt  of  in  ]  790. 

§  14.    The  Siwdi  or  Abwdb. 

This  is  the  place  to  introduce  a  description  of  the 
additions  by  which  the  native  Governments  were  accus- 
tomed to  raise  the  demand  from  the  Zamindars.  The  cesse* 
were  called  ' siwai '  (lit.  'extra,'  'besides')  or  'abwab' (plural 
of  'bab,'  the  heads  or  subjects  of  taxation1).  Sometimes  the 
Arabic  term  hubub  (plural  of  hab)  is  used.  The  common 
Hindi  or  Bengali  name  is  '  mathaut.'  They  were  calculated 
on  the  same  principle  as  the  jama',  at  so  much  per  bigha, 
or  so  many  seers  in  the  maund  of  grain.  The  ruler's  local 
deputy  levied  them  on  the  Zamindar,  who  was  authorized 
to  levy  them  on  the  cultivators.  When  such  extras  got 
numerous  and  complicated,  there  would  be  a  sort  of  com- 
promise ;  the  account  would  be  re-adjusted  so  as  to  con- 
solidate the  old  rate  and  the  cesses  in  one  ;  and  this  would 
become  the  recognized  rate,  till  new  cesses  being  imposed. 
a  new  compromise  was  effected2.  In  this  way,  therefore. 

settled  with  (Land  Tenure  by  a  or  after  the  nature  of  the  tax.  Thus 
Civilian,  1832,  pp.  65,  66).  There  we  find  the  fir^t  cess  imposed  by 
were  lists  kept  by  the  patwaris  Ja'far  Khan  called  '  khasnavisi,  a 
and  kanungos,  of  village  and  par-  tax  to  support  the  Government 
gana  rates,  called  '  raibandi '  or  writers  of  '  sanads,'  &c.  ;  '  naza- 
'  nirkh.'  But  then  the  abwab  or  rana  muqarrari,'  a  rate  to  enable 
cesses  were  added,  and  from  time  the  Deputy  or  Governor  to  send  his 
to  time  consolidated  with  the  customary  annual  present  to  the 
original  rates  See  also  p.  178,  Emperor ;  the  'faujdari,  to  main- 
where  Mr.  Justice  Campbell,  de-  tain  police ;  zar-i-mathaut,'  coin- 
scribing  the  system  of  additions,  is  prising  several  items  ;  '  chauth- 
quoted.  On  the  subject  of  the  Maratha,'  a  tax  to  meet  the  loss 
practical  existence  of  I  he  old  Ak-  caused  by  the  cession  of  part  of 
barian  assessment,  I  may  refer  to  Orissa  to  the  Marathas,  &c.,  &c. 
the  undeniable  authority  of  Mr.  An  elaborate  account  of  cesses  will 
Shore's  Minute  quoted  in  the  Fifth  be  found  in  Phillips,  p.  176  et  seq. 
Report,  vol.  i.  p.  139  (Minute,  §  218").  2  See  Mr.  Justice  (Sir  G.)  Camp- 
'  The  assal  jumma  established  by  bells  judgment  in  the  great  Rent 
him  does  not  now  anywhere  exist.'  Case,  B.  L.  Reports,  Supplementary 

1  They    were    called     after    the  volume,  p.  256. 
name  of  the  ruler  inventing  them, 

E  e  2 


42O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  11. 

the  revenue  would  periodically  rise,  and  the  rates  exacted 
from  the  cultivators  rise  also,  with  more  than  corre- 
sponding frequency.  The  revenue  actually  realized  was 
thus  composed  of  the  '  'asl  jama '  plus  these  extra  charges 
(siwai),  and  was  collectively  called  the  '  mal.'  . 

The  Zamindars  naturally  enough,  not  only  raised  the 
rents  of  the  raiyats  to  a  sum  sufficient  to  cover  the  whole 
assessment,  but  imitated  the  example  by  levying  private 
cesses  for  their  own  benefit,  in  addition  to  the  '  mal.' 

§  15.    The  Sdyer. 

Besides  the  land-revenue  there  were  other  imposts  only 
indirectly  connected  with  the  land,  and  called  '  Sair,'  or, 
according  to  the  Bengali  writing,  'Sayer.'  These  weie 
taxes  on  pilgrims,  excise,  transit  and  customs  duties,  taxes 
levied  on  shopkeepers  in  bazaars  (ganj)  and  markets  (hat), 
tolls,  &c.  They  amounted  usually  to  about  one-tenth  of 
the  land-revenue  ;  they  also  included  charges  on  the  use 
of  the  products  of  the  jungle  (ban-kar),  on  fishing  (jal- 
kar,  produce  of  water),  and  on  orchards  and  fruit-trees 
(pkal-kar1.) 

It  is  easy  to  understand,  then,  that  the  total  revenue  which 
each  Zamindar  had  to  account  for  to  the  State  consisted 
of  two  kinds, — the  '  mal '  (above  described)  and  the  '  sair.' 

The  sum  under  each  head  payable  in  total  for  the 
different  '  mahals '  or  estates  included  in  the  Zamindari, 
was  placed  on  record,  and  noted  also  on  the  sanad  of 
appointment. 

1  The  Fifth  Report  (vol.   i.  p.  26)  duce  above  mentioned.    I  may  here 

describes  the  Sdyer  as  consisting  in  mention  that  (as  regards  the  mistake 

'  land   customs,    duties   and   taxes,  of  mahal  for  mal  in  the  extract) 

and  whatever  teas  collected  on  the  part  that  the  report  i  the  original  as  well 

of  the  Government  and   not  included  as  the  reprint  which  exactly  follows 

in  the  "Mehaul"  (meaning  "  mal"  it)  is  full  of  mistakes  or  misprints 

or  land-revenue. )'     But  the  Sayer  of  native  terms.    Many  of  them  are 

also  included  the  charges  on  pro-  quite  unrecognizable. 


CHAP.   I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  42  [ 

§  1 6.     Disposal  of  these  items  at  Settlement. 

The  British  Government  abolished  all  extra  cesses  or 
'  abwab '  as  they  existed  when  its  rule  began ;  and 
naturally  it  required  the  Zamindars,  under  penalty,  to 
abstain  from  levying  such  cesses  from  the  raiyats. 

As  to  the  sdyer  dues,  those  which  were  in  the  nature  of 
separate  taxes — excise,  and  the  like — the  Government  took 
into  its  own  hands,  severing  them  entirely  from  the 
land-revenue  account.  Others,  which  were  oppressive,  as 
transit  duties,  taxes  on  pilgrims  and  the  like,  it  gradually 
abolished.  Such  dues  of  this  class  as  represented  payment 
for  the  use  of  produce  of  land  or  water,  the  Government 
handed  over  to  the  landowners  to  augment  their  legitimate 
profits. 

The  good  intentions  of  the  Government  as  to  freeing  the 
raiyats  from  liability  to  vexatious  cesses  imposed  by  the 
Zamindars  for  their  own  benefit,  were  never  carried  out,  at 
least  fully.  Even  at  the  present  day  such  cesses  are  paid 
by  the  raiyats,  partly  under  the  inexorable  bond  of  custom, 
and  partly  from  a  sense  of  helplessness.  For  though  the 
authorities  would  at  once  decide  against  the  exaction,  still 
the  Zamindar  could  always  either  conceal  the  fact  or  colour 
it  in  some  way,  or  else  make  things  so  unpleasant  for  the 
raiyat,  that  he  would  rather  pay  and  hold  his  tongue1. 

1  The  private  cesses,  as  distinct  Those  who   care   to   go  into   more 

from  the  authorized  cesses  of  old  detail  will  also  find,  following  the 

days,  were   legion.     A  few  names  extract    I   make,    a   list   of  cesses, 

will     sufficiently     indicate      their  showing  the  variety  and  ingenuity 

nature  ;    thus,  we  find  the  '  man-  which  their  levy  displayed, 

gan,'  a   benevolence   to   assist   the  '  The  modern  Zamindar  taxes  his 

Zamindar  in  debt  ;    '  najai,'  a  con-  raiyats   for  every  extravagance   or 

tribution   to  cover  the   loss  when  necessity  that   circumstances   may 

some  of  the  cultivators  absconded  suggest,  as  his  predecessors   taxed 

or  defaulted  ;    '  porvani '   or    '  par-  them    in   the   past.      He   will   tax 

bani,'  a  charge  to  enable  the  Zamin-  them  for  the  support  of  his  agents 

dar  to  celebrate  '  parva,'  or  religious  of  various   kinds  and  degrees,  for 

festival    days.      There    were    also  the  payment  of  his  income-tax  and 

levies  for  embankments  (piilbandi),  his  postal  cess,  for  the  purchase  of 

for  travelling  expenses  of  the  Zamin-  an  elephant  for  his  own   use,  for 

dar,     &c.,     &c.      As     regards     the  the     cost     of     the     stationery     of 

modern  levy  of  cesses,  I  cannot  do  his  establishment,  for  the  cost  of 

better   than    quote   from    the   Ad-  printing    the    forms    of    his    rent 

ministration    Report    of    1872-73.  receipts,  for   the    payment    of   his 


422 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 


The  Regulation  XXVII  of  1793  giyes  a  somewhat  de- 
tailed account  of  the  abolished  adyer  duties1.  It  refers  to 
the  Ayin-i-Aklari  (vol.  i.  p.  359),  as  showing  that  Akbar 
had  rescinded  some,  and  that  'Alamgir  (Aurangzeb),  '  the 
last  Emperor  who  maintained  the  full  authority  of  the 
Mussulman  government,'  abolished  seventy  others.  The 
abolition  of  all  transit  duties  and  marriage  taxes,  having 
been  at  an  early  time  of  the  Company's  administration 
enjoined  (viz.  in  1772),  was  to  be  maintained.  But  so 
anxious  were  the  Government  not  to  injure  the  Zamindars, 


lawyers.  The  milkman  gives  his 
milk,  the  oilman  his  oil,  the  weaver 
his  clothes,  the  confectioner  his 
sweetmeats,  the  fisherman  his  fish. 
The  Zamindar  levies  benevolences 
from  his  raiyats  for  a  festival,  for  a 
religious  ceremony,  for  a  birth,  for 
a  marriage ;  he  exacts  fees  from 
them  on  all  changes  of  their  hold- 
ings, on  the  exchange  of  leases  and 
agreements,  and  on  all  transfers 
and  sales ;  he  imposes  a  fine  on 
them  when  he  settles  their  petty 
disputes,  and  when  the  police  or 
when  the  magistrate  visits  his 
estates ;  he  levies  black-mail  on 
them  when  social  scandals  trans- 
pire, or  when  an  offence  or  an  affray 
is  committed.  He  establishes  his 
private  pound  near  his  cutcherry, 
and  realizes  a  fine  for  every  head 
of  cattle  that  is  caught  trespassing 
on  the  raiyats'  crops.  The  abwab, 
as  these  illegal  cesses  are  called, 
pervade  the  whole  zamindari  sys- 
tem In  every  zamindari  there  is 
a  naib  ;  under  the  naib  there  are 
gumashtas ;  under  the  gumashta 
there  are  piyadas  or  peons.  The 
naib  exacts  a  '  hisabana '  or  perqui- 
site for  adjusting  accounts  annually. 
The  naibs  and  gumashtas  take  their 
share  in  the  regular  abwab  ;  they 
have  also  their  own  little  abwab. 
The  naib  occasionally  indulges  in 
an  ominous  raid  in  the  '  mofu.ssil ' 
the  plain  country  away  from  the 
town  or  headquarters').  One  rupee 
is  exacted  from  every  raiyat  who 
has  a  rental,  as  he  comes  to  proffer 
his  respects.  Collecting  peons, when 
they  are  sent  to  summon  raiyats  to 


the  landholder's  cutcherry.  exact 
from  them  daily  four  or  five  annas 
as  summon  fees.'  (P.  23,  Body  of  the 
Report.} 

On  the  other  hand,  it  should  not 
be  forgotten  that  all  this  need  only 
continue  as  long  as  the  people  them- 
selves choose ;  but  in  fact  it  is  the 
ingrained  custom  and  is  submitted 
to  as  long  as  it  is  kept  within 
customary  limits.  Every  petty 
native  official  is  born  to  think  that 
'  wasila '  (pickings  and  perquisites ) 
are  as  much  a  part  of  his  natural 
rights  as  air  to  breathe  or  water  to 
drink.  Nor  will  the  public  seriously 
object  as  long  as  he  does  his  duty 
fairly.  When  he  tries  to  take  too 
much  and  does  '  zulm '  (petty 
tyranny),  the  people  will  turn  on 
him,  and  a  conviction  for  extortion 
is  more  or  less  attainable,  according 
as  the  culprit  still  has  friends  or  is 
generally  in  the  black  books. 

There  is  also  a  bright  side  to  the 
question  :  an  amicable  understand- 
ing with  a  raiyat  for  some  cesses 
will  often  obviate  a  good  deal  of 
litigation  about  rent  enhancement. 
This  was  the  case  in  Orissa.  In 
Macneile's  Memorandum  on  the  Revenue 
Administration  (1873),  an  interesting 
notice  of  the  subject  will  be  found. 
The  people  complained  of  certain 
cesses,  and  the  Zamindar  imme- 
diately responded  by  bringing  suits 
under  the  Rent  Act  for  enhance- 
ment, and  by  measuring  their  lands 
(see  p.  408 "i. 

1  See  Markby.  Appendix,  pp. 
144-148,  and  authorities  quoted. 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  423 

that  where  the  remission  of  sdyer  caused  a  real  loss  (by 
taking  away  from  them  the  tolls  on  roads  and  ferries,  or 
the  taxes  on  bazaars  and  markets  established  on  their  lands), 
they  were  compensated. 

§  17.    Other  Alloivances. 

There  were  other  charges  and  allowances  to  be  taken 
into  account  in  the  process  of  consolidating  the  Zammdars' 
revenue  liabilities  into  one  sum.  Allowances  which  had 
been  made  to  the  Zamindar,  for  expenses  of  collection, 
office  charges,  and  the  like,  were  of  course  duly  considered  and 
deducted  in  making  up  the  totals,  where  the  expense  would 
continue  to  fall  on  the  Zamindar.  Other  payments  which 
he  formerly  had  to  make  and  received  allowance  for,  were 
now  made  by  the  State  direct,  so  that  no  deduction  had 
to  be  made  on  account  of  them.  Thus  the  payment  of 
pensions  and  allowances  to  Muhammadan  law-officers  called 
Qazis,  other  pensions,  and  the  salaries  of  Kdnungos,  were 
now  to  be  paid  direct  by  the  treasury,  and  the  Zamindai1 
was  not  concerned. 

Nor  under  the  revised  arrangements,  was  it  necessary  to 
make  the  Zamindar  any  allowance  of  land  free  of  revenue 
as  remuneration  of  office — he  had  now  become  proprietor 
of  all,  and  his  remuneration  was  amply  secured  in  other 
ways.  Such  lands  as  were  formerly  held  as  nankar,  or  by 
other  similar  name,  were  not  excluded  from  assessment  *. 

§  1 8.  Resumption  of  Invalid  Revenue-free  Holdings. 

When  the  calculation  of  the  assessment  on  each  estate 
was,  so  far,  provided  for,  there  was  still  another  important 
and  very  troublesome  matter  to  be  disposed  of.  If  in  any 
Zamindari,  a  large  portion  of  the  land  was  held  '  revenue- 
free  '  by  landholders  on  the  estate,  owing  to  royal  favour 

1  But  if  the  Zamindar  refused  to       show  a  good  title  (Reg.  VIII.  1793, 
engage,  he  would  continue  to  hold       sees.  37-39)- 
such  land  revenue  free,  if  he  could 


424  LAXD    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

and  grant,  it  is  obvious  that  the  Zamindar  could  not  be 
called  on  to  make  good  the  revenue  to  the  treasury.  But 
in  some  cases  the  Zamindar  himself  had  made  such  grants, 
and  then  he  had  to  make  good  the  State  claims  as  a  matter 
of  course ;  the  grant  he  made  operated  against  himself, 
not  against  the  State. 

It  was  however  known  that  in  the  disordered  state  of 
the  late  Government,  a  great  number  of  claims  to  hold 
revenue-free  were  really  invalid,  and  so  the  land  was  liable 
to  be  assessed,  or  as  it  is  technically  called,  'resumed.' 
This  subject  demands  a  somewhat  fuller  notice.  It  may 
now  seem  a  matter  of  dry  detail,  but  at  the  time  it  affected 
the  livelihood  of  many  hundreds,  or  indeed  thousands,  and 
involved  a  vast  amount  of  Government  revenue. 

When  a  Government  is  strong,  it  is  very  careful  about 
titles  assigning  the  revenue  of  lands  away  from  the  treasury, 
and  about  granting  lands  to  be  held  revenue-free.  It  was 
no  doubt  reckoned  a  pious  duty  to  make  such  grants  for 
mosques,  temples,  schools,  dharnasalas  (or  rest-houses),  or  to 
the  families  of  reputed  saints  or  men  of  eminent  piety  and 
learning.  But  it  is  also  an  easy  thing,  when  the  treasury- 
is  empty  through  waste  and  corruption,  to  assign  revenue- 
free  lands  to  favourites  or  to  persons  to  be  rewarded,  who 
ought  properly  to  have  received  cash  pensions  or  life- 
grants.  In  short,  though  there  is  a  legitimate  use  of 
revenue-free  grants  which  the  oriental  mind  approves,  still 
it  is  easy  to  abuse  the  institution  and  to  forget  that  in  all 
cases  they  mean  freeing  one  set  of  persons  from  taxation  at 
the  expense  of  others  who  have,  in  the  end,  to  make  up  the 
loss.  In  the  decline  of  the  Mughal  empire,  not  only  were 
such  grants  multiplied,  but  a  great  many  of  them  were 
made  by  subordinate  officials  who  had  no  real  authority : 
not  only  so,  but  a  considerable  number  of  grants  were  held 
under  no  authority  at  all,  or  were  supported  by  forged 
title-deeds. 

It  was  therefore  necessary  in  the  proclamation  of  1793,  to 
announce  that  a  scrutiny  of  revenue-free  claims  would  be 
made.  '  The  Governor-General  in  Council  will  impose  such 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  425 

assessment  as  he  may  deem  equitable,  on  all  lands  at  present 
alienated1  and  paying  no  public  revenue,  which  have  been, 
or  may  prove  to  be,  held  under  illegal  or  invalid  titles.'  The 
grants  are  spoken  of  as '  lakhiraj  '  grants  ;  and  the  lands  were 
'  lakhiraj  '  lands.  The  name  is  derived  from  two  Arabic 
words,  'la,'  the  negative,  and  'khiiaj,'  revenue  or  land-tax. 
These  grants  had  been  either  made  by  royal  authority 
(badshahi),  in  which  case  they  were  dealt  with  under  Regu- 
lation XXXVII  of  1793,  or  'hukami'  (incorrectly  hukmi), 
i.  e.  made  by  authorities  other  than  the  king,  called  in  the 
Regulations  '  non-badshahi,'  and  these  are  dealt  with  in 
Regulation  XIX  of  1793.  It  was  the  latter  class  that  were 
the  most  likely  to  be  doubtful  in  origin  ;  properly  speaking, 
they  were  all  invalid.  The  Regulation  recites  that  if  a 
Zamindar  had  made  such  a  grant  (in  past  days)  it  was 
considered  void.  On  the  subject  of  grants  assumed  to  be 
made  by  '  officers  appointed  to  the  temporary  superintend- 
ence of  the  collection  of  the  revenue,  under  pretext  that 
the  land  was  for  pious  or  charitable  uses/  some  were  no 
doubt  bond  fide  ;  but,  says  the  preamble,  '  in  general,  they 
were  given  for  the  personal  advantage  of  the  grantee,  or 
with  a  view  to  the  clandestine  appropriation  of  the  produce 
to  the  grantor,'  or  were  given  for  a  money  consideration  to 
him.  Government  settled  the  Zamindar' s  estate  jama' 
without  reference  to  such  grants  and  exclusive  of  them. 
Consequently  it  was  at  liberty  to  'resume,'  i.e.  to  impose 
an  assessment  on,  all  that  were  invalid.  In  determining 
to  do  this,  Government  generously  enough  said  that  if  the 
grant  was  less  than  100  bighds  in  extent,  the  assessment 
would  not  be  for  the  benefit  of  Government  but  for  the  estate 
— would  be  in  fact  claimable  as  rent.  It  is  said  that  both 
these  Regulations  failed, — as  might  be  expected  in  the 

1  This  phrase  '  alienated '  is  com-  in    that    case    '  alienation '    would 

moner  in  Bombay  and  Madras  than  be  used  in  an  ordinary  sense.     But 

elsewhere  ;    it  refers  rather  to  the  where  the  land  did  not  belong  to 

alienation  of  the  revenue  from  the  Government,   '  alienation '  referred 

treasury   than   to   the   land   itself.  to  giving  up  the  revenue  demand, 

Of  course  Government  might  have  and  the  consequent  lien  or  ultimate 

land  at  disposal,  and  grant  both  it  title,  which  Government  has  over, 

and  the  revenue  due   on  it ;   and  or  to,  all  land  whatsoever. 


426  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

absence  of  a  survey  and  any  sufficient  land  records ;  for  I 
suppose  that  by  '  failing '  it  is  meant  that  the  claims  did 
not  come  to  light.  The  law  was  accordingly  revised  by 
Regulation  II  of  1819,  and  again  by  Regulation  III  of 
1 828.  This  latter  enactment  appointed  a  Court  of  '  Special 
Commissioners ' ;  and  after  they  had  done  what  they  could 
for  many  years,  they  were  abolished  by  order  of  Govern- 
ment in  1846.  The  more  modern  procedure  of  Registration 
and  Certificate,  which  will  be  described  in  the  sequel,  have 
at  length  done  everything  that  is  wanted. 

The  Zamindars  who  were  thus  empowered  to  '  resume ' 
all  the  petty  estates  for  their  own  benefit,  were  long  loath 
to  do  so.  No  doubt  where  the  '  mu'afi '  was  for  a  pious 
purpose,  it  would  have  been  contrary  to  the  public  feeling 
to  resume ;  but  if  many  were  created,  as  asserted,  either  as 
a  means  of  raising  money  or  otherwise  irregularly,  it  is  not 
so  easy  to  see  why  they  should  have  been  tenderly  dealt 
with ;  at  a  later  date,  when  the  Zamindaris  changed  hands, 
successors  were  not  so  particular,  and  resumption  suits 
became  common  *. 

§  19.    Principles  of  Resumption. 

In  order  to  simplify  matters,  all  grants  made  previous 
to  the  i2th  August,  1765  (date  of  grant  of  the  diwdni), 

1  See  this  explained  in  Markby,  sequently,    everybody    asserting   a 

p.    7.     I  take   occasion  to  observe  grant  or  claim  not  to  pay,  is  surely 

that  I  do  not  quite  follow  the  learned  most  naturally  the  person  who  has 

author    in    his    remark    that    the  to  take   the   burden  of  proof  and 

Regulations  gave  an  extraordinary  produce  his  exemption.     It  may  be 

facility  to  the  estate-holder  to  re-  that  he  has  no  grant,  but  has  been 

sume,  or  that  they  laid  the  burden  allowed  to  go  free  so  long,  that  now 

of  proof  on  the  persons  claiming  to  it  would  be  hard  to  charge  him  ; 

hold  free  in  a  manner  contrary  to  but  that  is  a  matter  of  the  nature 

the   usual  rule  ;    but  perhaps   the  of  his  title  ;  it  is  beside  the  question 

remark    is   due  to   the   confusion,  of  who  should  take  the  burden  of 

which  undoubtedly  is  traceable  in  proof  in  the  first  instance.     On  the 

the  law,  between  assessing  revenue  other  hand,  if  it  was  a  question  of 

or  rent  fas  the  case  might  bet  and  ejecting  from   the   land,   then   the 

ejecting  the  claimant  from  the  land.  burden  is,  of  course,  the  other  way. 

As  far  as  the  claim  to  rent  is  con-  The  man  in  possession  on  an  appa- 

cerned,   the    rent  was   only  what  rent  title  is  to  remain  until  some 

had  before  been  the  State  revenue  one  else  proves  his  superior  title  or 

demand  ;  every  acre   of  cultivated  proves  that  the  other  has  no  busi- 

land  is  bound  to  pay  this  ;    con-  ness  there. 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  427 

were  recognized  as  valid  without  question,  by  whatever 
authority  they  might  have  been  made,  and  whether  in 
writing  or  without  it:  the  only  condition  was,  that  the 
claimant  (or  his  predecessor)  should  have  actually,  and 
bond  fide,  obtained  possession  of  the  land  so  granted  pre- 
vious to  the  date  mentioned,  and  that  the  land  had  not 
already  been  declared  liable  to  pay  revenue  by  the  officers, 
or  under  the  orders,  of  Government. 

Grants  subsequent  to  1765,  and  before  the  date  of  the 
decennial  Settlement  (taken  as  December  ist,  I79O1),  were 
invalid  (with  a  few  unimportant  exceptions).  So  also  were 
grants  after  December  1790. 

The  provisions  of  both  Regulations  refer  only  to  the 
revenue  question,  not  to  the  right  in  the  soil,  which,  if 
disputed,  could  be  settled  in  the  Civil  Court. 

§  20.    Terms  of  Settlement  for  such  Lands. 

When  a  grant  lapsed  to  Government  or  was  resumed, 
the  Settlement  was  to  be  made,  in  perpetuity,  with  the 
person  entitled  to  hold  the  land,  which  became  an  in- 
dependent '  taluq  ' — a  separate  proprietary  estate. 

In  the  case  of  grants  made  between  1765  and  ist  Decem- 
ber, 1790,  Section  7  of  Regulation  XIX  of  1793  contem- 
plated certain  differences  as  to  amount  of  assessment, 
which  are  rather  complicated ;  and  it  is  now  of  no  impor- 
tance to  go  into  them.  These  rules  applied  also  (Section  8) 
to  grants  resumed  in  favour  of  Zamindars,  but  with  certain 
directions  as  to  ascertaining  the  revenue  without  expense 
to  the  grantee. 

The  Government  seems  to  have  been  more  anxious  to 
facilitate  the  resumption  by  the  landholders  of  the  invalid 
lakhiiaj  grants  of  less  than  100  bighas,  than  it  was  to 
secure  to  the  State  the  larger  invalid  grants.  Section  10 
invalidated  all  grants  since  December  1790;  so  that  if  the 
Zamindar  himself,  or  a  predecessor,  had  made  the  grant,  he 

1  1198  Fasli  era  of  Bengal  (see  Book  I,  chap.  i.  p.  13). 


428  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

could  undo  his  own  act l.  The  grant  was  invalid  as  regards 
the  revenue  (become  the  rent),  and  as  regards  the  soil  also, 
if  it  purported  to  include  the  latter:  'and  no  length  of 
possession  shall  be  hereafter  considered  to  give  validity  to 
any  such  grant.' 

§  21.  Procedure. — Limitation. 

The  Settlement-holder  (or  manager,  should  the  estate 
happen  to  be  held  'Mas')  was  empowered  to  levy  rent 
(or  to  eject  an  unentitled  holder  of  the  land)  without  any 
action  in  Court  or  notice  to  any  Revenue  Officer  ;  but  this 
applied  only  to  invalid  grants  dating  after  1790.  In  order 
to  assess,  or  to  eject  from  a  grant  previous  to  1790,  a 
regular  suit  was  at  first  required  (Section  n). 

Section  30  of  Regulation  II  of  1819  endeavoured  to 
facilitate  resumptions  of  grants  previous  to  1790,  by  saying 
that  the  application  to  resume  might  be  presented  direct  to 
the  Collector,  or  if  presented  to  a  Civil  Court,  should  be 
referred  to  the  Collector  for  an  opinion  ;  but  this  was  found 
inconvenient  and  was  repealed  in  1862  (Bengal  Act  VII). 

It  should  be  remarked  that  the  landholders  at  no  time 
largely  availed  themselves  of  the  summary  power  given  in 
Section  10  of  Regulation  XIX  of  1793,  but  preferred  to 
resort  to  the  Civil  Court  even  when  the  practice  of  resump- 
tion became  more  general2.  In  consequence,  Section  30 
of  Regulation  II 'of  1819  was  frequently  misapplied:  it 
was  not  intended  to  apply  to  cases  under  Section  10  of 
Regulation  XIX  (regarding  which  no  suit  at  all  was  needed, 
and  therefore  if  one  was  filed  it  was  the  landholder's  own 
pleasure) ;  it  was  designed  to  facilitate  inquiry  as  to  grants 
before  1790,  for  which  a  suit  VMS  needed ;  but  it  got  applied 


1  The    motive   for  this   was   the  his  renf),  and  so  contract  himself  out 

principle — which   is  not  unknown  of   the  power   of   meeting    his   own 

in    other  revenue    laws — that  the  revenue  engagements  to  the  Go vern- 

revenue-payer     ought    not    to    be  ment. 

allowed    (or    encouraged)     impru-  2  See  Markby,  p.  8,  and  the  cases 

dently  to  give  away  his  lands  free  there  quoted, 
of  the  revenue  (which  now  became 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  429 

to  both,  till  the  Privy  Council  ruled  that  it  could  not  legally 
be  so. 

The  power  given  under  Section  10,  above  referred  to, 
was,  however,  taken  away  by  Act  X  of  1859,  and  the  land- 
holder was  required  to  file  his  suit,  which,  however,  lay  to 
the  Collector  as  a  Revenue  Court :  and  when  this  Act  was 
repealed  by  Act  VIII  of  1869,  the  reference  was  re-trans- 
ferred to  the  Civil  Court,  as  in  all  other  matters. 

It  was  also  ultimately  ruled  by  the  Privy  Council,  that 
notwithstanding  the  terms  above  quoted,  the  Government 
right  to  resume  was  subject  to  the  law  of  limitation,  and 
that,  by  parity  of  reasoning,  so  was  the  Zamindar's 1.  The 
modern  limitation  law  (1877.  Act  XV)  sets  the  question 
at  rest,  since  Article  130  of  Schedule  II  expressly  gives 
twelve  years  as  the  limit  for  a  private  resumption  suit ; 
and  all  suits  by  the  Secretary  of  State  are  limited  to  sixty 
years. 

§  22.    '  Tkdnaddri  Lands.' 

Among  other  '  resumptions  '  it  may  be  proper  to  mention 
that  the  Zamindars  were  relieved  from  the  responsibility  of 
maintaining  police  forces,  and  so  lands  held  free  under  the 
name  of  '  thanadari,'  to  provide  for  them,  were  resumed  and 
assessed.  The  '  chakaran '  lands  held  for  village  service — 

Q 

i.e.  for  village  watchmen  or  '  chaukidars '  and  '  bulahirs  ' —  p^t  \q ri 
are  not  included  in  this.  of  J793- 


§  23.    The  Waste  Lands. 

Although  we  gather,  from  the  early  reports  and  his- 
tories, that,  at  the  date  of  the  Permanent  Settlement,  a  very 
large  proportion  of  Bengal  was  uncultivated  and  covered 
with  jungle,  the  matter  attracted  no  definite  attention. 

1  This  was  because,  in  the  limit-  to  authorize  a  suit  barred  by  the 

ation  law  then  in  force  (^Regulation  various  periods  prescribed  ;  so  that 

II  of  18051,  it  was   provided  that  the    terms    quoted    above,    out    of 

'nothing   ...   in    any  part  of  the  Section  10, Regulation  XIX  of  1793, 

existing  Regulations '  should  be  held  were  over-ridden. 


43O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  11. 

Perhaps  it  was  less  prominent  in  the  central  districts  that 
formed  the  important  revenue-paying  tracts. 

At  all  events,  it  was  assumed  that  the  boundaries  of 
Zamindaris  or  other  estates  were  known.  And  all  that  was 
within  the  boundary  belonged  to  the  proprietor,  whether 
waste  or  cultivated ;  so  that  many  fine  '  sal '  forests  and 
other  such  lands  have  become  included  as  private  property, 
though,  in  the  absence  of  any  detailed  survey  or  register 
of  fields,  it  was  quite  impossible,  in  most  cases,  for  any 
one  to  tell  whether  the  waste  was  really  part  of  the  '  estate ' 
or  not. 

That  some  waste  was  so,  goes  without  saying ;  for  the 
extension  of  the  Zamindar's  income,  by  bringing  under  the 
plough  lands  that  were  uncultivated,  was  one  of  the  means 
most  frequently  spoken  of,  by  which  his  wealth  was  to  be 
assured. 

I  do  not  find  any  mention  of  '  excess  waste  lands '  (i.  e. 

not  included  in  any  one's  estate)  till  Regulation  II  of  1819. 

Even   then   nothing  is   said   about   the  want  of  title  of 

persons  who  had  squatted  or  occupied ;  only  it  is  said  such 

R«g.  II  of  lands  were  liable  to  be  assessed  to  revenue.     The  Regula- 

1819860.3.  £jon  referre(j  especially,  as  instances  of  such  lands,  to — 

(«)  lands  cultivated  in  the  Sundarbans1  (these  were 
chiefly  on  the  higher  parts  of  the  delta — better 
protected  from  inundation,  and  probably  exten- 
sions or  encroachments  from  the  permanently 
cultivated  estates  inland) ; 

(&)  '  chars '   and  islands   formed  in  rivers ;   and   other 

alluvial  accretions  since  the  decennial  Settlement ; 

(c)  lands   which   did  not  come   under   the  Settlement 

specially  let  out  on  clearing  leases  by  Collectors. 

The  assessment  was  to  be  on   the    'principles   of  the 

General  Regulations,'  and  therefore  permanent  (see  Section 

6  of  Regulation  I  of  1793). 

1  Avast  tract  of  forest  intersected  24-Pergunnahs,  Khulna  and  Bakir- 

by  myriads   of  tidal  streams   and  ganj,  between  the  main  mouth  of 

creeks,  and  forming  the   southern  the  Hughli   on  the  west  and  the 

or  delta  portion  of  the  districts  of  Megna  river  on  the  east 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  43 1 

The  matter  was  better  provided  for  at  a  later  time. 
Regulation  III  of  1828  recites  in  the  preamble  that — 

*  Commissioners  have  likewise,  from  time  to  time,  been  ap- 
pointed, under  the  orders  of  Government,  to  maintain  and 
enforce  the  public  rights  in  different  districts,  in  which  exten- 
sive tracts  of  country,  unowned  and  unoccupied  at  the  time  of 
the  Permanent  Settlement,  are  now  liable  to  assessment,  or, 
'being  still  tvaste,  belong  to  the  State.' 

This  is  the  first  legislative  declaration  I  have  found  on 
the  subject  of  the  title  to  waste  lands  (see  Chap.  V,  p.  236). 
And  while  it  also  follows  from  this  that  all  lands  '  owned ' 
and  occupied  were  liable  to  be  assessed  (and  that  per- 
manently), no  others  could  claim  a  Permanent  assessment. 
In  other  words,  the  benefit  of  the  Regulations  extended  to 
estates  then  occupied,  even  without  title,  not  to  all  that  might 
thereafter  be  created  by  new  occupation  and  cultivation. 

We  shall  have  occasion  to  notice  how  waste  lands  were 
disposed  of  in  several  instances  in  the  sequel.  Here  it  is 
sufficient  to  notice  what  the  Settlement  Regulations  in- 
tended on  the  subject. 

§  24.    Resume  of  the  Zaminddrs  Position  under 
the  Permanent  Settlement. 

The  result  of  these  various  provisions  may  now  be 
summarized. 

(a)  The  Zamindar  was  only  required  to  pay  one  sum, 

with  no  extra  cesses  on  the  land. 

(6)  The  'abicdb'  were  abolished;  and  he  was  not  allowed, 
in  his  turn,  to  levy  such  charges  on  his  raiyats. 

(c)  The   '  Sayer '   were   not   charged    in    the   revenue  : 

some  items  were  left  to  benefit  the  estate,  others 
were  abolished,  and  others  (excise,  road-tolls,  &c.) 
were  taken  out  of  the  land-revenue  account 
altogether  and  separately  collected  by  the  Govern- 
ment. 

(d)  The  Zamindar  was  not  allowed  to  have  any  deduc- 


43 2  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

tions  from  his  sum  total  on  the  plea  of  private 
lands  revenue-free  as  '  nankar '  or  subsistence 
allowance. 

(e)  Nor  to  claim  deductions  on  the  ground  of  grants  of 
land  revenue-free  made  by  the  former  Government 
or  by  its  officers,  unless  these  were  valid  on  the 
terms  prescribed  by  law.  All  others  were  're- 
sumed' and  assessed.  This  did  not  affect  the 
Zamindars  if  the  'resumed'  grant  was  over  100 
bighas,  because  such  were  treated  as  separate 
estates  and  assessed.  But,  as  regards  smaller 
grants,  the  Zamindar  got  the  benefit  of  the  re- 
sumption, and  it  was  left  to  him  to  resume  or 
not,  under  the  prescribed  procedure,  as  he  chose. 

(/)  The  Zamindar  was  not  allowed  deductions  for 
pensions,  pay  of  Qdzis,  or  of  Kdnungos,  or  for 
police  lands — because  the  State  no  longer  required 
him  to  meet  any  such  charges. 

§  25.    Profit  left  to  Zaminddr. 

The  Settlement  thus  made  with  the  Zamindars  for  one 
consolidated  lump  sum  of  revenue,  was  supposed,  in  theory, 
to  represent  nine-tenths  of  what  they  received  directly  in 
rent  from  the  raiyats,  the  remaining  tenth  being  allowed 
to  them  for  their  trouble  and  responsibility1.  In  reality, 

1  See   Regulation  VIII   of  1793,  the  peons  or  messengers,  to  keep 

Section  77  ;  and  Whinfield's  Revenue  up  the  office,  &c.,  &c. 

Law   and  Practice   of  Bengal   1,1874',  If  anything  is  wanting  to  show 

p.  n.     That  was  also  the   theory  how  utterly  unlike  a  '  landlord '  th3 

under  the  native  rule.    The  Zamin-  Zamindar  originally  was,  this   will 

dars  were  to  pay  in  the  whole  of  supply  the  want.     He  got  nothing  in 

their  collections,  less   only  a  per-  the  nature  of  rent  from  the  land.     The 

centage     allowed     them     for     the  raiyat  took  the  balance  of  its  yield 

trouble  (called  mushahara\  together  after  paying  the  Government  share 

with  some  allowances  (called  '  maz-  (the  balance   to   him   being    often 

kiirat'),    for    charitable     and    re-  small  enough),  and  the  Zamindar 

ligious  purposes — to  keep  lamps  at  had  to  account  to  Government  for 

the  tombs  of  saints,  to  preserve  the  the  whole  of  his  collections,  getting 

'  qadam  rasul '  or  foot-prints  of  the  back   only  such   allowance   as  the 

Prophet,  to  give  khairat  or  alms  to  State   made   him   to   keep   up    his 

the    poor,    to    pay   the   village   or  office,  &c.,  and  to  remunerate  him 

minor  revenue  officials   to  support  for  his  trouble.    Whatever  he  made 


CHAP,  i.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  433 

the  Zamindar,  when  made  landlord,  got  all  the  increase  of 
rents  (as  the  raising  of  rents  gradually  came  to  be  under- 
stood), and,  in  any  case,  he  got  the  benefit  of  all  extension 
of  cultivation,  as  well  as  all  the  '  sayer '  items  from 
fisheries,  fruit,  grazing,  &c.,  and  the  benefit  of  all  invalid 
grants  (under  100  bighas)  which  he  chose  to  resume.  And 
with  all  these  sources  of  income,  it  very  soon  came  to  pass 
that  the  revenue  payment  was  nothing  at  all  resembling 
nine-tenths  of  the  total  receipts  from  the  estate. 

§  26.    Settlement  Arrangements  regarding  the  Zaminddrs' 
dealings  with  the  Raiyats. 

The  Settlement  procedure  certainly  involved  very  little 
action  with  reference  to  the  raiyats, — the  great  body  of 
agriculturists, — now  reduced  to  a  secondary  position  under 
the  Zamindars.  The  Regulations  may  be  said  to  have 
hoped  much  and  provided  little.  What  they  did,  however, 
though  it  might,  in  some  respects,  be  conveniently  noticed 
here,  had  better  be  passed  over,  for  the  reason  that  I  must 
recur  to  the  subject  (of  landlord  and  tenant)  at  a  later 
stage,  and  it  is  an  object  to  avoid  repetition.  I  will  there- 
fore simply  reserve  the  provisions  of  the  Regulation  regard- 
ing raiyats  or  tenants  to  a  subsequent  chapter. 

§27.    Registration  of  Landed  Estates. 

It  will  next  be  asked,  what  attempt  was  made  to  prepare 
registers  of  estates  and  records  of  other  rights  under  the 
Permanent  Settlement  ? 

As  there  was  no  survey  or  demarcation  of  estates,  the 
only  thing  that  could  be  done  was  to  prepare  a  descriptive 
register,  showing  the  names  of  estates  and  the  villages,  and 
local  subdivisions  of  land  included  in  it.  Regulation 

for     himself     was     derived     from  rulers  contracted  with  the  Zamin- 

revenue-free    land, — that    held    as  dar  for  a  fixed  sum,  this  soon  came 

'  nankar,'  or  from  the  levy  of  un-  to  be  regarded  as  something  apart 

authorized  cesses.     In   time,  it   is  from  the  total  rents  paid  in  by  the 

true,  he  came  to  get  something  very  raiyats. 
like  rent.     When  the  later  Native 

VOL.  I.  F  f 


434  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

XLVIII  of  1 793  contemplated  a  general  register  of  estates 
paying  revenue  immediately  to  Government.  Each  estate 
was  to  be  described  by  name,  and  it  was  to  be  mentioned 
whether  it  consisted  of  a  village,  a  tappa  (group  of  villages), 
or  a  pargana  ;  whether  it  was  a  jdgir  grant,  or  a  taluq,  or 
any  other  special  form  of  grant  (of  which  we  shall  hear 
when  we  come  to  the  chapter  on  Tenures).  If  the  estate 
had  been  partitioned,  the  shares  were  to  be  specified.  And 
should  portions  of  estates  lie  in  different  districts,  the  term 
'  qismat '  (section  or  fragment),  was  to  be  prefixed. 

The  registers  were  also  supposed  to  show  the  local  name 
and  the  (nominal)  area  of  each  village  and  pargana,  with 
the  names  of  the  landlord,  farmer  of  rent,  &c. 

The  registers  were  to  be  renewed  every  five  years  ;  and  a 
register  noting  intermediate  changes  in  the  proprietorship, 
partitions  and  other  like  occurrences  affecting  the  estates, 
was  to  be  kept  up. 

To  facilitate  this  work,  the  Civil  Courts  were  to  send 
copies  of  all  decrees  which  affected  land,  and  the  Board  of 
Revenue  were  to  notify  sales  made  under  the  Revenue  Re- 
covery laws.  Registrars  of  deeds  were  also  to  send  notices, 
and  proprietors  were  to  give  due  information  of  transfers  of 
property,  failing  which  they  became  liable  to  penalty. 

Separate  registers  were  kept  up  of  revenue-free  estates, 
and  of  those  which,  being  invalid,  were  resumed  and  assessed 
to  revenue. 

These  rules  were  first  revised  by  Regulation  VIII  of 
1 800,  which  mentions  the  failure J  which  had  occurred,  and 

1  I  do  not  mean,  by  the  failure  tenures.     But  the  task  was  a  diffi- 

of  the  early  records,  to  imply  that  cult  one :  there  was  delay  in  carrying 

the  authors  of  the  Settlement  pur-  it  out.     English  ideas  of  the  rights 

posely  neglected  the  work.     On  the  of  a  landlord  and  of  the  advantage 

contrary,  '  The  original  intention,'  of    non-interference,    began    more 

says  Sir  G.  Campbell, 'of  the  framers  and   more    to    prevail    in    Bengal, 

of  the  Permanent  Settlement,  was  The  Executive  more  and  more  ab- 

to  record  all  rights.     The  kanungos  negated  the  functions  of  recording 

and  patwaris  were   to  register  all  rights  and  protecting  the  inferior 

holdings,    all    transfers,   all    rent-  holders,  and  left  everything  to  the 

rolls,    and    all    receipts    and    pay-  judicial    tribunals.     The    patwaris 

ments  ;  and  every  five  years  there  fell  into  disuse,  or  became  the  mere 

was  to  be  filed  in  the  public  offices  servants    of   the    Zamindars  :    the 

a   complete   register    of   all    land-  kanungos  were  abolished.  No  record 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  435 

directed,  among  other  changes,  that  the  registers  should  be 
kept  by  parganas.  There  is  no  occasion  to  go  into  detail, 
as  the  rules  have  long  since  been  repealed.  They  never 
were,  or  could  have  been,  fully  carried  out,  so  impossible  is 
it  to  manage  Records  of  rights  without  a  survey. 

§  28.    Registration  of  Under-tenures. 

But  no  registration  of  under-tenures,  or  record  of  the 
nature  and  extent  of  the  rights  of  cultivators  and  lessees 
subordinate  to  the  landlords,  was  made.  And  this  was  a 
serious  want,  because  after  all  the  '  taluq '  grantees  and 
others  had  been  'separated'  (and  so  recorded  as  estate- 
holders  on  their  own  account),  there  must  have  remained  a 
large  number  of  'dependent'  taluqs,  'muqarrari '  and  '  istim- 
rari'  lessees,  and  others  (of  whom  we  shall  afterwards  hear), 
whose  rights  were  certainly  above  those  of  tenants,  and 
ought  therefore  to  have  been  recorded.  The  Settlement 
Regulations,  however,  though  by  no  means  ignoring  such 
rights,  or  wishing  to  destroy  them,  thought  it  enough  to 
assume  that  there  were  fixed  terms  of  the  grant  by  which 
the  tenure  originated,  and  to  declare  these  binding.  The 
want  of  proper  authoritative  registers  of  such  tenures  and 
their  holders  long  continued ;  and  it  is  only  of  late  years 
that  the  registration  has  been  put  on  a  better  footing.  A 
notice  of  the  present  practice,  however,  belongs  to  a  later 
stage  of  our  study. 

§  29.    The  means  of  recovering  the  Revenue. — Sale-laws. 

I  have  already  alluded  to  the  first  indication  of  the  SALE 
LAWS.  The  Government  had  dealt  liberally  with  the 
Zamindars;  it  had  given  them  a  valuable  property,  and 
secured  them  by  a  permanent  limit  to  the  State  revenue 
demand.  It  was,  therefore,  thought  only  fair  that,  in 

of  the   rights   of   the   raiyats   and  tained  for  a  time,  fell  into  disuse.' 

inferior  holders  was    ever    made ;  (Sir  G.  Campbell's   Land  System   of 

and  even  the  quinquennial  register  India — Cobden  Club  Papers,  p.  148). 
of  superior  rights,  which  was  main- 

F  f  2 


436  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

return,  the  State  revenue  should  be  paid  with  the  unfail- 
ing punctuality  required  to  meet  the  pressing  needs  of  the 
treasury ;  and  it  was  held,  without  question,  that  if  the 
landlord  did  not  or  could  not,  pay,  he  must  be  removed 
at  once,  by  the  sale  of  the  whole  or  a  part  of  the  estate,  as 
circumstances  should  indicate.  In  those  early  days,  the 
Revenue  instalments  were  payable  monthly;  and  it  was 
held  that  failure  to  pay  any  month's  due  justified  an 
immediate  sale1.  But  in  1799  the  rule  was  relaxed.  Regu- 
lation VII  provided  that  no  sale  should  take  place  till  the 
end  of  the  year,  and  thus  give  more  time.  And,  as  the 
landlord  was  dependent  on  the  recovery  of  his  rents  for 
his  ability  to  pay,  a  summary  power  of  distraint  for  rent 
was  given  him.  The  sanction  of  the  Board  of  Revenue  was 
also  required  before  a  sale  was  ordered  ;  and  only  such  part 
of  the  estate  as  would  suffice  was  actually  sold.  Interest 
was  not  charged  on  arrears ;  and  this  is  still  the  law. 

The  law  of  summary  distraint  was  oppressive  to  the 
raiyats,  but  we  are  not  concerned  with  that  here,  but  only 
with  the  law  for  recovery  of  arrears  of  revenue  and  its 
effect  on  the  system.  As  the  revenue  got  lighter  and 
lighter,  and  the  landlords  had  more  and  more  power 
against  the  rent-payers,  it  is  hardly  to  be  wondered  at  that 
the  provisions  against  revenue  default  should  have  been 
made  more  stringent.  The  next  Regulation  of  importance 
was  Regulation  XI  of  1822,  which  made  it  no  longer  neces- 
sary to  issue  process  of  attachment  or  try  any  arrangement 
for  direct  collection,  before  putting  up  the  estate  (or  part 
of  it)  to  sale. 

This  law  lasted  till  1841,  when  Act  XII  replaced  it ;  this 
in  its  turn  was  repealed  in  1 845  ;  and  Act  XI  of  1 859  began 
what  I  may  call  the  '  modern  sale  law ' — to  which  reference 
will  be  made  in  the  chapter  headed  '  Revenue  Business  and 
Procedure.' 

1  Kaye,  p.  185.    As  a  matter  of  sale  of  his  property.    Regulation  III 

fact,   the   first   Regulation,  XV  of  of  1794  abolished  the  imprisonment 

1793,  prescribed  the  ordinary  pro-  of   the  defaulting  proprietor,  and 

cess  against   debtors,  viz.   the  im-  substituted  a  power  of  immediate 

prisonment  of  the  person,  and  the  sale  of  his  estate. 


CHAP.  I.]  THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT.  437 

§  30.    Voiding  of  existing  encumbrances  ivhen  the 
Estate  was  sold. 

One  feature  of  the  sale  law,  which  was  early  allowed 
to  be  necessary,  deserves  to  be  mentioned.  Besides  the 
under-tenures,  which  existed  in  the  shape  of  dependent 
taluqs  and  other  privileged  holdings,  it  became  the  custom 
with  the  landlords  to  divest  themselves  of  the  trouble  of 
management,  by  farming  out  portions  of  their  estate. 
The  detail  of  this  will  appear  later  on,  but  it  is  obvious 
that  the  result  was  to  create,  on  most  estates,  numerous 
under-tenures.  All  these  were  so  many  encumbrances 
on  the  estate ;  and  if,  when  the  landlord's  interest  was 
sold  for  arrears,  all  these  remained  valid,  the  net  interest 
saleable  would,  in  all  probability,  not  fetch  enough  at 
auction  to  realize  the  arrear.  As  early  as  Regulation  Reg.  XLiv 
XLIV  of  1793,  we  find  that  when  an  estate  is  auctioned  for 
arrears — 

'  all  engagements  which  such  proprietor  shall  have  contracted 
with  dependent  taluqdars  whose  taluqs  may  be  situated  in  the 
lands  sold;  as  also  all  leases  to  under- farmers,  and  pattds  to 
raiyats  [with  certain  exceptions]  ....  shall  stand  cancelled  from 
the  day  of  sale,  and  the  purchaser  ....  shall  be  at  liberty  to 
collect  from  such  dependent  taluqdars,  &c.,  whatever  the  former 
proprietor  would  have  been  entitled  to  demand,  according  to 
the  established  usages  and  rates  of  the  pargana,  &c.,  had  the 
engagements  so  cancelled  never  existed.' 

This  did  not  apply  to  absolute  alienations  (e.g.  to  reverse 
a  sale  actually  made),  nor  to  leases  to  Europeans,  of  lands 
for  dwelling-houses,  gardens,  or  manufactories ;  nor  did  it 
interfere  with  the  assessment  imposed  by  the  Permanent 
Settlement1. 

But  this  wholesale  avoidance  of  contracts  made  by  the 
defaulting  landlord,  was  soon  recognized  to  be  excessive. 
We  gradually  find  new  Regulations  softening  the  terms. 

1  So  that,  when  the  estate  was  Permanent  Settlement  would,  in 
sold,  the  Collector  could  not  offer  it  many  instances,  have  been  got  rid 
at  a  new  assessment,  otherwise  the  of. 


LAND   SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

First,  Regulation  I  of  1801  protected  arrangements  that 
might  have  been  concluded  during  the  year  previous  to 
the  date  of  sale.  Next,  Regulation  XI  of  1822  modified  the 
general  rule.  It  no  longer  provided  that  such  leases,  &c., 
'  stood  cancelled,'  but  only  that  they  were  '  Halle  to  be 
annulled'  by  the  purchaser:  and  it  was  also  expressly 
allowed  that  five  classes  of  persons  who  had  an  heritable 
and  transferable  interest,  or  raiyats  who  had  a  right  of 
occupancy,  could  not  have  their  engagements  annulled. 
This  was  perhaps  implied,  but  not  stated,  by  the  earlier 
law. 

The  Sale  laws  of  1841  and  1845  are  very  much  the  same 
in  these  respects,  but  expressly  declare  the  right  of  the 
purchaser  to  enhance  the  rents  of  all  under-tenures  and 
(after  notice  given)  to  eject  tenants,  subject  to  exceptions, 
five  in  number. 

Nothing  further  was  changed  till  1859.  The  only  in- 
terest these  earlier  provisions  now  have  is  as  illustrating 
how  the  revenue  system  grew,  and  how  ideas  regarding 
sales,  under-tenures,  and  enhancement  of  rents,  were  gra- 
dually modified.  But  it  is  to  be  remembered  that  titles  to 
existing  property  may  still  depend  on  the  laws  which  were 
in  force  at  the  time  when  the  sales,  under  which  they  arose, 
took  place,  and  therefore  the  early  laws  cannot  be  omitted 
altogether  from  notice. 

How  many  difficulties  have  arisen  out  of  this  principle  of 
sale,  and  the  necessary  '  clear  title '  which  goes  with  it,  and 
how  those  difficulties  had  been  met,  belongs  to  a  later 
section,  where  we  shall  deal  with  the  modern  law  in  its 
practical  application. 

§  31.    Effects  of  the  Permanent  Settlement  and  its  Laws. 

Having  now  taken  a  general  retrospect  of  the  principles 
and  practice  of  the  Permanent  Settlement,  as  regards  the 
persons  settled  with,  the  nature  of  the  revenue,  the  method 
of  its  assessment,  the  treatment  of  the  waste  land,  the 
registration  of  estates,  and  the  recovery  of  arrears  of  reve- 


CHAP.  I.] 


THE    PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT. 


439 


nue,  we  may  proceed  to  make  a  general  retrospect  of  what 
the  effects  of  the  Settlement  have  been. 

The  decennial  Settlement,  made  permanent  in  1793,  ex- 
tended to  Bengal,  Bihar,  and  Orissa — the  Orissa  of  these 
days  being  (I  may  repeat)  the  tract  between  the  Kupnarain 
and  Subarnrekha  rivers,  now  in  the  Midnapore  district l. 

In  general  terms,  it  may  be  said  that  it  disappointed 
many  expectations  and  produced  several  results  that  were 
not  anticipated.  It  has  been  stated  that,  at  first,  the 
revenue  levied  from  the  Zamindars  and  others  made  pro- 
prietors, was  heavy ;  but  as  the  effects  of  British  peace  and 
security  made  themselves  felt,  and  as  the  value  of  land  and 
its  produce  rose,  and  waste  lands  were  brought  under  the 
plough,  the  assessments  became  proportionately  lighter  and 
lighter  2.  And  it  must  be  borne  in  mind  that  every  estate 
at  the  time  of  its  original  assessment  contained  considerable, 


1  The  land-revenue,  though  per- 
manently fixed  in  1793,  was  liable 
to  be  increased  by  causes  which  had 
nothing  to  do  with  the  assessment 
of  the  original  estates  ;  for  example, 
the  Zamindars  were  relieved  of 
police  charges,  and  the  lands  held 
free  for  the  purpose  would  be  called 
in  and  assessed  as  the  arrangements 
were  completed.  Then  the  gradual 
resumption  of  invalid  revenue-free 
tenures  caused  an  increase,  as  well 
as  the  assessment  of  land  held  in 
excess  ('taufir '  in  revenue  language) 
of  the  proper  estate  (Reg.  II  of  1819) : 
and  there  were  other  causes.  This 
is  exclusive  of  the  revenue  of  tem- 
porarily settled  estates,  or  lands 
held  by  Government.  The  Per- 
manent Settlement  Revenue  was 
about  R.  2,85,87,722.  In  1828-29, 
the  demand  had  risen  to  Company's 
R.  3,04,27,770,  in  1846-47  it  was 
R.3,12,52,676,  and  in  1848  49  R.3,4O, 
96,605.  In  1856-57  it  appears  at 
the  slightly  reduced  figure  of  3,37, 
38,783.  In  the  following  year  it  rose 
to  R.  3,39,10,632.  In  1882-83  it  was 
R.  3,62,78355:  the  increase  during 
the  ten  years  previously  had  been 
more  than  a  lakh  a  year.  In  1888- 
89  the  permanently  Settled  Re- 
venue was  R.  3,22,90,777  (Rev.  Adm. 


Rep.  p.  2).  These  figures  are  cal- 
culated for  the  whole  of  the  dis- 
tricts in  the  old  Permanent  Settle- 
ment, excluding  Chota  Nagpore 
(Chutiya  Niigpur),  which  had  not 
then  been  settled  (Report,  1883). 

2  The  revenue  assessed  in  1790- 
93  being,  as  just  stated.  Company's 
R.2, 85, 87, 722, or  under  three  millions 
of  pounds,  the  Zamindars  were  esti- 
mated to  get,  as  their  profit,  a  sum 
equal  to  about  a  tenth  of  the  total 
assessment.  They  no  doubt  got 
more  ;  but  even  if  we  say  a  fifth, 
instead  of  a  tenth,  the  rental  or 
profit  would  be  under  a  million. 
At  the  present  day,  judging  from 
the  valuation  for  road-cess  ^made  in 
respect  of  the  rent  paid  to  landlords 
by  tenants  and  tenure-holders  of  all 
classes, plus  the  value  of  land  in  the 
direct  possession  of  the  proprietors), 
a  fair  estimate  of  the  rental  made  it 
thirteen  millions,  and  it  must  have 
largely  increased  since  that  date. 
The  revenue  they  pay  now  is  about 
three  and  a-quarter  millions.  So 
that  even  on  the  rule  of '  half- rental 
assets  =  the  revenue*  prevalent  in 
Northern  India,  they  pay  less  than 
half  (probably  less  than  one  thirds 
of  what  other  landowners  have  to 
pay. 


44O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

often  very  large,  areas  of  culturable  waste  of  great  value ; 
and  as  this  was  entirely  unassessed,  all  the  immense  sub- 
sequent extension  of  cultivation  was  so  much  clear  profit 
to  the  owner1. 

Before,  however,  these  changes  began  to  tell,  the  assess- 
ments were  heavy  enough  to  necessitate  diligence  and 
prudence ;  and  the  landlords  were  not  able  at  once  to  keep 
pace  with  the  inflexible  demand.  The  consequence  was 
a  very  widespread  default.  As  just  now  explained,  the 
law  practically  stood  to  enforce  a  sale  of  the  estate  (or  part 
of  it),  directly  the  owner  was  in  arrears,  and  it  followed 
that  large  numbers  of  estates  were  put  up  to  sale. 

'In  1796-97,'  says  the  late  Mr.  J.  Macneile2,  'lands  bearing 
a  total  revenue  of  Sicca3  R.  14,18,756,  were  sold  for  arrears, 
and  in  1797-98  the  Jama'  of  lands  so  sold  amounted  to  Sicca 
R.  22,74,076.  By  the  end  of  the  century,  the  greater  portions 
of  the  estates  of  the  Nadiya,  Rajshahi,  Bishnpur,  and  Diiiajpur 
Rajas,  had  been  alienated.  The  Bardwan  estate  was  seriously 
crippled,  and  the  Birbhiim  Zamindari  completely  ruined.  A 
host  of  smaller  Zamindaris  shared  the  same  fate.  In  fact,  it  is 
scarcely  too  much  to  say  that,  within  the  ten  years  that  imme- 
diately followed  the  Permanent  Settlement,  a  complete  revolu- 
tion took  place  in  the  constitution  and  ownership  of  the  estates 
which  formed  the  subject  of  that  Settlement.' 

One  effect  of  the  '  Sale  Law '  was  to  reduce  very  greatly 
the  size  of  the  Zamindaris,  for  up  to  1845  they  were  sold 
piecemeal.  The  making  into  separate  estates  of  taluqs,  the 
owners  of  which  established  a  claim  to  be  dealt  with  sepa- 


1  Government,    no   doubt,   after-  Murshidabad,  but  still  bearing  the 
wards  resumed,  and  assessed  sepa-  name  of  the  Mughal  Emperor  Shah 
rately,  some  large  areas  of  waste,  but  'Alam.      lit.   Regulation   XXXV   of 
it  was  waste  improperly  or  fraud-  I793>  it  was  enacted  that  this  coin 
ulentlyannexed  to  the  estate.  Many,  was  to  be  legal  tender,  and  was  to 
if  not  most,  estates  had  a  great  deal  bear  the  igth  year  of  the  Emperor's 
of    waste   which    was    confessedly  reign  for  uniformity  sake.     Speak- 
included  in  their  boundaries.  ing  roughly,  three  '  Company's  ru- 

2  Memorandum  on  the  Revenue  Ad-  pees '  equalled  two  sikka.    The  sikka 
ministration   of  the  Loioer  Provinces  of  contained   176-13  grains  Troy,  and 
Bengal  ^Calcutta,  1873  ,  p.  9.  the  rupee  afterwards  introduced  in 

3  The  '  Sikka '  was  the  first  rupee  1835  as  the  '  Company's/  165  grains, 
struck  (in  1773)  by  the  Company  at  of  pure  silver. 


CHAP.  I.] 


THE   PERMANENT    SETTLEMENT. 


441 


rately  from  the  Zamindars,  and  the  effect  of  partitions, 
had  also  tended  to  the  same  result.  The  tendency  to  sub- 
divide estates  is  also  great,  and  especially  in  Bihar.  In 
twenty  years,  the  number  of  estates  was  doubled  in  Patna 
division,  and  in  Tirhut  (Muzaffarpur  and  Darbhanga  dis- 
tricts) was  more  than  trebled.  Taking  the  figures  for 
1882-3,  out  of  a  total  number  of  110,456  estates  borne  on 
the  roll  of  39  districts  of  Bengal  proper  and  Bihar,  457, 
or  0-41  per  cent,  only,  are  great  properties,  with  an  area  of 
20,000  acres  or  upwards:  12,304,  or  ii'i  per  cent.,  range 
from  500  to  20,000  acres  ;  while  the  number  of  estates 
which  fall  short  of  500  acres,  is  97,695,  or  88-4  per  cent,  of 
the  whole  l. 

In  Chittagong,  however,  the  estates  were  always  small, 
and  in  Bihar  there  never  were  any  very  large  Zamindarfs. 


§  32.    Districts  affected  by  the  Permanent  Settlement. 

The  Permanent  Settlement  extended  over  the  following 
districts  in  Bengal,  as  the  districts  are  now  constituted  :— 


Bardwan. 
Bankura. 
Birbhum. 
Hooghly  (Hughli). 
Howrah  (Haura;. 
24-Pergunnahs. 
Jessore  (Jasur). 
Khiilna. 


Patna. 
Gaya. 
Shahabad. 
Muzaffarpur*. 


BENGAL. 

Nadiya. 

Murshidabad. 

Dinajpur. 

Malda. 

Rajhshahi. 

Eangpur. 

Bogra  (Bagura). 

Pabna. 

BIHAB, 

Darbhanga*. 

Saran. 

Champaran. 


Maimansingh. 
Faridpur. 
Bakirganj. 
Chittagong      (Chatta- 

graon). 

Noacolly  (Nawakhali). 
Tipperah  (Tipra). 
Dacca  (Dakha). 


Purneah  (Parniya). 
Bhagalpur. 

Monghyr  (Munger\ 


These  two  form  the  old  Tirhut  District. 


SANTALIA. — Part  of  the  Santal  Pergunnahs  adjoining  the  Regulation 
Districts. 

ORISSA. — Mednipur   (Midnapore\   except   one   pargana  which  was 
settled  along  with  Katak  (Cuttack). 

CHOTA  NAGPORE  (Chutiya  Nagpur).     Parts  of  all  the  districts. 
1  Report,  1883,  p.  4. 


442  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  11. 

Some  estates  in  the  Manbhum,  Singbhum,  Lohardagga, 
and  Hazaribagh  districts  (now  in  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  Divi- 
sion) came  under  Permanent  Settlement,  though  they  are 
'  non-Regulation  districts,'  because  they  were  then  included 
in  collectorates  which  formed  part  of  the  Bengal  or  Bihar 
of  that  date. 

The  part  of  the  Jalpaiguri  district  south-west  of  the  Tista 
river,  also  was  permanently  settled  under  the  same  circum- 
stances. A  glance  at  the  '  Settlement  map  '  annexed  to  this 
volume  will  show  the  whole  matter. 

A  portion  of  Sylhet  was  permanently  settled,  but  the 
Settlement  did  not  extend  to  Jaintiya,  nor  did  it  touch 
anything  but  the  lands  under  cultivation  at  the  time. 
This  district  will  be  alluded  to  under  the  head  of  Assam, 
in  which  province  it  is  now  included.  Part  of  Goalpara 
(also  in  Assam)  was  included  in  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment l. 

§  33.    Proportion  of  Permanent  and  other  Settlement 
Revenue  in  Bengal. 

It  may  also  be  convenient  here  to  notice  the  proportion 
of  Bengal  revenue  which  is  permanently  settled  to  that 
obtained  from  estates  not  so  settled.  The  total  land-re- 
venue, as  stated  in  the  Board's  Report  1888-9,  is,  in  round 
numbers,  R.  3,81,00,000,  of  which  R.  3,23,00,000  comes  from 
permanently- settled  estates  and  R.  58,00,000  (or  15-2  per 
cent,  of  the  whole)  from  estates  which  are  temporarily 
settled,  and  from  estates  of  which  the  soil  is  owned  by 
Government,  together. 

1  The  results  of  the  Settlement,  Rulers  (p.  166  et  seq.).     Such  ques- 

and  the  condition   of  the  tenants  tions,  interesting  as  they  are,  are 

under  it,  both  in  Bihar  and  Bengal,  evidently  outside  the   scope    of  a 

as  questions  of  social  economy,  are  Revenue  manual,  and  I  can  only 

well  stated  in  Mr.  (now  Sir  H.  S.)  make   this  brief  reference   to    the 

Cunningham's  British  India  and  its  subject. 


CHAPTER   II. 

THE  TEMPORARY   SETTLEMENTS,  INCLUDING  THE  RENT- 
SETTLEMENTS   OF   GOVERNMENT   ESTATES. 

SECTION  L— INTRODUCTORY. 

§  i.    Lands  not  Permanently  Settled. 

IN  this  chapter  we  have  to  treat  of  two  different  classes 
of  lands,  which  must  not  be  confused  together:  (i)  lands 
held  by  persons  recognized  as  proprietors,  but  not  under 
the  Permanent  Settlement  law;  (2)  lands  which  do  not 
belong  to  proprietors,  i.e.  in  which  no  proprietary  right 
other  than  that  of  Government  exists. 

In  the  first  class  there  is,  of  course,  a  Settlement  of  land- 
revenue,  only  that  it  is  not  under  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment Regulations,  but  under  later  laws  which  contemplate 
the  assessment  being  raised  periodically,  and  the  making  of 
a  Revenue-survey  and  record  of  the  rights  of  all  parties. 

In  the  second  class  there  is  properly  no  Settlement  of 
land-revenue,  because  Government  being  itself  the  owner, 
the  revenue  is  merged  in  rent  taken  by  the  Government  as 
owner.  Nevertheless  '  Settlement  operations '  are  spoken 
of  as  applicable  to  both  classes  of  estates,  under  a  view  of 
the  matter  which  I  will  presently  endeavour  to  make  clear. 

In  the  first  class  of  lands, — proprietary  estates  tem- 
porarily settled, — the  law  is  chiefly  contained  in  Regu- 
lations VII  of  1822  and  IX  of  1833,  and  some  special  Acts 
which  will  be  noticed  more  in  detail  hereafter. 

In  the  second  class,  or  Government  estates,  two  methods 


444  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

of  management  may  be  adopted :  either  the  tract  is  kept 
'raiyatwar,'  i.e.  Government  deals  as  landlord  directly 
with  its  tenants 1 ;  or  a  farmer  or  some  kind  of  middleman 
(who  is  in  no  sense  a  proprietor)  may  be  employed  on  cer- 
tain terms,  to  collect  and  pay  in  the  rents  of  the  tenantry, 
for  which  he  receives  a  certain  emolument  by  way  of  deduc- 
tion from  the  collections.  The  present  tendency  is,  however, 
against  the  employment  of  such  persons ;  it  is  preferred  to 
deal  direct  with  the  tenants  2. 

The  origin  of  these  two  classes  of  lands  has  to  be  ex- 
plained. 

§  2.    Temporarily-settled  Estates. 
To  this  class  belong — 

(1)  Territory  annexed  by  treaty  or  conquest  at  a  date 

subsequent  to  1793.  In  these  Government  recog- 
nized existing  proprietary  rights,  but  the  Perma- 
nent Settlement  Regulations  did  not  apply;  as 
(speaking  in  general  terms)  in  the  districts  of  the 
modern  Orissa  (Katak,  Balasiir,  and  Puri).  To 
this  we  may  add  districts  exempted,  for  special 
reasons,  from  the  operation  of  the  Regulations ; 

(2)  Resumed  and  lapsed  revenue-free  (lakhiraj)  lands, — 

not  in  permanently-settled  districts,  but  held  by 
persons  who  are  recognized  as  proprietors  3 ; 

(3)  Alluvial   accretions   to   temporarily-settled    estates, 

which,  under  the  law,  may  belong  to  the  estate- 
owner,  but  be  liable  to  pay  revenue. 

1  The  student  will  mark  this,  and  is   no   proprietor  but  Government, 

not  confuse  the  '  raiyatwari  tracts '  and  that  Government  acts  directly 

of  modern  Bengal  Reports  with  the  as  the  landlord,  taking  rent  from  the 

raiyatwari  districts  of  Bombay,  Ma-  tenants,  which  rent  it  enhances,  &c., 

dras,  &c.    In  the  latter,  Government  just   as    any  other    landlord    does 

treats  the  raiyats  not  as  its  tenants,  under  the  law. 
but     as     individual     proprietors —          2  See  post,  §  6,  page  449. 
whether  called  in  law  '  proprietors '          3  Invalid  or  lapsed  revenue-free 

or  '  occupants ' — and  assesses  their  holdings  in  a  permanently- settled  rft'.s- 

holdings  to  land-revenue  properly  trict,  when   '  resumed/  are  entitled 

so  called.      The  term  '  raiyatwari  to  be  permanently  settled,  but  no 

tract '  in  the  eleven  Bengal  districts  others. 
in  which  it  occurs,  means  that  there 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  445 

§  3.    Government  Estates, 

To  this  class  belong — 

(1)  Waste  lands. — In  the  first  place  the  Permanent  Set- 

tlement Regulations  extended  only  to  estates  of 
Zamindars  and  other  actual  proprietors  as  they 
existed  at  the  time.  These  estates,  no  doubt,  were 
very  loosely  defined,  and  all  included  a  good  deal 
more  land  than  was  actually  cultivated  at  the 
time,  and  were  intended  to  do  so ;  but  there  were 
districts  in  which  the  area  of  waste  was  so  large 
that  no  claim  to  it  was  made,  not  even  by  squat- 
ters or  persons  encroaching  beyond  their  own 
adjacent  estates.  This  is  notably  the  case  in  such 
districts  as  Goalpara  and  Sylhet  (described  under 
Assam)  and  Chittagong ;  and  again  in  the  tract 
known  as  the  Sundarbans  between  the  mouths  of 
the  Hiighli  and  Megna  rivers  (part  of  the  districts 
of  the  '  24-Pergunnahs,'  Khulna  and  Bakirganj), 
in  the  '  Daman-i-koh,'  or  hilly  tract  of  the  Santal 
Pergunnahs.  In  all  such  waste  lands,  until  (under 
'  Waste  Land  Rules ')  Government  leased  or 
granted  the  proprietary  right,  the  ownership  re- 
mained vested  in  the  State. 

(2)  When  estates  or  parts  of  estates  were  sold  for  arrears 

of  revenue  and  Government  bought  them  in,  either 
because  no  bidders  appeared,  or  because  satisfactory 
terms  were  not  offered 1. 

(3)  Thanadari  lands,  or  lands  formerly  allotted  to  Zanrin-  Reg.  I  of 

dars  for  keeping  up  '  thanas  '  or  police  stations. 
The  Zamindars  were  exonerated  from  this  duty, 
and  the  lands  were  resumed  by  Government. 


At  one  time  it  was  supposed  porary  Settlement  :  but  this  is  not 
that  if  Government  parted  with  the  so.  Whenever  sold,  the  purchaser 
proprietary  right  in  estates  origin-  would  acquire  a  Permanent  Settle- 
ally  permanently  settled  but  sold  ment  right  under  the  Regulations. 
for  arrears,  the  proprietor  so  ac-  See  Boards  Rev.  Rules,  vol.  ii. 
quiring  was  only  entitled  to  a  tern- 


446  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

(4)  Islands  and  '  chars '  formed  in  rivers  or  on  the  sea- 

shore— not  being  accretions  by  alluvion  to  existing 
estates,  which  by  the  law  or  custom  (Reg.  XI 
of  1825)  belonged  to  the  estate  to  which  they 
accreted — were  liable  to  a  separate  Settlement. 
With  such  a  vast  river-system  as  Bengal  pos- 
sesses, this  head  is  not  devoid  of  importance. 

(5)  Lands    escheated     in    default     of    legal    heirs    or 

claimants. 

(6)  Lands  forfeited  for  any  State  offence,  e.g.  the  Khiirda 

estate  in  Puri. 

(7)  Lands  which  were  acquired  by  conquest  in  cases 

where  the  lands  were  not  already  owned,  and  the 
Government  did  not  see  fit  to  confer  any  general 
proprietary  title  :  as,  e.g.  the  Dwars  of  Jalpdiguri 
and  the  Darjiling  District 1. 

§  4.    Official  Classification. 

The  existence  of  these  variously-originating  estates  neces- 
sitated a  recognized  official  classification.  Such  a  classi- 
fication was  adopted  under  Sir  G.  Campbell's  administration 
in  the  district  Revenue  Rolls  for  1876-77  2  : — 

CLASS  I.  (All)  permanently-settled  estates — 

(1)  At  the  decennial  Settlement  (1789  to  1791); 

(2)  Resumed  revenue-free  settled  permanently ; 

(3)  Estates  formerly  the  property  of  Government,  but 

the  proprietary  right  in  which  had  been  sold  to 
private  persons  subject  to  revenue  fixed  in  per- 
petuity. 

(4)  Ditto,  ditto,  subject  to  a  revenue  liable  to  periodical 

revision  3. 

1  I  need  hardly  add  an  eighth  class  re-sold  or  kept  as  Government  lands. 
— Land  acquired  under  the  Acquisi-  2  And  lands  were  described  ac- 
tion Act— for  such  lands  will  usually  cording  to  it  in  the  Board's  Report, 
be  applied  to  a  special  purpose  ;  but  1874-75.  See  Report,  1883,  p.  3. 
such  lands  are  sometimes  taken,  3  As  a  subhead  of  Class  I,  No.  4 
and  not  being  needed,  are  either  seems  a  little  contradictory  :  I  sup- 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  447 

CLASS  II.  Temporarily-settled  estates,  the  property  of 
private  persons — 

(1)  Settled  for  definite  periods,  including   (of  course) 

such  estates,  when— 

(2)  Farmed  ) 

(  Owing  to  refusal  of  the  proprietors  to 

(3)  or  managed  t  thg  termg  of  Settlement 

direct.          ' 

CLASS  III.  Estates  the  property  of  Government,  however 
acquired,  and  whether  settled  (i.  e.  the  rents  are  made  over 
to  a  responsible  collector,  who  is  allowed  a  remuneration), 
or  whether  managed  direct :  but  this  class  has  been  for 
convenience  subdivided  so  as  to  give  a  further — 

CLASS  IV.  'Raiyatwari  tracts,'  i.e.  large  Government 
estates  with  an  area  of  not  less  than  5000  acres,  where  the 
Government  deals  direct  with  the  cultivators,  settling  and 
recording  their  rents,  and  collecting  them  itself. 

A  glance  at  the  table  of  estates  and  revenue  at  pp.  470-1 
will  show  how  these  are  distributed. 

The  orders  contemplate  the  '  Daman-i-koh '  of  the  '  San- 
tal  Pergunnahs,'  being  classified  as  a  single  raiyatwari 
tract. 

The  Khurda  and  Noanand  estates  in  Orissa  are,  however, 
entered  as  Government  estates  under  Class  III,  because, 
though  in  some  respects  raiyatwari  (all  rents  and  rights 
being  recorded),  the  collection  is  managed  by  responsible 
'  sarbarakars,'  who  are  allowed  a  sort  of  Settlement. 

Government  lands  called  '  Jalpai '  lands  in  Midnapore 1 
are  not  treated  as  '  raiyatwari '  unless  the  tract  is  5000  acres 
or  over — notwithstanding  that  the  raiyats  pay  direct. 

In  Chittagong,  farms  of  circles,  and  '  nauabad '  taluqs  or 
holdings,  are  in  Class  III,  because  they  are  Government 
property  as  far  as  the  right  in  the  soil  is  concerned. 

pose   it  refers  to   cases  where  the  vol.  iii.  86-100).     They  are  lands  for 

Settlement  has  been  made  once  for  producing  the  fuel  used  in  boiling 

all,  but  at  progressive  rates.  brine   to   make  salt.     Government 

2  Mentioned   in   the   chapter  on  resumed  these  lands  under  the  Salt 

Tenures.     They  cover  76.835  acres  laws,  and  compensated  the  owners 

(Statistical   Acc.,   Bengal,  Midnapore —  or  holders. 


448  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

§  5.    Certain  Districts  without  any  Revenue  System. 

In  concluding  this  introductory  explanation,  I  should 
take  occasion  to  observe  that  I  omit  from  consideration 
certain  territories  which  are  under  Government  control  in 
the  Political  Department,  and  have  no  regular  revenue- 
system.  Such  are — 

(1)  The  portion  of  the  Chittagong  district  known  as  the 

Chittagong  Hill  tracts. 

(2)  The  portion  of  the  Tipperah  (Tipra)  District  known 

as  Hill  Tipperah  belonging  to  the  Maharaja  of 
Tipperah. 

(3)  The  Chiefships  known  as  Tributary  or  '  Peshkash ' 

States  of  Orissa. 

(4)  Chiefships  in  the  Chutiyd,  Nagpur  Division  (those  of 

the  old  '  South  -West  Frontier  Agency '). 


§  6.    Policy  as  to  Retention  or  Disposal  of  Land. 

It  will  next  be  asked,  Under  what  principle  does  Go- 
vernment sell  or  retain  and  farm  or  manage  direct,  the 
lands  which  became  Government  estates "?  To  this  question 
I  can  best  reply  by  an  extract  from  the  Report  of  1882-83 
on  the  Land  system  in  Bengal,  Bihar,  and  Orissa  (p.  6) : — 

'  The  Government  estates  were  originally  either  permanently 
settled  or  sold  outright.  The  policy  was  changed  in  1871, 
since  when,  temporary  Settlements  only  have  been  allowed, 
and,  where  sales  have  been  considered  expedient,  the  estates 
were  first  settled  for  a  term  of  years,  and  then  sold  subject  to  a 
revision  of  the  Government  revenue  on  the  expiration  of  the  term 
of  Settlement.  The  above  procedure,  however,  appeared  to  be 
of  questionable  legality,  and  in  1875  the  Government,  at  the 
suggestion  of  the  Board  of  Revenue,  ruled  that  an  estate  should 
be  considered  as  qualified  for  direct  management — 

(i)  If  it  was  of  sufficient  extent  and  cultivation  to  support 
a  tahsildari  [special  collecting]  establishment; 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEAEY    SETTLEMENTS. 


449 


(2)  If,  though  not  yielding  a  revenue  sufficient  to  cover 

such  expense,  there  was  reasonable  expectation  that 
its  gross  rent  could  be  increased  by  improvements, 
extended  cultivation,  or  otherwise,  to  that  amount ; 

(3)  If,  though  not  sufficient  in  extent  or  rental  alone,  to  find 

employment  or  funds  for  a  separate  establishment,  it 
was  so  situated  as  to  be  capable  of  being  incorporated 
with  one  or  more  similar  '  khas-mahals/  so  as  to  form 
a  compact  tahsildari  circle 1 ; 

and  that  smaller  isolated  estates  might  still  be  retained  under 
direct  management,  if  their  situation  near  the  headquarters  of 
a  district  or  a  subdivision  was  such  as  to  allow  of  their  proper 
supervision  by  the  Government  officers.  Smaller  estates  not 
admitting  of  such  super  vision 'were  to  be  sold  after  survey  and 
Settlement,  in  which  the  rights  of  all  classes  of  cultivators 
were  to  be  recorded  ;  and  the  estates  so  sold,  were  to  be  trans- 
ferred to  their  new  proprietors,  with  the  revenue  fixed  in  per- 
petuity, except  in  Orissa  (a  temporarily-settled  province),  where 
the  sale  should  be  made  subject  to  revision  of  the  jama'  on  the 
termination  of  the  general  Settlement  of  the  province.  The 
above  orders  are  still  in  force.  Farming  is  adopted  only  in 
very  exceptional  cases,  or  as  a  last  resort,  when  every  other 
mqde  of  disposing  of  the  estate  has  failed.  Direct  manage- 
ment, though  more  troublesome,  and  probably  not  less  expen- 
sive, is  preferred  to  farming,  because  it  enables  Government 
officers  to  gain  a  practical  knowledge  of  the  progress  of 
agriculture,  of  the  extent  to  which  the  productive  powers  of 
the  land  have  developed,  and  of  the  increased  money-value 
of  the  produce,  which,  in  Bengal,  it  is  difficult  to  obtain  in 
any  other  way.' 


1  I  may  repeat  the  explanation 
that,  in  revenue  language,  when  any 
land  was  managed  directly  by  the 
Collector's  establishment  (without 
a  farmer  or  lessee)  it  was  said  to  be 


held  '  khas.'  Government  estates 
were  therefore  called 'khas  mahals,' 
and  the  term  is  commonly  used  in 
Revenue  Reports. 


VOL.  I. 


G  or 


450  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  II. — THE  TEMPORARY  SETTLEMENT  LAW  AND 
PROCEDURE. 

§  i.    Origin  of  the  Settlement  Law. 

When  the  first  extensive  additions  to  the  Company's  ter- 
ritory occurred  on  the  annexation  of  the  '  Ceded  '  districts 
(1801)  and  the  '  Conquered'  districts  (1803),  the  Permanent 
Settlement  and  its  methods  had  already  come  into  discus- 
sion in  connection  with  the  Madras  Settlements,  as  I  have 
stated  at  length  in  the  chapters  devoted  to  Madras.  Both 
the  Ceded  Provinces  in  the  North -West,  and  Orissa,  pre- 
sented special  features  which  did  not  invite  a  repetition  of 
the  Permanent  Settlement ;  and  notably  there  were  few,  if 
any,  'Zamindars'  of  the  Bengal  class.  I  will  state  pre- 
sently some  particulars  about  Orissa,  but  here  I  only  wish 
to  touch  on  certain  salient  points. 

The  result  of  the  discussions,  and  of  Mr.  Holt  Macken- 
zie's x  Minute,  was  the  passing  of  the  Temporary  Settlement 
Kegulation,  No.  VII  of  1822,  which  applied  to  the  'Ceded 
and  Conquered  Districts' — the  Orissa  Districts  (called  in 
the  preamble  'Katak,  Pataspur,  and  its  dependencies') 
being  among  the  latter.  Now  this  law,  instead  of  proceed- 
ing to  an  estimated  lump-sum  Settlement  without  survey 
or  inquiry  into  details,  expressly  directed  a  survey  and  an 
inquiry  into  the  rights  in  every  village  and  field,  which  was 
to  be  followed  by  a  valuation  of  the  '  net  produce  '  of  land 
— i.  e.  (briefly  stated)  an  inquiry  into  the  actual  produce  on 
various  lands,  of  various  crops.  From  the  gross  produce 
valued  in  money,  the  cost  of  production,  wages  of  labour, 
&c.,  were  to  be  deducted,  and  the  result  was  the  net  pro- 
duce, of  which  a  certain  fraction,  never  fixed  by  law  but 

1  This  eminent  civilian  was,  if  I  kenzie's  great  minute  of  1819  in  the 

may  say  so.  the  prophet  of  the  Tern-  North -Western   Provinces,  did   for 

porary  Settlement  system  of  Upper  the  system  there,  what  Mr.  Shore's 

India  (and  Orissa"),  as  Mr.  Shore  had  minutes  of  1788-89  did  for  Bengal, 

been  in  1788-89  of  the  Zamindari  (See  the  chapter  on  N.  W.  Provinces 

Settlement  of  Bengal.     Mr.  H.  Mac-  Settlements.) 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  451 

determined  on  principles  of  fair  dealing  and  expediency 
by  the  executive  power,  was  to  be  taken  as  the  State  share 
or  land-revenue.  But  (as  more  fully  detailed  in  the  chapter 
on  the  North -Western  Provinces  Settlement,  vol.  ii)  the 
task  of  finding  this  '  net  produce '  of  every  field  proved  an 
impossible  one;  and  by  Regulation  IX  of  1833  it  was 
abandoned  in  favour  of  one  which  aimed  at  determining 
the  'net  assets.'  This  practically  meant  (or  rather  came 
to  mean  as  experience  widened)  the  total  receipts  from 
the  land  in  the  shape  of  rents.  Putting  it  shortly,  all 
modern  methods  of  Temporary  Settlement  which  trace 
their  origin  to  the  Regulations  of  1822-33,  tend  more  and 
more  to  aim  at  discovering  what  is  the  actual  rental  of 
land,  correcting  the  sum  total  of  rents  paid,  by  adding  in 
the  estimated  rent  (calculated  on  the  data  afforded  by  the 
neighbourhood)  of  lands  which  are  enjoyed  rent-free  or  are 
cultivated  by  the  proprietors  themselves.  In  other  words, 
the  ascertainment  of  the  income  from  rental  and  personal 
enjoyment  of  cultivated  lands,  is  the  basis  of  Settlement. 
Now,  in  Bengal,  for  temporarily-settled  districts,  a  certain 
proportion  of  this  '  corrected  rental '  is  the  land-revenue. 
But  in  Government  estates,  the  State  as  landlord,  has  also 
to  fix  the  whole  rental  which  it  takes  as  owner.  In  both 
cases,  therefore,  a  public  officer  has  to  ascertain  the  rent ; 
and  it  matters  very  little  whether  it  is  only  ascertaining 
what  that  rent  is,  with  a  view  to  taking  a  portion  as  revenue, 
or  whether  it  also  involves  (in  disputed  cases),  adjusting, 
equalizing,  raising  or  reducing,  rents,  with  a  view  to  taking 
the  whole  as  landlord J.  A  rent-inquiry  of  some  kind  is  at 
the  basis  both  of  temporary  Settlements  and  of  managing 
Government  estates. 

The  reader  will  then  understand  why  we  are  able  to  put 
these  two  dissimilar  classes  of  estates  under  one  chapter, 
and  why  '  Settlement  operations  '  are  conveniently,  if  not 
quite  logically,  spoken  of  as  applicable  to  both. 

1  Or  the  whole  rental  less  such  middleman  is  employed  to  collect  the 
percentage  as  it  allows  in  case  a  rents. 

Gg  2 


452  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  ll. 

§  2.    Settlement  and  Rent-settlement  Law. 

i 

The  law  for  the  Settlement  of  Rents  is  now  contained  in 
the  tenth  chapter  of  the  Bengal  Tenancy  Act  (General),  Act 
VIII  of  I8851,  and,  when  that  Act  does  not  apply,  in  other 
Acts,  as  will  be  presently  noted. 

The  same  principles  apply  to  the  adjustment  of  rents  in 
Government  estates  and  raiyatwari  tracts,  as  in  those 
cases,  in  private  estates,  in  which  the  Tenancy  law  contem- 
plates the  interference  of  public  authority  to  settle  rents. 

And  for  all  matters  connected  with  the  Settlement  of  the 
Land-Revenue,  other  than  the  adjustment  of  rents,  Regula- 
tion VII  of  1822  (amended  in  1825)  and  Regulation  IX  of 
1833  are  still  the  law,  except  for  the  '  Scheduled  districts,' 
in  which  there  are  special  laws  for  the  Land- Re  venue 
administration. 

Act  vin       Rules  under  the  Tenancy  Act  (which  have  the  force  of 
sec*  189'      law),  and  instructions  as  to  Settlement  issued  by  the  Board 
of  Revenue,  are  the  natural  and  necessary  supplement  to 
both  kinds  of  Settlement  law. 

The  Tenancy  Act  of  1885  does  not,  however,  apply  (un- 
less extended  specially)  to  the  districts  of  Orissa  (Katak, 
Balasiir,  and  Piiri)  nor  to  the  '  Scheduled  Districts.'  Hence, 
in  those,  we  have  three  sources  of  rent  and  Settlement  law : 
(i)  the  Regulations  and  instructions  above  mentioned;  (2) 
Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1879  (not  repealed  in  districts  to  which 
Act  VIII  of  1885  does  not  apply);  (3)  any  special  laws  or 
Regulations  relating  to  particular  districts  as  far  as  those 
touch  on  rent  or  revenue  matters.  The  law  in  force  under 
these  three  heads  may  be  thus  exhibited  2  :— 

1  The  magnitude  of  the  interests  in  the  Bengal  Legislative  Council, 
involved,  and  the  contest  there  was,  2  E.  and  F.  Tenancy  Act,  p.  176. 
as  well  as  the  bearing  of  the  Act  on  B.  Act  VIII  of  1879  refers  to  Settle- 
other  laws  framed  in  the  Imperial  ment  officers'  powers,  and  will  not 
Council,  rendered  it  necessary  that  be  confused  with  VIII  of  1869  (the 
the  Act  should  be  passed  in  the  old  Tenant  Act)  still  in  force  in 
Legislative  Council  of  India,  and  not  those  districts. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOKAEY    SETTLEMENTS.  453 

DISTRICTS. 


Balasur,  Katak,  and  Puri  -j 


Regulation  VIII  of  1  793  l. 

(For  Katak)  Regulation  XII  of  1805. 

Regulation  V  of  1812  (not  applicable  to  Katak; 

Regulation  XVIII  of  1812. 
Regulation  VII  of  1822  (and  amendments  i 

1825). 

Regulation  IX  of  1833. 
Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1879. 


f  «  Act  Vm  of 

(south  of  the  Tista)  .      } 

Jalpaiguri   (the  Bhutan  )  Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1879. 

or  Western  Dwars).       \  Act  XVI  of  1869. 
Santal  Parganas.  Regulation  (33  Viet.,  Cap.  3)  III  of  1872. 

(  Act  XXII  of  1860. 
Chittagong  Hill  Tracts,    j  (See  Bengal  Settlement  Manual,  1888,  page  4.) 

Chutiya     Nagpur     Dis-  , 

trusts—  /  Bengal  Act  vill  of  1879  ;  and  see  Bengal  Acts 

Manbhum,  Hazaribagh,  >      n»rf  and  I    f  £> 

Lohardagga,       Singh-  I 
bhum.  / 

Under  these  laws,  according  to  circumstances,  different 
kinds  of  Settlements  can  be  made:  e.g.  if  it  is  desirable 
merely  to  settle  a  lump  sum  of  revenue  without  recordiug 
tenants'  rents  or  rights,  it  can  be  done  under  the  Regula- 
tions. This  is  seldom  the  case.  If  (as  is  usually  the  case) 
the  more  complete  Settlement  with  a  record  of  rights  and 
an  enhancement  of  rents  (where  necessary)  is  desired,  then 
in  districts  where  the  Act  of  1885  does  not  apply,  the 
Regulation,  aided  by  Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1879,  will  give 
the  needful  authority.  The  Act  is,  in  fact,  the  supple- 
ment of  the  Regulations  of  1822-33.  The  latter  only 
enabled  the  Settlement  Officer  to  declare  what  he  con- 
sidered a  fair  rent,  and  this  was  only  presumed  to  be 
correct  till  set  aside  by  a  regular  civil  suit  ;  but  Act  VIII 
of  1879  empowers  rents  to  be  enhanced  under  circumstances 
therein  stated. 

In  cases  where  the  Act  of  1885  is  in  force,  then,  if  it  is 
desired  to  have  a  complete  record  and  adjustment  of  rents. 
the  Act  must  be  followed  ;  but  if  it  is  supposed  the  en- 

1  Applicable  to  a  number  of  es-  a  Permanent  Settlement  for  special 

tates,    intermediate     between     the  reasons  ;    and   they  occupy  a   con- 

semi-independent'  Tributary'  States  siderable  portion  of  the  districts  — 

or    Mahals    and    the    periodically-  Katak  especially. 
settled  portion.    These  were  granted 


454  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 

hancement  is  not  necessary,  and  that  Settlement  will  be 
made  without  readjustment  of  rents,  or  with  such  a  readjust- 
ment as  can  be  made  by  agreement  (e.g.  the  enhancement 
not  being  in  excess  of  two  annas  in  the  rupee1),  then 
there  will  be  no  occasion  to  proceed  to  notify  the  tract 
under  the  Tenancy  Act,  but  the  old  Settlement  procedure 
will  suffice. 

§  3.    Certain  operations  even  in  permanently -settled 
Estates. 

It  should  be  remarked  that  even  where  no  re-assessment 
of  land-revenue  is  possible,  i.  e.  in  permanently-settled  dis- 
tricts,— some  of  the  operations  of  a  Settlement  may  require 
to  be  carried  out. 

The  Local  Government,  with  the  sanction  of  the  Gover- 
nor-General in  Council,  may  order  a  survey  and  a  record  of 
rights  to  be  prepared  for  all  lands  in  any  local  area.  This 
power  has  not  yet  been  exercised  except  experimentally. 
In  time  it  is  to  be  hoped  that  every  district  will  ultimately 
be  so  provided  for2. 

Without  the  supreme  sanction,  such  orders  can  be  issued 
in  cases  where  a  large  proportion  of  either  landlords  or 
tenants  desire  it  and  deposit  the  amount  (or  security  for 
the  amount)  of  expenses,  as  directed  by  the  Local  Govern- 
ment ;  or  where  such  a  proceeding  is  calculated  to  settle  or 
avert  a  serious  dispute  between  landlords  and  tenants  ;  or 
where  the  estate  is  being  managed  by  the  Court  of  Wards. 
This  is  in  addition  to  its  application  (before  alluded  to)  to 
all  Government  Estates  (where,  indeed,  legal  sanction 
would  hardly  be  necessary) ;  or  where  a  Temporary  Settle- 
Act  vin  inent  of  land-revenue  is  to  be  made. 

of  1885. 

sec.  10 1.          *  That  being  the  limit  under  the  and   a   complete   record    of  rights 

Act  to  •which  enhancement  by  con-  prepared.     In  Bengal   an   attempt 

tract  is  valid.     (Sec.  29,  &c.)  — which  I  am  afraid  I  must  call 

8  The  reader  will  learn  hereafter  abortive — has  been  made  in  one  of 

that  in  the  North- Western  Provinces  the   Bihar  districts,   but    the   day 

permanently- settled  districts  (those  must  come  when  the  work  will  be 

that  belonged  to  the  Benares  Pro-  carried  out. 

vince    and   were    ceded    in    1795;,  3  F.  and  K.  Tenant  Act,  p.   174, 

though  permanently  settled,  have  where  the  orders  are  quoted, 
now  all  been  cadastrally  surveyed, 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  455 

This  remark  practically  covers  the  whole  ground,  be- 
cause in  territories  to  which  the  Act  of  1885  is  not  as  yet 
extended,  the  existing  law  enables  the  same  thing  to  be 
done,  at  least  to  a  certain  extent. 

§  4.    Operations  of  Settlement. 

In  any  ordinary  Settlement  under  the  Regulations  of 
1822-33,  measurement,  I  have  said,  is  contemplated  by  the 
law ;  or,  if  proceedings  are  undertaken  under  the  Tenancy 
Act,  a  survey  is  specially  authorized.  There  is  also  a 
General  Survey  Act  (Bengal  Act  V  of  1875),  under  which 
the  Lieutenant-Governor  may  direct  that  a  survey  may  be 
made  of  any  lands,  and  that  the  boundaries  of  estates, 
tenures,  '  mauzas '  (villages),  and  fields,  be  demarcated  and 
surveyed. 

The  following  processes  are  therefore  ordinarily  coin- 
prised  in  Settlements  of  land-revenue,  and  in  other  Settle- 
ments of  rent,  so  far  as  may  be  necessary  x : — 

1.  Demarcation  of  lands  and  adjustment  of  boundary 
disputes. 

2.  Measurement  and  testing  the  same. 

3.  Fixing  and  recording  of  rents. 

4.  Recording  rights  and  interests  in  the  soil. 

5.  Settling   any  provision  for   police   expenses,   village 
patwaris,  allowances  of  the  nature  of  mdlikdna,  &c. 

6.  In    land-revenue    Settlements,    fixing    the    terms  of 
Settlement,  and  who  is  to  be  settled  with. 

§  5.    Demarcation. 

The  Collectors  or  the  Settlement  Officers  are  empowered, 
by  the  Regulations  and  Acts  mentioned,  to  enforce  the  attend- 
ance of  the  proper  persons  to  point  out  boundaries  and  give 
the  necessary  information.  They  are  also  empowered  to 
decide  boundary  disputes  generally,  on  the  usual  basis  of 

1  The  student  will  do  well  to  Revenue  Settlement  Manual  (Edition 
have  for  reference  the  Board  of  of  1888  :  Calcutta  Secretariat  Press). 


456  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

possession,  leaving  disputes  of  title  to  be  settled  in  the 
Civil    Court.      But   where   the   proceeding  is   under  the 
Act  VIII    Tenancy  Act,  the  Settlement   Officer  is  wisely  endowed 
sec*  106,  7.  with  the  power  of  settling  disputes  of  title  as  well 1. 

§  6.    Survey. 

I  may  take  this  opportunity  of  giving  a  general  account 
of  the  Bengal  Survey  system.  The  Report  of  1883  gives 
the  following  account : — 

'  Almost  the  whole  of  these  provinces  has  now  been  surveyed 
so  as  to  show  the  boundaries  of  each  village  and  estate  ;  but 
there  has  been  no  field-measurement  except  in  a  few  limited 
tracts.  There  is  a  demarcation  department  whose  business  it 
is  to  define  the  boundaries  of  villages  and  estates,  and  to  make 
a  compass-and-chain  survey  of  them.  The  ordinary  scale  of 
the  maps  prepared  from  this  survey  is  sixteen  inches  to  the  mile. 
All  disputes  regarding  boundaries  are  decided  by  the  demarca- 
tion officers. 

'  Where  the  whole  of  a  village  belongs  to  one  estate,  nothing 
but  the  outer  boundary  of  the  village  has  to  be  defined  and 
surveyed;  but,  in  a  very  large  proportion  of  cases,  there  are 
lands  of  more  than  one  estate  in  the  village,  and  the  lands  of 
each  estate  are  frequently  scattered  about  the  village  and  not 
situated  in  one  compact  block.  Thus,  there  may  be  lands  of 
ten  estates  in  a  village,  but  they  may  be  contained  in  forty, 
fifty,  or  even  double  that  number  of  separate  plots.  Each  of 
these  plots  has  to  be  separately  defined  and  surveyed  by  the 
demarcation  surveyor.  It  is  the  extent  to  which  plots  of  land 
belonging  to  different  estates  are  thus  intermixed  that  renders 
the  demarcation  of  a  Bengal  district  such  a  lengthy  operation. 
To  take  Hooghly  as  an  example,  there  were  in  round  numbers 
4000  village  circuits  demarcated  ;  in  about  1000  of  these  the 
whole  of  the  village  belonged  to  one  estate,  and  no  interior 
measurements  were  necessary.  In  the  remaining  3000,  no 

1  Act  VIII  of  1885,  sees.  106-7.  (speaking  generally)  under  the  Civil 

In  Section   108  it  is  enacted  that  Procedure    Code,    and    there    is    a 

the   Local    Government    shall    ap-  second   or   '  special '   appeal    (on    a 

point  a  special  judge  (or  more  than  point    of   law    only,   with    certain 

one)  to  hear  appeals  in  such  cases.  special  additions,  Sec.   109)  to  the 

Both  suits  and  appeals  are  heard  High  Court. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEAEY    SETTLEMENTS.  457 

less  than  80,000  plots  had  to  be  surveyed,  owing  to  the  inter- 
mixture of  lands  of  different  estates. 

'  The  demarcation  has  been  followed  by  a  professional  survey- 
staff,  whose  business  it  is  to  make  a  scientific  survey  of  the 
village  boundaries,  and  also  a  map  (usually  on  a  scale  of  four 
inches  to  the  mile)  showing  the  geographical  and  topogra- 
phical features  of  the  country.  The  whole  of  the  work,  both 
of  the  demarcation  and  professional  survey,  has  been  carried 
out  at  the  expense  of  Government,  although  the  Government 
derives  no  additional  revenue  and  no  direct  advantage  from 
the  process.  The  surveyors,  in  making  the  survey  of  the 
village  boundaries,  were  guided  by  the  marks  put  up  at 
time  of  demarcation  at  every  bend  and  turn  of  the  boundary. 
Unfortunately,  there  were  no  permanent  marks  round  the 
boundaries  of  villages  or  esta-tes  in  Bengal,  and  no  provision 
then  existed  for  compelling  landholders  to  set  them  up  and 
keep  them  in  order.  The  consequence  was  that  the  marks 
have  been  obliterated  and  the  use  of  the  survey  for  practical 
purposes  has  been  greatly  impaired.' 

§  7.    Special  Survey  of  Alluvial  Lands. 

1  The  surveys  of  Ganges  alluvion  and  diluvion,  in  accordance 
with  the  provisions  of  Act  IX  of  1847,  were  commenced  in  the 
Patna  division  about  1863,  and  brought  to  a  close  in  the 
Rajshahi  division  in  1871-72.  The  operations  were  afterwards 
continued  in  the  Dacca  division.  The  object  of  the  law  was  to 
obviate  the  effects  of  the  changes  constantly  going  on  in  the 
banks  of  rivers  and  adjacent  lands.  By  these  changes  large 
portions  of  land  are  often  washed  away — sometimes  suddenly, 
sometimes  by  slow  degrees — from  one  side  of  a  river,  while  an 
accession  of  land  takes  place  on  the  other  side.  It  was  thought 
advisable,  for  the  security  of  the  land-revenue,  that  some  pro- 
vision should  be  made  for  allowing  to  a  proprietor  whose 
estate  had  suffered  diluvion,  an  abatement  of  revenue  cor- 
responding to  the  extent  of  his  loss ;  and,  on  the  other  hand, 
for  assessing  the  proprietor  whose  estate  had  gained  land,  with 
an  additional  revenue,  proportionate  to  the  amount  of  his  gain. 
The  law  accordingly  enacts  that  in  districts  of  which  a  revenue 
survey  has  already  been  made,  Government  may,  whenever 
ten  years  may  have  elapsed  from  the  date  of  approval  of  such 
survey,  have  a  new  survey  made  of  lands  on  the  banks  of 


458  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

rivers  with  a  view  to  ascertain  the  extent  of  the  changes  since 
the  last  survey.  Having  ascertained,  by  inspection  of  the  new 
survey  map,  which  estates  have  lost  and  which  gained  land, 
a  corresponding  abatement  from,  and  addition  to,  the  revenue 
assessed  on  the  estates  respectively  losing  and  gaining,  is  to  be 
made. 

'The  Settlements  made  were  formerly  permanent,  except 
when  the  proprietors  of  some  of  them  refused  to  take  the 
engagement,  in  which  case  the  lands  were  let  in  farm  for 
periods  of  from  three  to  ten  years  ;  but,  latterly,  orders  have 
been  issued  by  Government  prohibiting  further  permanent 
Settlements,  and  temporary  Settlements  are  made. 

'In  the  course  of  the  six  years,  1877-78  to  1882-83,  the 
banks  of  the  chief  rivers  of  Eastern  Bengal — namely,  the 
Ganges  and  Megna,  with  their  principal  branches  down 
to  the  Bay  of  Bengal,  the  Dhaleshwari,  the  Brahmaputra, 
and  the  southern  portion  of  the  Jamuna — were  surveyed. 
The  total  area  of  the  tracts  of  country  surveyed  in  Dacca, 
Furreedpore,  Backergunge,  Tipperah,  Noakholly,  and  Mymen- 
singh,  is  5,682*74  square  miles,  at  a  total  expenditure  of 
R.  1,59,430.  The  cost  per  square  mile  of  country  surveyed 
has  therefore  been  R.  28-6-10.  This  survey  has  been  made 
in  the  same  scientific  manner  as  the  survey  conducted  by  the 
Revenue  Survey  Department,  and  the  accuracy  of  the  work  has 
been  tested  by  connections  made  with  eighteen  tower  stations 
of  the  Great  Trigonometrical  Survey. 

'  The  total  area  of  land  added  to  estates  since  the  survey  of 
the  districts,  ascertained  by  a  comparison  of  the  new  maps 
with  those  of  the  previous  survey,  was  nearly  479  square  miles. 
Out  of  this  area,  273  estates,  measuring  120*5  square  miles, 
have  been  assessed  and  settled  under  the  provisions  of  section 
6,  Act  IX  of  1847,  yielding  an  annual  revenue  of  R.  59,461-2, 
including  malikana  ;  128  estates,  measuring  51*2  square  miles, 
with  a  rental  of  R.  23,848,  are  pending  Settlement.  In  113 
cases,  57  square  miles,  with  a  rental  of  R.  45,084,  have  been 
left  unassessed  under  orders  passed  in  appeal  by  the  Commis- 
sioner or  the  Board;  151 '3  square  miles  have  been  left  un- 
assessed as  being  (i)  less  than  ten  acres,  (2)  accretions  to 
temporarily-settled  estates  which  are  not  liable  to  assessment 
until  the  Settlements  of  the  estates  expire,  (3)  washed  away 
between  survey  and  Settlement,  and  (4)  included  in  estates 
sold  or  permanently  settled  by  Government  on  a  revised 


CHAP.  li.]  THE    TEMPOEAET    SETTLEMENTS.  459 

assessment  since  the  first  survey  of  the  districts,  and  therefore 
not  liable  to  reassessment.  In  165  cases,  covering  an  area  of 
99  square  miles,  with  a  rental  of  E.  48,765,  the  proceedings 
have  not  yet  become  final,  as  objection  cases  are  pending 
before  the  Superintendent  or  in  appeal.' 

§  8.  Surveying  Agency. 

In  large  areas — generally  speaking  over  fifteen  square 
miles — the  area  is  professionally  surveyed  under  the  Survey 
Department  of  the  Government  of  India.  In  areas  less 
than  that,  the  ordinary  district  staff  carry  out  the  detailed 
work  (as  more  fully  described  in  the  chapters  on  North- 
Western  Provinces).  With,  the  aid  of  skeleton  maps  in 
which  main  points  and  traverse  lines  have  been  laid  down 
for  them  with  scientific  accuracy,  they  survey  both  the 
outer  boundaries  and  field-  and  holding-boundaries,  and 
plot  them.  With  the  detailed  map,  a  field-index  or  register 
called  (as  usual)  a  khasra  is  prepared.  This  shows  the 
details  of  area,  crop  grown,  irrigation,  and  class  of  soil. 
The  area  is  given  in  standard  (Bengal)  bighas  l  (of  14,400 
square  feet  or  1600  square  yards). 

The  khasra  ordinarily  names  the  raiyat  working  the 
field,  but  does  not  attempt  to  record  his  status  or  his  rent. 
In  order  to  group  the  different  fields  held  by  the  same  man 
together,  the  surveyor  prepares  from  the  khasra,  abstracts 
(called  'khatian'  or  'jamabandi')  showing  this.  The 
record  of  the  status  and  the  determination  of  the  rent  pay- 
able come  afterwards. 

§  9.    Fixing  and  recording  Rents. 

Assuming  that  the  particular  law  under  which  the 
Settlement  is  proceeding  allows  it,  the  rents  will  be  ad- 
justed, wherever  required  by  the  circumstances  under 
which  the  Settlement  is  being  made.  The  surveyor  hands 

1  And  the  bigha  is  divided  into  ganda    contains    4    'kauri.'      This 

20    cottas    (kattha),   the   biswa   of  last  subdivision  is  equal  to  9  square 

other  parts  ;  and  that  into  20  ganda  feet  or  i  square  yard, 
(the  biswansi  of  other  parts).     The 


460  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

over  his  maps,  with  the  index-register  and  abstracts,  to 
the  Settlement  Officer,  who  has  then  a  basis  to  work  upon. 
I  assume  also  that  the  status  of  all  existing  tenants  has 
been  recorded  and  the  incidents  of  their  tenancy.  What 
the  status  is,  is  a  matter  concerning  land-tenures  and  will 
be  described  in  a  later  section. 

'  Generally  speaking1,  it  may  be  said  that  the  determination 
of  rents  includes  the  ascertainment  of  existing  rates  of  rent 
which  may  be  applied  to  the  areas  ascertained  by  measure- 
ment '  (and  of  course  this  may  be  something  different  from 
the  actual  sums  paid  hitherto),  '  and  the  enhancements  of  such 
rentals  as  may  be  legally  possible  under  Bengal  Act  VIII  of 
1879,  or  the  Tenancy  Act,  or  other  special  Act  under  which 
the  officer  is  working. 

'  The  first  object  is  therefore  the  ascertainment  of  existing 
facts.  For  this  purpose  the  Settlement  Officer  calls  the  parties 
together,  attests  the  entries  made  by  the  surveyor  regarding 
areas  and  occupation  of  lands,  and  records  the  status  of  tenants 
and  tenure-holders,  and  their  existing  rents.  He  at  the  same 
time  disposes  of  such  disputes  and  objections  as  may  arise.' 

§  10.    Enhancement  of  Rents  under  the  Act  of  1879. 

When  Settlements  (involving  rent  adjustment)  are  being 
made  under  the  Regulations,  supplemented  by  Bengal  Act 
VIII  of  1879,  Sections  6  and  7  of  the  Act  explain  the 
grounds  of  enhancement,  which  are — (i)  that  the  rate  of 
rent  is  below  that  paid  by  raiyats  of  the  same  class  for 
land  of  a  similar  description  in  the  vicinity ;  (2)  that  in- 
crease is  justified  by  an  increase  in  the  productive  power 
of  the  land  which  has  taken  place  otherwise  than  at  the 
expense  of  the  raiyat ;  (3)  that  the  value  of  the  produce  has 
increased  otherwise  than  by  the  agency  of  the  raiyat ;  (4) 
that  the  quantity  of  land  held  is  greater  than  that  for  which 
he  has  been  paying  rent.  In  order  to  legalize  an  enhance- 
ment on  these  grounds,  the  record  must  be  published  with  a 

1  The  inverted  commas  refer  to  culture,  to  which  I  am  indebted 
a  memorandum  prepared  by  the  for  much  of  the  information  on 
Director  of  Land  Records  and  Agri-  details  in  this  chapter. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEAEY    SETTLEMENTS.  46 1 

notice  to  each  raiyat  specifying  exactly  the  grounds  on  which 
the  demand  is  based.  The  raiyat  may,  within  a  period  of 
four  months,  contest  the  enhancement  by  suit  in  the  Civil 
Court.  Under  this  law,  also,  the  sanction  of  the  superior 
revenue  authorities  is  required  to  increase  of  rates  or  rentals. 

§  ii.    Enhancement  of  Rents  under  the  Act  of  1885. 

Under  the  Tenancy  Act  (1885)  in  Government  estates, 
the  landlord  (Government)  may  apply  for  an  enhancement. 
The  application  is  dealt  with  as  a  civil  suit.  The  legal  pre- 
sumption under  the  Act  is  that  the  existing  rent  is  fair ; 
granted  then,  that  the  existing  rent  is  ascertained,  the 
claimant  must  show  justification  for  increase  on  one  or 
other  of  the  grounds  mentioned  in  Sections  6,  30-37,  46, 
&c.  (as  the  case  may  be).  These  grounds  are  briefly — (i) 
that  the  rate  is  below  the  prevailing  rate  paid  for  the  same 
class  of  lands  by  occupancy  raiyats  in  the  village  ;  (2)  that 
there  has  been  a  rise  in  the  average  local  prices  of  staple 
food-crops  during  the  currency  of  the  present  rent ;  (3)  that 
the  productiveness  of  the  land  has  been  increased  by  im- 
provement effected  by  the  landlord,  (4)  or  by  river  action ; 
(5)  that  the  area  of  the  holding  has  been  increased,  new 
land  having  been  brought  under  cultivation  for  which  rent 
was  not  previously  paid. 

The  same  principles  apply  to  private  estates  when  an 
adjustment  of  rents  has  been  ordered. 

§  12.    Duration  of  Rents  so  settled. 

Under  the   Tenancy   Act,    1885,    when    an    occupancy 
raiyat's  rent  is  enhanced,  it  cannot  be  again  enhanced  for 
fifteen  years  ;  and  when  an  ordinary  tenant's  rent  is  raised,  Act  vin 
no  further  increase  can  take  place  for  five  years  :  it  follows  ggcl8«875' 
that  the  effect  of  a  Settlement  is  to  fix  rents  for  fifteen  and  id.  sec.  46, 
for  five  years  respectively. 

Under  Act  VIII  of  1879,  any  rent  fixed  will  be  for  ten  11L'3_ 
years,  or  for  the  period  of  Settlement,  whichever  expires  Act  VIII 

of  l8?9' 
sec.  13. 


462  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 


§  13.    Remarks  on  the  policy  of  the  law. 

In  the  '  Papers  relating  to  the  Bengal  Tenancy  Act,  1885,' 
at  page  424,  the  following  explanatory  remarks  are  made — 

'  What  has  been  done  has  been  to  give  the  Eevenue  Officer 
in  the  first  instance  power  to  settle  all  disputes  that  may  come 
before  him.  Where  no  dispute  arises,  and  it  does  not  appear 
that  the  tenant  is  holding  land  in  excess  of  or  less  than  that  for 
which  he  is  paying  rent,  and  neither  the  landlord  nor  the 
tenant  applies  for  the  settlement  of  a  fair  rent,  the  Eevenue 
Officer  will  record  what  he  finds, — he  will  not  alter  rents,  and 
his  entries  will  only  have  a  presumptive  value  (will  be  pre- 
sumed to  be  true — Section  109 — until  the  contrary  is  proved) 
in  cases  afterwards  brought  before  the  Courts.  When  a  dis- 
pute arises,  or  it  appears  that  the  tenant  is  holding  land  in 
excess  of  or  less  than  that  for  which  he  is  paying  rent,  or 
either  of  the  parties  applies  for  the  settlement  of  a  fair  rent, 
the  Kevenue  Officer  will  decide  a  dispute  or  settle  a  fair  rejit, 
as  the  case  may  be,  on  the  same  grounds,  by  the  same  rules, 
and  with  the  same  procedure,  as  a  Civil  Court.  His  decision 
will  be  liable  to  appeal  to  a  special  Judge,  who  may  or  may  not 
be  the  Judge  of  the  district,  and  will  be  subject  to  a  further 
special  appeal  to  the  High  Court.  In  appeal  the  High  Court 
may  settle  a  new  rent,  but  in  so  doing,  is  to  be  guided  by  the 
other  rents  shown  in  the  rent-roll.  In  other  words,  there  can 
be  no  second  appeal  to  the  High  Court  merely  on  the  ground 
that  the  rent  has  been  pitched  too  high  or  too  low  ;  but  if 
a  second  appeal  is  preferred,  as  it  may  be,  on  the  ground  that 
the  special  Judge,  owing  to  some  error  on  a  point  of  law,  has 
(for  example)  found  the  holding  to  comprise  more  land  or  less 
land  than  it  actually  does  comprise,  or  has  given  the  raiyat 
a  wrong  status,  and  the  appellant  succeeds,  the  High  Court 
can,  without  altering  the  rates,  reduce  or  increase  the  rents,  as 
the  case  may  be.' 

§  14.    Sub-tenants  or  under-raiyats. 

In  addition  to  settling  the  rents  of  raiyats  (i.e.  tenants 
not  being  tenure-holders),  the  Settlement  Officer  is  bound 
to  record  (that  is  all — for  the  rent  payable  is  matter  of 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOKARY    SETTLEMENTS.  463 

contract)  the  rents  payable  by  any  sub-tenants,  or  under- 
raiyats  as  the  Act  calls  them. 

§  15.    '  Tenures' 

In  many  districts  the  '  sub-infeudation,'  which  I  have 
before  alluded  to,  has  taken  place  ;  i.  e.  the  landlord  has  con- 
tracted for  the  management  and  collection  of  his  rents  with 
a  patnidar  or  other  '  tenure-holder/  and  he  again  with  a 
sub-tenure-holder,  and  not  infrequently  he  again  with  a 
third.  Thus  there  may  be  quite  a  chain  of  interests 
between  the  superior  landlord  and  the  actual  rent-paying 
cultivator,  when  rent  has  been  settled  in  the  manner 
described.  And  there  are  other  kinds  of  tenure-holders 
(not  being  patnidars)  who  are  above  the  grade  of  ordinary 
tenants. 

The  rights  of  these  tenure-holders  must  be  defined  and 
recorded.  It  may  also  be  necessary  to  declare  them  invalid 
and  to  set  them  aside. 

If  these  tenures  are  found  to  be  binding  against  the 
landlord  or  against  Government,  it  is  necessary  (unless 
they  are  rent-free)  to  determine  the  relations  in  the  matter 
of  payments  between  them  and  the  superior.  This  is 
ordinarily  done  by  determining  the  portion  of  the  total  of 
the  cultivating  rentals  under  them  which  they  are  entitled 
to  retain  and  not  pass  on  to  their  superior  or  landlord. 
This  deduction  must  be  at  least  ten  per  cent.,  and  may  be 
as  much  more  as  the  Revenue  Officer  thinks  proper  under 
the  circumstances  of  the  case  (see  Section  7). 

It  is  to  be  remembered  that  no  tenure  which  has  been 
held  rent-free  or  at  a  fixed  rent  since  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment, can  now  be  assessed  to  rent  or  enhanced ;  nor  in  any 
case  where  the  facts  are  such  that  a  suit  for  resumption  in 
a  Civil  Court  would  be  held  barred  by  limitation. 

§  1 6.    Publication  of  Rent-rolls. 

When  the  record  of  rents  is  complete,  if  under  the  earlier 
law,  only  so  much  of  it  as  includes  enhancements  must  be 


464  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

published  for  four  months,  during  which  period  a  civil  suit 
B.  Act  to  contest  the  orders  may  be  filed.  Under  the  Tenancy 
1879.  sees.  Act,  1885,  the  whole  roll  has  to  be  published  for  one  month, 
9.  I0-  within  which  objections  may  be  filed  (as  civil  suits)  before 

the  Settlement  Officer. 

§  17.    Record  of  Customs,  &c. 

In  all  important  Settlements,  a  record  is  made  of  village 
customs  regarding  rights  of  pasture,  and  waste  land,  forest, 
fisheries,  and  customs  as  to  payment  of  village  officials,  and 
the  like. 

§  1 8.    Assessment  of  Land-Revenue. 

Where  we  are  dealing  with  lands  that  have  a  recognized 
proprietor  other  than  the  State,  there  is  an  assessment  of 
land-revenue,  and  the  Settlement  is  one  strictly  so  called. 

The  Government  revenue  (as  above  explained)  is  a  pro- 
portion of  the  'assets,' — i.e.  the  total  rents  of  raiyat  lands, 
or  of  tenures  which  are  recognized  as  binding  on  the 
Government1,  plus  any  income  from  fisheries,  jungle,  or 
fruits,  or  mineral  profits  (if  there  are  any)  belonging  to  the 
proprietor. 

§  19.    Proportion  of  Assets  taken  by  Government. 

The  proportion  fixed  for  Settlement-holders  (properly  so 
called)  is  70  per  cent,  to  Government  and  30  to  the  Settle- 
ment-holder. 

Where  there  are,  as  in  Orissa,  sarbarakars  or  village 
headmen,  who,  though  Government  servants,  contract  for 
the  revenue  of  the  villages,  the  amount  of  the  allowance  is 

1  Where  there  are  no  '  tenures,'  as  binding  on  Government,  the 
the  whole  rent  of  the  raiyats  is  sums  received  accordingly  are  re- 
taken of  course  by  the  proprietors  ;  cognized  as  the  assets  ;  if  the  under- 
where  there  are,  the  proprietor  gets  tenures  are  invalid,  any  deductions 
only  so  much  less  than  the  full  are  the  proprietor's  concern.  His 
raiyati  rent  as  the  grants  of  the  assets  are  then  regarded  as  the 
under-tenure-holders  indicate.  And  rents  of  the  raiyats  irrespectively 
if  the  under-tenures  are  recognized  of  the  unrecognizable  under-tenure. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  465 

regulated  by  special  order  of  the  Board  of  Revenue  in  each 
case. 

In  Government  estates  managed  direct  (khas),  or  where 
the  raiyats  pay  direct  to  Government  (raiyatwari  tracts), 
there  is,  of  course,  no  question  of  dividing  the  proprietary 
assets  between  the  proprietor  and  Government,  because  they 
are  merged  in  one. 

But  should  Government  in  any  estate  make  an  arrange- 
ment for  its  rental  with  a  tenure-holder,  or  with  one  or 
more  of  its  principal  tenants,  the  rule  is  to  make  an  allow- 
ance of  20  per  cent,  on  the  total  rental  for  expenses  of 
collection  and  farming  profits1. 

This  is  a  convenient  place  at  which  to  offer  some  remarks 
on  the  percentage  taken  by  Government.  It  should  be 
remarked  that  the  '  proprietor  '  who  gets  only  30  per  cent., 
is  in  reality  a  person  with  no  strong  claims,  who  is  well 
remunerated  by  such  a  proportion  of  profits.  In  a  letter 
(N.  1917  Government  to  Board  of  Revenue),  dated  8th 
Sept.,  1874,  it  was  inquired  whether  30  per  cent,  was  not 
too  much,  and  whether  10  per  cent,  for  expenses  of  collec- 
tion and  10  per  cent,  for  profit  was  not  enough.  In  the 
Board's  office  is  an  excellent  printed  note  (dated  4th  June, 
1874)  on  the  whole  subject.  The  origin  of  the  percentage 
was  the  one-tenth,  i.e.  10  per  cent,  originally  allowed  (as 
already  stated)  by  the  Native  Governments  to  the  Zamin- 
dars  as  collectors  of  the  revenue.  When  the  proprietary 
position  of  the  various  kinds  of  landholder  was  recognized, 
naturally  it  was  desired  to  be  a  little  more  liberal,  so  when 
Regulation  VII  of  1822  was  passed,  section  7  (clause  2) 
mentions  20  per  cent,  as  the  minimum  profit  exclusive  of 
costs  of  collection.  In  Bengal  20  per  cent,  remained  the 
rule,  and  a  circular  of  1836  pointed  out2  that  the  10  per 

4» 

1  It  may  here  be  mentioned  that  anything  paid  to  a  proprietor  (or 

when  a  person  entitled  to  a  Settle-  oftener  ex-proprietor)  in  recognition 

ment  refuses  the  terms,  and  so  the  of  his  (lost)  right, 

estate  is  held  in  farm,  20  per  cent.  2  The  20  per  cent,  was  supposed 

is  also  allowed  to  the  farmer,  and  to  represent   10  per  cent,   costs  of 

10  per  cent,  as  malikana  to  the  ex-  collection  plus  10  per  cent,  allow- 

cluded  proprietor  for  the  term  of  ance  for  profit. 
his    exclusion.      Malikana    means 

VOL.  I.  H  h 


466  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

cent,  from  profits  was  to  be  on  the  balance  after  allowing 
for  10  per  cent,  as  costs  of  collection.  All  this  depended 
on  the  fact  that  the  so-called  proprietor  was  really  a  very 
artificial  creation — a  mere  farmer  called  proprietor.  In 
other  provinces,  where  the  person  called  landlord  was.  one 
who  had  a  strong  natural  right  in  the  land,  his  profits  were 
larger.  He  had  at  first  to  give  66  per  cent,  on  his  assets, 
very  loosely  calculated,  and  when  these  assets  were  more 
closely  ascertained  his  revenue  payment  was  reduced  to 
45  to  55  per  cent,  of  the  net  assets. 

§  20.     With  whom  the  Settlement  is  made. 

In  temporarily-settled  estates  there  is  always  some  one 
recognized  as  proprietor,  and  he  is  settled  with  ;  and  so  in 
the  case  of  resumed  or  lapsed  revenue-free  estates.  Where 
it  was  a  Settlement  for  land  that  was  in  excess  of  the 
holder's  proper  estate  (in  some  cases  under  Regulation  II  of 
1819),  the  Settlement  was  made  permanent,  because  at  the 
time  no  other  law  existed.  But  no  law  declared  all  '  taufir  ' 
land  to  be  entitled  to  such  a  benefit.  Hence,  when  the  Tem- 
porary Settlement  Law  was  passed,  such  lands  would  be 
settled  under  it,  and  with  the  person  who  could  prove  a 
title.  When  it  is  a  Settlement  for  alluvial  accretions  to 
existing  estates,  which  accretions  under  the  law  are  liable 
to  be  separately  settled,  the  Settlement  is  of  course  made 
with  the  owner  of  the  estate,  who  is  under  the  alluvion 
law  (Regulation  XI  of  1825)  entitled  to  the  accretions. 

§  21.    Alluvial  Settlements. 

I  shall  not  go  into  details  about  the  special  rules  regard- 
ing 'Deara  Settlements,'  as  they  are  called — the  Settle- 
ments of  alluvial  accretions.  They  apply  to  river  flats 
and  islands  (chars)  and  to  alluvial  lands  which  are  not 
accretions  but  are  the  property  of  Government ;  they  also 
contain  special  directions  regarding  the  survey  (Deara 
Survey).  They  can  be  read  in  the  Board's  '  Settlement 
Manual,'  1888. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORAEY    SETTLEMENTS.  467 

§  22.    Duration  of  Settlement. 

For  temporary  Settlements  there  is  no  rule  fixing  twenty 
years  or  thirty  years  or  any  other  period  ;  the  term  depends 
on  the  circumstances  of  the  estate,  and  is  usually  fixed  with 
reference  to  the  period  for  which  occupancy  rents  are  fixed 
(fifteen  years  or  ten  years,  according  to  the  law  in  force). 
And  the  periods  are  further  ordered  so  that  they  may  fall 
in  in  successive  years  in  the  different  divisions,  so  that 
Survey  and  Settlement  establishments  may  proceed  from 
one  district  to  another  as  their  services  are  required. 

§  23.    Records  of  Settlement. 

When  the  record  of  rents,  &c.,  has  been  published  and 
has  become  final,  clean  copies  are  prepared  for  deposit  in 
the  Collector's  office.  Under  the  Tenancy  Act  copies  or 
extracts  are  also  given  to  the  landlord  and  tenants.  An 
abstract  or  '  tirij  '  (written  also  'terij ')  is  made  out,  showing, 
in  a  convenient  form,  all  the  main  features  of  the  estate  or 
holding  with  the  owner,  tenure-holders,  raiyats,  &c.,  and 
the  payments  due  from  each 1. 

A  general  report  is  then  prepared  (either  for  each  village 
or  for  the  whole  tract,  as  may  be  ordered).     It  shows — 
(a)  the  number  of  tenants  of  each  class  ; 
(6)  the   area   and   classification  of  the  village  lands 
according   to   the  Survey   and    Settlement,   and 
also  according  to  the  landlord's  own  jamabandi, 
if  known ; 

(c)  the  rental  according  to  Settlement  and  according 

to  the  landlord's  jamabandi,  with  explanation 
of  increase  or  decrease,  amount  of  Government 
revenue,  and  comparison  of  rent  with  revenue  ; 

(d)  the  rates  of  rent  prevailing,  with  history  of  past 

enhancements ; 

(e)  proximity  to  markets ; 

1  Called  also  '  Sadharan-khatian.'  See  No.  10  in  the  Appendix  to  the 
Settlement  Manual. 

H  h  2 


468  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

(/)  facilities  for  irrigation  ; 

(g]  village    customs,    including    payment    of    village 

officials  ; 

(h)  arrangements  made  for  maintenance  of  records  ; 
(i)  other  matters  deserving  of  notice  which  do  not  find 

a  place  in  the  record  of  rights. 

Besides  these  particulars,  the  report  will  describe  the  whole 
tract  as  regards — 

1 .  General  features  of  the  tract. 

2.  Its  fiscal  history. 

3.  Statistical  results. 

4.  Comparison  of  condition  of  the  tract  as  regards  rentals 

before  and  after  the  Survey. 

5.  Final  results,  including  approximate  division  of  ex- 

penses under  the  heads  of — 
(a)  Survey. 
(6)  Record  of  rights. 

(c)  Preparation  and  distribution  of  records. 
The  report  also  makes  proposals  as  to  the  parties  to  be 
settled  with,  and  notices  arrangements  existing,  or  to  be 
made,  regarding  the  instalments  of  rent  and  revenue, 
which  must  be  adapted  to  local  circumstances,  seasons, 
and  harvests. 

§  24.    Sanction  of  Settlements. 

When  whole  districts  or  large  areas  are  settled,  the 
sanction  (as  usual)  of  the  Local  Government  and  of  the 
Government  of  India  is  required.  But  many  Settlements 
are  of  single  or  limited  estates.  The  following  are  the 
powers  of  sanction  in  that  case  : — 

Temporary  Settlements  up  to  a  rental  of  K.  500  . . .  The  Collector. 

From  K.  500  to  R.  10,000 The  Commissioner. 

From  R.  10,000  to  R.  25,000 

Also  when  the  Settlement  will  be  permanent  ^  The  Board  of  Revenue, 
under  a  statutory  right    


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  469 

§  25.    Supervision. 

The  Director  .of  Land  Records  and  Agriculture  super- 
vises all  Settlements  in  which  the  agency  of  the  Survey 
Department  is  employed  or  which  are  made  under  the 
Bengal  Tenancy  Act ;  and  his  services  are  available  for 
other  Settlements  at  the  discretion  of  the  Board.  He  exer- 
cises, in  respect  of  all  these  Settlements,  the  powers  of  a 
Commissioner,  save  in  matters  in  which  power  is  by  law 
vested  in  the  Commissioner  himself. 

§  26.    Conclusion. 

It  may  be  necessary  to  repeat  here,  that  for  matters  of 
detail,  the  Acts  and  Regulations  quoted  require  study,  and 
also  the  Settlement  Manual.  The  object  here  (as  in  the 
chapter  on  Revenue  business)  is  not  to  furnish  a  complete 
handbook  of  details,  but  an  introduction  or  general  guide 
to  the  principles  and  leading  features  of  the  system, — pre- 
paratory to  such  a  detailed  study  as  will  be  necessary  for 
officers  who  have  actually  to  take  their  part  in  district 
duty. 

§  27.    General  Conspectus  of  Estates. 

Such  being  the  general  principles  on  which  Temporary 
Settlements  are  made  in  tracts  owned  by  private  proprie- 
tors, and  on  which  Rents  are  fixed  in  Government  estates 
(whether  raiyatwari  tracts  or  managed  otherwise),  it  will 
be  desirable,  before  proceeding  to  an  account  of  special 
Settlements  in  certain  exceptional  districts,  to  give  some 
particulars  about  the  general  results  of  Settlements  and  the 
distribution  of  the  different  classes  of  estates. 

The  general  map,  showing  the  prevalence  of  the  various 
Settlement  systems,  indicates,  as  far  as  Bengal  is  concerned, 
the  Permanent  Settlements  in  one  colour,  and  those  districts 
which  are  as  a  whole  temporarily  settled — i.  e.  the  districts 
of  Orissa — in  another  colour.  An  attempt  has  also  been 


470 


LAND   SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  ir. 


fi-S 

*   3 

g 

-S 

1           1 

a 

»i 

a 

1 

05 

0  a 

0 

3 

s 

3    ID      " 

r~* 

3 

-2  2 

M 

•a 

PH 

oS_g 

0> 

H 

!*» 

p 

1 

*  11 

* 

a 

d 

ON  -<f 

oo 

CO 

*2 

3    0} 

CO 

C-    M 

If 

ff 

CO 

oo 

Hi      [*• 

ON  c- 

« 
0 

(4 

« 

H 

"3^ 

<M     °° 

O   <R 

# 

* 

K 

to| 

M 

^ 

.9  . 

M 

H  co  m  m      o 

CO  w    N    O           CN 

\O      ON    M     H               Tj- 

TJ-  r^  Cvl    O  vO 
co  vo  m  o  co 
•*vo  cq  co  i> 

m  m  T»-  m  ON  o 
00    CO  in  •*  O\  ON 
!N    CO  CO  ON  O    ON 

co  H  m  o 

O    (M    O    •* 

Tf    TTVO     CO 

ij 

••*•          oo       co 

•*•         CO 

COCO    CO  w    r- 
ON  M         CO  W 

tj-       00    CO  Tt- 
IH          CO        (M 

r-  HI    -^-  ON 

co  co  co  M 

1-1 

W 

H                        M 

N 

o 
O 

d| 

HI  ON  W  TJ-      in 

•*•    H              0             Tj- 

<-<                 O          <N 

r-  cj  m  w  r^ 

O    C-vO  00    ON  I> 

HO)                     Tj-    O 
M 

O    TTOO    O 

HI      M      CO 

£ 

_g 

ON       \O    ON        CO 
0       in  in       HI 

H  oi  m  o  co 

«    VO      Tt-    Tj-    CO 

m  IN  oo  i>  co 

co  o  co       in 

ON  O          CO 

m  IN       co 

CO  CO  w  00 
CO  C^  ON  0) 
O    O    O    ON 

Iff 

a  S, 
I1 

GO 

vO    0    "I-  I>  ON 

vo  in           « 

on      oo 

IN 

ONVO    m  CO 
CO  ON  CO\O 

H 

o 
| 

•si 

O          H    ON         (M 

CO             IN        r- 

01    O    O  vO    if) 

«  vo  in  N  \o 

O     M     ON          CO 

CO    HI                t- 

r-  co  O   co 
oo  in  M   ov 

o'-B 

H 

^- 

• 

v  r  

>  v  ' 

^ 

CO 

H 

ON 

C 

.g 

r~ 

CO 

HI 

<§ 

m 

§ 

rt    p^ 

oo 

oo 

TJ- 

a 

ID 
02 

fefl 
M 

\0 

Tt- 

* 

<u 

-s| 

oo  o  M  vo       in 

CO  ON  O    ON        IH 
00  CO    O  \O        VO 

oo    r-  r^  o\  in 
00    ON  co  m  H 
m  M  xj-  c—  co 

r~  in  co  O   -^-  HI   (M 

M  t^  in  m 

00      •*•    t-l      Tj- 

M  vO    O  vO 

<0 

J^  "S 

-*•         H    <N          CO 

M    N    N          « 

M                     H 

oo  m  covo 

Pk 

H 

:        :    us 

01      .     '.     .     . 

:        :    i'$ 

*  :-  ;  :i 

O     '•'•'•  ^ 

i  =i4 

I 

i 

i 

i 

|||||w 

a    i   i   :•" 

lull 

jllll 

ill 

S  a 

.'ill 

2  'S  S  S. 
fi^MS 

f 

^                                ^ 

^_     ^  . 

1 
C 

! 

^K 

i 

"3 

1 

^ 

9 

i 

J 

(• 

1 

§ 

i 

Hi 

8 

pq 

CM 

M 

Q 

CHAP.  II.] 


THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS. 


471 


Jjjfs 

rif 

•3.2  ®  J 

0 

•M    £*<£• 

C 

C 

Q     00   •+»     M* 

S 

"o     *S  || 

•e 

Mil 

O  "~  *""* 

g 

*rt  re  •? 

M 

NO  ^-  o            in 

Tt-    Tt- 

ON 

CO 

r»  ON  in              ON 

CM  in 

N    O  OO                 Tf 

t-  0 

cT 

T? 

r~  cf  M"               ON 

•*•  IN               vq^ 

ci  NO" 

ON 

in 

M 

oo" 

# 

M 

0)      M      M                           M 

CO    M 

CM 

CO 

O     M     CO 

ON  r-  M 

<N  "i-NO  co  in  M  IN 

CO    1-1    O    O    C^CO    c^ 

NO  NO  00  NO        00 
M    M-  in  (M           C- 

ONNO    (M 
r»  IN    Tf 

in  co 

ON  CO 

CO 
CO 

«   i-^  in 

O    ONCO    ON  CO  r*1 

o  *^*co  ON      in 

r^NO    c^ 

O      M 

inccToo" 

••?  4-  cf  cf  cf  H" 

co"  d\  <N"NO'       cf 

•4-  r^  cf 

NO"  •*? 

CO" 

NO  q  i-i,      H 

M                        M 

NO    NO     N 

C^NO 

0 

co  i-T 

M^   t-T 

<N" 

CO 

CM 

in  moo 

CO    IN 

O    CO  CO  Tj-00  00    M 
\O    ^~00  NO          H 

r-  in  ^NO       in 

in  co  o 
o 

gNO 

r- 

0 

M      M 

M 

CO 

CO 

CO 

CO    M    IN 

q  co^q 

in  r»  CM  co  c—  NO  t— 

CO    H     M     ON   -*•    ON   l> 

r»  H  ot  co  in  in  M 

T)-  (M    H    ON         ON 

w  NO  m  in       in 
cq  NO  t>cc^       in 

ON  IN    i^- 
CO    ONNO 
r-  M.  CO 

0*  ON 
CO  NO 

NO 
1O 

ON  w"  in 

in  T?  o"  cT      of  i-T 

co           in       i-T 

NO    CO  CM 

:  oo"  t-T 

rt- 

CO  CM 

H      W      C^    M                 M 

CO                 w 

M      O_^     10 

"O 

l>  CO  CO 

C) 

CO  CO  <N 
*  ON 

M    CO  O    •<*-  0)    ONNO 
«    IN  00    IN          in 

M    CO  ON  in        CO 

Tj-                         MM 

O    CO  CO 

co  m  co 

;    (N    CM 

't- 

00 

ON  T}-  CO 

oo 

CO          <- 

-  —  ^-- 

-                (  - 

—  -—  '' 

—  —  V  

—  ^-^-^-' 

I 

ON 

CO 

NO 

in 

r^ 

ON 

^*" 

r- 

CO 

Tj- 

CO 

i> 

cf 

$ 

cf 

NO 

CO 

vq 

o" 

O\ 

ON 

r- 

c" 

M 

«" 

CM" 

r^» 

CO 

CM 

CO 

r^\o    O 

CM    rj-  in 

co  co  r-  H  n  co  Tf 

NO    CJ    w    M  CO    O    ON 

M    COCO    CO         ON 

ONCO  M  in       >n 

CO  O'JCO 
Cl          •* 

00  NO    M    TJ- 

NO  in      CM 

co 

fin  co 

COCO    CO  n    ^*-  ^h  O 

NO  co  NO  in      ^~ 

Q\ 

M     M 

ON  in^O    r^  O    -*  rn 

NO     ^*    1 

t^* 

iO 

M 

.    .    .    .   i 

Chittagong  
Noakh&li  
Tipperah  , 

I 

:    :    :    :  fl 

M          :                % 

%M  * 

"S>^§^2^ 
§3  3^  g  g 

u   o  *s 

68  S  % 
S  o  ^3 

S    O  'S3 

OPnW 

fill 

M      M    J*    t^ 

1  1  ^b  a 

W  P-)  SS 

1 

C 

a 

0 

1   " 

M 



"^T" 

)q 

p 

s  * 

O 

d. 

S3 

| 

•< 

^ 

^ 

. 

g 

g 

v° 

1 

s  - 

a 

PH 

M 

0 

K  £ 
Q 

472  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

made  to  indicate  by  a  third  colour  the  larger  raiyatwdri 
and  Government  estates ;  but  it  was  not  possible  to  show 
all  such  tracts,  on  account  of  their  (often)  small  size  and 
the  way  in  which  they  are  scattered  about  in  the  districts. 

In  the  Board  of  Revenue's  Annual  Reports  it  is  now  the 
practice  to  insert  district-maps  which  show  the  Government 
estates. 

Taking  the  Report  for  1888-89,  Appendix  II  gives  (A) 
the  permanently-settled  estates  ;  (B)  the  temporarily-settled 
estates  ;  and  (C)  the  Government  estates,  separating  the 
raiyatwari  tracts  under  (D). 

The  Government  estates  in  (C)  all  appear  as  either 
settled  for  definite  periods  or  occasionally  '  farmed '  or 
managed  direct  owing  to  recusancy  of  the  proprietors1. 
The  table  on  p.  470  is  an  abstract  of  this  Appendix  IL 
designed  to  give  the  student  an  idea  of  the  distribution  of 
estates  in  those  general  classes  2. 

The  numbers  of  permanently-settled  estates  vary  by 
reason  of  partitions,  which  are  most  numerous  in  the 
Patna  division  districts :  the  temporarily-settled  estates 
also  vary  chiefly  by  reason  of  alluvial  accretions. 

No.  of 
Estate. 

1  These  cases  of  recusancy,  I  be-       i.  Permanently-settled  Es- 

lieve,  are  where  the  lands  are  un-  tates  of  1793  1262 

productive  and  the  holders  do  not       2.  Resumed  Revenue-free  of 

care  to  undertake  the  Settlement  re-  1 793  98 

sponsibility.  3.  Islands,  &c.,  excess  ('tau- 

2  Under  those  general  classes  the  fir')  lands  settled  under 
individual  estates  maybe  in  great  Regulation  II  of  18:9...       103 
variety  of  origin  as  the  result  of  the  4.  Estates   sold   for  arrears 
operation  of  different  laws  and  cir-  and  then  permanently 
cumstances.     For  example,  in  the               settled  (Section  6  of  Re- 
Tipperah  (Tipra)  district  the  follow-  gulation  VIII  of  1793") .       167 
ing    details   appear    (Statistical   Ac-  5.  Tenures  temporarily  set- 

count    of  Bengal,    vol.   vi.   pp.    400-  tied  (this  includes  Go- 

440)  : —  veriiment  Estates) 241 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEAEY    SETTLEMENTS.  473 


SECTION  III. — THE  OEISSA  SETTLEMENTS. 

The  three  districts  of  modern  Orissa — including  the 
Pat&spur  pargaha — were  acquired  after  the  Maratha  war  in 
1803,  so  they  did  not  come  under  the  Permanent  Settlement 
Regulations.  That  Settlement  only  affected,  more  or  less,  the 
Midnapore  district  which  (excluding  Pataspur)  was  the  old 
Orissa  of  1765.  Midnapore  is  not  now  spoken  of  as 
'  Orissa '  at  all. 

These  districts  were  originally  the  seat  of  Hindu  king- 
doms— '  Rajputs,'  who  at  a  remote  period  invaded,  conquered 
and  ruled  over  the  Kolarian  and  Dravidian  population. 
The  conquest  probably  only  extended  to  the  level  and 
culturable  districts,  for  the  Kolarian  and  other  tribes  in 
the  hilly  country  were  found  following  their  own  customs, 
but  little  if  at  all  changed.  The  incursion  of  the  '  Y&vanas,' 
and  other  events,  detailed  in  Hunter's  Orissa,  cannot  now 
be  traced  in  any  effect  they  may  have  had  on  the  land- 
system,  and  so  I  pass  them  over. 

The  Rajputs  were  in  the  end  overthrown  by  the  Muham- 
madan  king  of  Bengal;  and  Orissa  was  finally  swept  into 
the  dominions  of  the  Mughal  Emperor.  But  in  the  middle 
of  the  eighteenth  century,  the  Marathas  succeeded  to  a 
short-lived  domination.  Neither  of  these  later  powers  had 
therefore  the  time  and  the  opportunity  to  modify  very 
deeply  the  land-tenures ;  and  we  do  not  find  any  '  Zamin- 
dars,'  in  the  sense  of  contractors  for  the  revenue,  like  those 
in  Bengal. 

The  Rajput  kingdom  was  organized  here  as  it  was  else- 
where ;  for  the  remains  of  this  organization  are  still 
manifest. 

The  country  consists,  roughly  speaking — (i)  of  a  marshy 
tract  on  the  coast,  full  of  swamp  forest  like  the  Sundar- 
bans  ;  (2)  a  belt  of  rice-land  and  other  cultivation ;  (3)  a 
hilly  tract  beyond,  going  up  into  the  hill  ranges  of  the 
'  South- West  Frontier.' 

As  might  be  expected,  the  chief  Raja  had  his  '  khalsa '  or 


474  LANr>    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

demesne  lands  in  the  best  and  level  parts,  and  the  hill 
tracts  were  the  territories  or  estates  of  his  feudal  chieftains, 
who  held  them  and  took  the  revenue  on  condition  of  keep- 
ing the  country  quiet.  With  the  estates  of  these  chieftains 
the  Mughals  appear  not  to  have  interfered,  but  the  rice- 
tract  (2)  was  called  the  'Mughalbandi,'  and  was  regularly 
assessed  to  revenue. 

The  Marathas  in  turn  assessed  the  chiefs  to  a  tribute  or 
quit-rent.  On  the  British  annexation  in  1803  the  chiefs' 
estates  were  maintained.  Some  have  been  recognized  as 
'  tributary  chiefs '  —  the  '  Tributary  Mahals  '  of  Orissa. 
These  are  not  subject  to  any  regular  Settlement  and 
Revenue  system  ;  they  are  managed  in  the  Political  De- 
partment, and  this  work  is  not  concerned  with  them. 

There  were  nineteen  of  them  formerly ;  but  two  were  con- 
fiscated,— Angul  in  1847  for  the  rebellion  of  its  Raja  ;  and 
Banki  in  1840,  the  chief  having  been  convicted  of  murder1. 

A  certain  number  of  the  chiefships  nearer  the  plains 
were,  though  not  placed  in  the  first  rank,  favoured  so  far 
that  they  were  granted  a  Permanent  Settlement,  and  this  fact 
accounts  for  the  permanently-settled  estates  shown  in  the 
table  under  the  Orissa  districts.  These  estates  were  called 
'  qila"  (i.e.  forts — territories  surrounding  and  protected 
by  the  chiefs  residence).  The  estates  were  treated  as  in 
the  position  of  full-rated  permanently-assessed  Zamindari 
estates.  At  first,  fifty  such  estates  were  proposed  to  be 
constituted.  The  rest  of  the  province  was  left  to  the 
ordinary  (temporary)  Settlement. 

On  the  1 5th  September,  1804,  a  proclamation  regarding 
the  Settlement  was  issued ;  and  this  was  afterwards  em- 
bodied in  the  Regulation  XTT  of  1805.  The  plan  was  first 
to  settle  for  one  year,  then  to  grant  a  three  years'  lease. 
Then  a  four  years'  lease  was  offered  at  an  increase  to  be 

1  Angul    and    Banki    now   form  £3,322  to  the  British  Government. 

'  Government    Estates  ' — Angul    as  This  tract  was  called  '  Rajwara '  or 

part  of  the  Piiri  district,  Banki  in  Garhjat,  as  opposed  to  the  revenue- 

Katak.     The  remaining  seventeen  paying  plain  called  '  Mughalbandi.' 

states  consist  of  15,187  square  miles,  The  chiefs  were  locally  known  as 

with  a  population  of  nearly  a  million  '  Khandaits.' — Hunter, 
and  a  half.    They  pay  a  tribute  of 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  475 

obtained  by  adding  two-thirds  of  the  net  increase  of  any 
one  year  of  the  three  years'  Settlement,  to  the  total  assess- 
ment amount  of  that  lease.  At  the  expiration  of  the  four 
years  it  was  announced  that  for  such  lands  as  then  were  in 
a  sufficiently  improved  state  of  cultivation,  a  Permanent 
Settlement  would  be  concluded  on  such  terms  as  the 
Government  considered  fair  and  equitable. 

The  Regulation  next  refers  to  the  '  Tributary  Mahals,' 
which  it  exempts  from  the  Regulations.  Of  the  second 
class  of  estates  above  mentioned,  eleven  were  selected  ;  the 
sanads  granting  a  permanent  assessment  to  nine  of  them, 
which  had  been  issued  by  the  Board  of  Commissioners 
(appointed  to  manage  Orissa,  or  the  Katak  province  as  it 
was  then  called),  were  confirmed.  Khurda1  and  Kanika 
were  directed  to  be  treated  in  the  same  manner  hereafter. 
These  eleven  estates  however  differed  only  from  the  rest  of 
the  district  in  having  the  assessment  fixed  for  ever. 
The  history  of  the  Settlements  is  briefly  as  follows  : — 
Certain  changes  as  regards  the  revenue  (of  no  impor- 
tance now)  were  made  by  Regulations  X  of  1807  and  VI 
of  1 808 ;  and  when  the  last  or  four  years'  Settlement 
became  due,  a  Special  Commission  was  appointed  to  make 
it  with  due  care :  for  it  was  supposed  it  would  be  made 
permanent  if  the  Home  Government  approved.  But  the 
Home  Government  by  this  time  had  seen  the  evil  of  hastily 
concluding  Permanent  Settlements  ;  they  did  not  approve2, 
and  Regulation  X  of  1812  was  passed  to  declare  the  fact, 
but  (as  was  done  in  the  Upper  Provinces)  still  held  out  the 
hope  of  a  permanent  assessment  iclien  the  state  of  the  lands 


1  Khurda  soon  afterwards  (1804)  indeed  a  model,  Government  estate. 

was  confiscated   owing  to   the   re-  2  See   Kaye,  p.  239.     It  will   be 

bellion   of   the   Raja.     The   titular  observed  that  the  principles  adopted 

Raja  was    hereditary   guardian   of  for  Orissa  were  exactly  the  same  as 

the  Jagan-nath  temple,  and  he  was  those   in   the   Regulations   of  1805 

maintained  as  such,  as  a  pensioner.  for  the  North-West  Provinces.    It  is 

But  the  holder  of  the  title  in  1878  instructive    to    note   the    prevail- 

was  convicted  of  murder  and  de-  ing     ideas    on     revenue     matters, 

ported.   The  estate  of  Khurda, which  as  exhibited  by  the  Regulations  of 

gave  some  trouble  in  1804  by  re-  this  date,  and  how  they  had  begun 

bellion,  and  again   in  1817-18,  is  to  be  doubted  at  home, 
now  a  large  and  well-ordered,  and 


47^  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

was  such  as  to  recommend  it.  Regulations  of  1815  and 
1816  made  some  further  provisions  which  are  now  of  no 
interest. 

In  1818  disturbances  occurred,  due  in  great  measure  to 
the  operation  of  the  Sale  Law1,  and  a  Special  Commissioner 
was  appointed  (Regulation  V  of  1818).  In  the  same  year 
Regulation  XIII  extended  the  existing  Settlements  for 
three  years,  so  as  to  afford  due  time  to  the  revenue  officers 
to  collect  the  materials  necessary  for  the  formation  of  a 
new  Settlement  on  proper  principles. 

Though  the  '  materials  '  were  not  ready,  the  outlines  of 
the  new  Settlement  system — imperfect,  but  in  the  right 
direction — had  been  determined  on.  Regulation  VII "of 
1822,  was  passed  for  Katak  (i.e.  the  Orissa  districts),  cer- 
tain parganas  (Pataspur,  &c.)  which  are  part  of  the  Mid- 
napore  district,  and  for  the  districts  of  the  North  -Western 
Provinces. 

The  history  of  this  Regulation,  and  of  the  recognition  of 
its  defects  and  their  removal  by  Regulation  IX  of  1833,  is 
stated  more  fully  in  the  account  of  the  North -Western 
Provinces  (vol.  ii.). 

The  Regulation  (Sec.  2)  once  more  extended  the  existing 
Katak  Settlements  for  five  years,  and  Act  VI  of  1837  de- 
clared that  the  Settlement  should  continue  until  a  new  one 
was  made.  The  first  regular  Settlement,  with  a  survey  and 
record  of  rights,  was  made  in  1838-45. 

In  1856  a  revision  was  undertaken.  In  1867,  Bengal 
Act  X  again  extended  the  Settlement ;  this  time  for  thirty 
years  ;  so  that  there  will  be  no  further  revision  till  1897  2. 

The  Settlement  was  made  with  various  kinds  of  estate- 
holders,  either  individuals  or  joint  families, — malguzars  (as 
Act  VI  of  1837  calls  them),  who  had  grown  up  over  the 
villages — as  we  shall  see  hereafter. 


1  Field,  p.  68 1,  note.  is  a  minute  on  the  Province  by  the 

2  There  is  an  abstract  of  the  history  Commissioner  (A.  J.  Moffat  Mills, 
of  the  early  Settlements  in  Mr.Stack's  1847);  and  Macneile's  Memorandum 
Memorandum  on  Temporary  Settlements,  on  Revenue  Administration  in  Bengal, 
1880,    p.    579.     In    the    Selections  1873,  also  contains  ample  inform- 
from  Bengal  Records,  No.  III.  1851,  ation. 


CHAP   II.]  THE    TEMPORAKY    SETTLEMENTS.  477 

The  estates  were  then  assessed  village  by  village ;  and 
there  were  in  most  cases  subordinate  tenures  or  interests 
of  headmen  and  village -managers  who  collected  the  pro- 
prietors' rents ;  these  were  entitled  to  a  certain  allowance 
representing  their  own  interest,  so  that  the  Settlement  is 
spoken  of  as  '  mauzawar.'  As  a  matter  of  fact,  all  the 
village  lands  were  cultivated  by  '  thani '  (i.  e.  resident) 
raiyats,  or  by  '  pai '  (i.  e.  non-resident)  raiyats,  and  some 
were  held  as  the  village  headman's  '  sir '  or  free  holding  in 
virtue  of  his  office  (a  relic  of  the  former  Dravidian 
organization). 

The  plan  of  settling  a  lump  sum  of  revenue  for  the 
village — the  '  aggregate  to  detail  method,'  and  then  dis- 
tributing this  sum  over  the  holdings — was  rejected.  The 
Settlement  Officer  determined  separately  the  rents  of  the 
holding  of  each  raiyat,  and,  putting  a  value  on  the  'sir' 
land,  added  the  whole  together.  The  total  revenue  was  60 
to  70  per  cent,  of  the  rental  assets  so  ascertained.  But  the 
nominal  landlord  did  not  get  even  the  30  or  40  per  cent. 
which  remained  ;  for  there  were  the  village-headmen  or 
managers,  who  directly  collected  the  village  rental  and  had 
certain  rights — almost  like  sub-proprietors — in  virtue  of 
which  they  received  a  percentage,  20  to  25  per  cent,  if  a 
muk^dam  or  pradhan  {hereditary  headman).  15  to  20  if 
a  sarbarakar  (manager). 

§  i.    The  JKhurdd  Estate. 

This  estate,  occupying  a  considerable  portion  of  the 
inland  side  of  the  Piiri  district,  is  one  of  the  Government 
estates,  managed  as  a  '  raiyatwari  tract.' l  For  some  years 
after  the  confiscation  in  1804,  separate  survey-Settlements 
were  made  by  '  mahals '  or  groups  of  land,  with  local 
managers  called  sarbarakars  ;  but  in  the  last  quinquennial 
Settlement,  care  was  taken  to  make  the  sarbardkdrs  give 
the  raiyats  leases  at  rates  fixed  for  the  whole  term.  In 
1836,  a  regular — virtually  raiyatwari — Settlement  was 

1  There  is  a  printed  volume  of  Selections  from  the  Correspondence  relating  to 
the  Khurdd  Estate,  1879. 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 

made,  at  rates  ascertained  for  classes  of  soil  and  applied  by 
measurement.  Sarbarakars  were,  however,  charged  with 
the  responsibility  for  the  revenue  of  the  whole  area.  In 
j  853,  some  three  years  before  the  expiry  of  the  term  of  Settle- 
ment, a  renewal  was  offered  to  the  sarbarakars  at  the  old 
rates,  plus  the  assessment  recorded  for  the  culturable  waste 
fields,  on  the  supposition  that  they  had  been,  or  would  soon 
be,  all  taken  under  the  plough.  This  proposal  was  de- 
clined ;  consequently  actual  measurement  of  the  extended 
cultivation  was  made.  And  the  Settlement  so  made  expired 
in  1880.  Preparations  for  the  revision  that  then  became 
due,  began  in  1875,  and  the  estate  was  cadastrally  sur- 
veyed. The  produce  of  fields  was  ascertained  by  declara- 
tion of  the  raiyats  themselves,  and  an  acreage  produce 
rate  being  thus  established,  villages  were  classified  into 
homogeneous  tracts,  ranked  into  grades,  and  revenue  rates 
applied  accordingly.  The  Government  share  had  been  fixed 
at  one-fifth l  of  the  average  gross  produce.  The  sarbarakars 
still  collect  the  revenue,  and  are  allowed  a  deduction  to 
cover  their  risk  and  expenses.  Joint  bodies  of  sarbarakars 
are  avoided,  and  it  is  arranged  so  that  each  sharer  in  a 
family  gets  a  separate  village.  Mr.  Stack  compares  the 
sarbarakar,  who  is  thus  a  paid  collector,  not  a  proprietor, 
to  the  '  mauzadar '  described  under  the  Assam  system.  The 
Settlement  shows  a  considerable  increase  of  revenue  and 
works  admirably.  The  raiyats'  holdings  are  generally 
small.  The  average  of  172  test  villages  gives  no  more  than 
i  s  acre  to  each  raiyat.  The  raiyat's  rent  is  fixed  for  the 
term  of  Settlement ;  but  there  is  no  relinquishing  and 
taking  up  lands,  and  consequently  no  annual  'jamabandi,' 
as  under  other  raiyatwari  systems,  is  necessary. 

1  The  proposal  was  one-fourth,  but  it  was  ultimately  fixed  as  stated. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  479 


SECTION  IV. — THE  WASTE  LAND  RULES. 

§  i.    Importance  of  the  Subject. 

This  subject  seems  one  which  demands  a  certain  detail  in 
treatment.  The  economist,  and  perhaps  also  the  capitalist, 
may  be  interested  to  know  how  (for  example)  the  'tea-estates' 
of  Darjiling  and  Assam  had  their  origin ;  and  perhaps  to 
inquire  how  land  for  cultivation  of  imported  staples  can 
still  be  obtained.  The  whole  system  of  dealing  with  waste 
lands  depends  on  the  principle  developed  in  Chapter  IV  of 
Book  I,  that  waste  and  unoccupied  land  is  at  the  disposal 
of  the  State. 

In  Bengal,  as  already  stated,  the  Permanent  Settlement 
only  extended  to  the  estates  actually  possessed,  or  to  allu- 
vial accretions  which  (though  separately  assessable)  were 
afterwards  formed  upon  their  boundaries.  In  tolerably 
settled  parts  this  gave  rise  to  no  difficulties  ;  but  where 
there  were  large  tracts  of  waste  it  was  otherwise.  In  1819, 
it  seems,  the  subject  first  came  under  notice,  but  that  notice 
did  not  extend  to  the  question  of  ownership ;  the  Regula- 
tion II  of  that  year  only  declared  the  lands  assessable.  The 
authorities  of  the  day  were  perhaps  only  too  glad  to  see  waste 
taken  up,  and  seemed  to  think  that  if  it  had  been  occupied 
de  facto,  no  matter  how,  they  might  accept  the  fact,  treating 
the  occupier  as  lawful  owner ;  what  was  more  essential  was 
to  provide  for  his  duly  paying  land-revenue. 

Regulation  II  of  1819  specially  mentions  the  case  of  the 
Sundarbans  *, — the  forest  tract  on  the  delta  between  the 
Hughli  and  Megna  rivers.  The  waste  lands  there  occu- 
pied were  in  fact  temporarily-cultivated  lots  known  as 
'patitabadi  taluqs,'  and  were  encroachments  from  the 
regular  estates  inland.  Hence  arose  the  practice  of  calling 
these  irregularly-occupied  lands  '  tauf  ir '  or  excess,  i.  e. 

1  As  to  the  early  attempts  to  issue  times,  grants  began  to  be  asked  for 

clearing  leases,  see  article  '  Sundar-  in  1807,  and  up  to  1872  nearly  1087 

bans'  in  Imp.  Gaz.,  vol.  xiii.  p.  no.  square  miles  had  been  brought  under 

They  date  back  to  1782.     In  later  cultivation. 


480  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

assuming  that  they  were  extensions  of  regular  estates.  On 
this  ground  perhaps  such  lands  were  treated  as  entitled  to 
be  permanently  assessed1.  At  any  rate,  this  was  the  prac- 
tice till  after  the  Temporary  Regulation  (1822)  had  become 
law.  The  Regulation  did  not,  indeed,  in  terms,  apply  to 
anything  but  the  '  Ceded  and  Conquered '  Provinces ;  but 
obviously,  if  the  land  was  not  entitled  to  a  permanent 
assessment,  the  Government  could  assess  it  for  a  term. 

A  particular  instance  of  this  occurs  in  the  case  of  the 
districts  of  Sylhet  and  Cachar ;  but  as  these  districts, 
once  part  of  Bengal,  were  attached  to  Assam  in  1874,  the 
history  of  them — and  it  well  illustrates  this  section — must 
be  looked  for  in  the  chapters  relating  to  Assam. 

In  1828  (Regulation  III)  further  and  more  definite  pro- 
vision was  made  regarding  assessment,  and  it  was  then 
declared  that  the  '  waste '  was  Government  property. 

§  2.    The  Sundarbans. 

In  the  Sundarbans,  the  first  occupied  lands  (higher  up 
on  the  delta)  appear  all  to  have  been  recognized  as  having 
proprietors 2.  But  in  time  '  Waste  Land  Rules '  were  pro- 
vided, and  then  there  was  an  end  to  irregular  occupation. 
A  part  of  the  area  is  now  taken  up  as  State  forest ;  it  is 
the  great  source  of  fuel-supply  to  Calcutta,  besides  yielding 
many  valuable  woods  for  building  and  for  industrial  pur- 
poses. Waste  land  rules  for  the  Sundarbans  had  been 
issued  as  early  as  1825,  but  they  were  ineffectual  (Macneile, 
§  173),  and  the  first  useful  code  seems  to  have  been  that  of 
1853.  Under  these  rules  1773  square  miles  were  granted. 
The  land  was  held  subject  to  a  revenue  payment  which  was 

1  Mr.    Macneile's    Memorandum  darbans     to     be     State     property, 
(§  167)  mentions  that  the  squatters  although  parts  of  it  had  been  occu- 
were  so  fully  treated  as  owners,  that  pied  before  1819.  This  led  to  various 
in   cases  where  they   refused    the  orders  and  legal  contests  (see  Mac- 
'taufir'   assessment  they  were  al-  neile's   Memorandum,    §§    166-70". 
lowed  malikana  like  excluded  pro-  The     right     of    Government    was 
prietors  on  regular  estates.  affirmed ;  but  in  the  end,  hard  cases 

2  In  one  place  indeed,  the  Regu-  were  allowed,  and  the  occupiers  re- 
lation distinctly  declares  the  Sun-  cognized  as  proprietors. 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY   SETTLEMENTS.  481 

progressive.  In  1889,  474,080  acres  (of  which  the  maxi- 
mum revenue  would  be  R.  137,231)  were  still  held  under 
the  terms  of  the  rules  of  1853.  But  the  rules  themselves 
were  superseded  by  the  Sale  Rules  of  1863. 

These  rules  were  made  after  Lord  Canning's  Minute  of 
1  86  11  on  the  disposal  of  waste  lands.  As  regards  the 
Sundarbans,  they  did  not  prove  successful.  Only  a 
few  lots  were  sold  ;  and  seven  out  of  twelve  fell  in  for 
default  in  payment  of  the  purchase-money.  For  a  time 
recourse  was  had  once  more  to  the  rules  of  1853.  In  1871 
a  committee  reported  on  the  whole  subject,  and  in  1879 
another  set  of  rules  was  issued. 


'The  rules  of  iSyg2  differ  from  the  rules  of  1853  in  pro- 
viding a  rent-free  period  of  only  ten  years,  and  in  laying  down 
only  one  clearance  condition,  viz.  that  one-eighth  of  the  entire 
grant  should  be  rendered  fit  for  cultivation  at  the  end  of  the 
fifth  year.  This  condition  may  be  enforced  either  by  forfeiture 
of  the  grant  or  by  the  issue  of  a  fresh  lease,  omitting  the  re- 
mainder of  the  rent-free  period,  and  requiring  payment  of  rent 
at  enhanced  rates  during  the  term  of  grant. 

'  The  rules  also  provide  for  gradually  increasing  rates  of 
assessment  after  the  expiration  of  the  rent-free  period,  and 
varying  rates  within  different  tracts  according  to  the  rent- 
paying  capabilities  of  the  land.  It  is  further  provided  that 
there  shall  be  constantly  recurring  renewals  of  the  lease  on 
re-settlement.  The  term  of  the  original  lease  is  fixed  at  forty 
years,  and  re-settlements  are  to  be  made  after  periods  of  thirty 
years  ;  maximum  rates  being  laid  down  for  each  re-settlement. 

'  The  limits  within  which  lands  may  be  held  for  leasing  are 
fixed  in  consultation  with  the  Forest  Department.  An  accu- 
rate definition  of  boundaries  is  provided  for.  The  maximum 
area  of  grants  is  restricted  to  5000  bighas,  the  minimum  being 
200.  Cultivation  must  not  be  scattered  all  over  the  area  of  the 
land,  but  proceed  regularly  through  the  blocks  ;  and  leases  are 
to  be  sold  at  an  upset  price  when  there  is  only  one  applicant, 
and  to  the  highest  bidder  when  there  are  more  than  one. 

'  The  leases  confer  an  occupancy  right  hereditary  and  trans- 
ferable. Survey  fees  are  payable  by  the  applicant,  at  the  rate 

1  This  minute  is  described  further  2  Quoted   from   the   Report,   1883, 

on.  page  22. 

VOL.  I.  I  1 


482  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  ir. 

of  four  annas  an  acre,  as  also  a  deposit  of  R.  16  for  notices  to 
objectors.  Eefunds  and  adjustments  of  fees  deposited  are 
permitted.  Rights  of  way  and  water  and  other  easements  are 
reserved.  The  right  of  using  all  streams  in  any  way  navigable, 
and  the  use  of  a  tow-path  not  less  than  25  feet  wide  on  each 
side  of  such  stream,  are  also  reserved  to  the  public  ;  while 
Government  reserves  to  itself  the  right  to  all  minerals  in  the 
land,  together  with  rights  of  way  and  other  reasonable  facilities 
for  working,  getting,  and  carrying  away  such  minerals.  No 
charge  is  made  for  timber  on  the  land  at  the  time  it  is  leased, 
nor  for  any  cut  or  burnt  to  effect  clearances  or  used  on  the 
land  ;  but  a  duty  is  levied  on  any  exported  for  sale. 

'  Forms  of  preliminary  grant  called  'amalnamas  —  for  plots  of 
land  below  200  bighas— are  given  to  small  settlers,  guaranteeing 
them  a  formal  lease  for  thirty  years  if  the  lands  are  brought 
under  cultivation  within  two  years.  The  thirty  years'  lease 
allows  a  rent-free  term  of  two  years,  and  then  progressive  rates 
of  rent  on  the  cultivated  area,  fixed  with  reference  to  the  rates 
paid  in  the  neighbourhood  by  raiyats  to  landholders  for  similar 
lands. 

'  If  available,  an  area  of  unreclaimed  land  equal  to  the  culti- 
vated area  is  included  in  the  lease,  and  in  addition  the  lessee 
can  bring  under  cultivation  any  quantity  of  land  adjoining  his 
holding  which  he  may  find  bond  fide  unoccupied.  The  holding 
is  liable  to  measurement  every  five  years,  and  all  cultivated 
land  in  excess  of  the  area  originally  assessed  can  be  assessed  at 
the  same  rate.  After  thirty  years,  renewed  leases  can  be  given 
for  thirty  years'  periods,  and  rates  of  assessment  can  be  ad- 
justed at  each  renewal  with  reference  to  rates  then  prevailing 
in  the  neighbourhood.  The  tenure  is  heritable  and  transfer- 
able, provided  that  notice  of  transfer  is  given  to  the  Sundarbans 
Commissioner  within  one  month,  and  no  holding  is  to  be 
divided  without  his  permission.  No  charge  is  made  for  wood 
and  timber  on  the  grant,  nor  for  any  cut  or  burnt  in  making 
clearances,  or  used  on  the  land  ;  but  a  duty  is  levied  on  any 
exported  for  sale. 

'  These  rules  are  reported  not  to  have  worked  well,  as  when 
the  time  comes  to  grant  leases  those  who  hold  'amalnamas 
wish  to  be  recognized  as  under-tenure  holders,  of  the  class  (to 
be  described  hereafter)  called  hawaladars ;  and  they  refuse  to 
take  leases  as  raiyats.  It  has  been  decided,  therefore,  to  grant 
hawaladari  rights.' 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEAET   SETTLEMENTS. 


483 


§  3.    Statistics  of  Occupation. 

It  may  be  interesting  to  give  a  few  statistics  of  the 
occupation  of  land  in  these  delta  forests. 

The  result  of  the  recognition  of  squatters  under  the 
early  law  of  1819,  was  that  in  1874  there  were  98  holdings 
recognized  as  estates  permanently-settled,  and  amounting 
to  255,849  bighas  in  the  '  24-Pergunnahs '  district,  93,695 
in  Khulna",  and  134,709  in  Bakirganj.  There  were  also 
a  number  of  '  resumed '  plots  and  other  estates  kept  in  the 
hands  of  Government l. 

As  to  the  lands  sold  or  leased  under  the  Rules,  as  they 
now  survive,  the  Board's  Revenue  Report  of  1888-9  gives 
the  following  figures. 

It  will  be  seen  that  a  certain  number  of  persons  are  con- 
tent to  hold  under  the  ordinary  Temporary  Settlement  and 
not  under  the  special  rules. 


Kind  of  Estate. 

Number 
of  leases. 

Acres. 

Bevenue  payable. 

Rupees. 

Under  ordinary  Settle- 
ments. 

1- 

46,238 

515,240  (will  eventually 
rise  to  16,782). 

Capitalists'  rules  of  1879 

21 

28,590 

—  20,641. 

Petty  cultivators'  rules  .  . 

129 

3-375 

2,216  —  10,049. 

§  4.    Waste  Lands  in  other  parts. 

The  Waste  Land  Rules  have  found  application  (besides 
the  Sundarbans)  chiefly  in  Jalpaiguri  and  Darj  fling  (hill 
estates  for  tea),  and  in  Chittagong :  a  few  leases  have  been 
granted  in  Lohardagga. 

1  Among  them  the  Tushkhali  Es-  of  Government  in  1836.  It  was 
tate  of  22,754  acres  in  the  Bakirganj  settled  as  a  '  raiyatwari  tract'  in 
district,  which  became  the  property  1875. 

I  i  2 


484  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

The  following  account  of  the  Rules  is  once  more  quoted 
from  the  Report  on  the  Land  System,  1882-83  : — 

'  Lord  Canning's  Minute  of  the  i  yth  October,  186 1,  laid  down 
three  main  principles  on  which  grants  of  waste  lands  were  to 
be  made  in  future.  These  were,  first,  that  "in  any  case  of 
application  for  such  lands  they  shall  be  granted  in  perpetuity 
as  a  heritable  and  transferable  property,  subject  to  no  enhance- 
ment of  land-revenue  assessment"  ;  second,  that  "all  prospective 
land-revenue  will  be  redeemable  at  the  grantee's  option  by 
a  payment  in  full  when  the  grant  is  made,  or,  at  the  grantee's 
option,  a  sum  may  be  paid  as  earnest  at  the  rate  of  10  per 
cent.,  leaving  the  unpaid  portion  of  the  price  of  the  grant, 
which  will  then  be  under  hypothecation  until  the  price  is  paid 
in  full"  ;  and,  third,  that  "there  shall  be  no  condition  obliging 
the  grantee  to  cultivate  or  clear  any  specific  portion  after  grant 
within  any  specific  time."  The  minimum  price  for  the  fee- 
simple  was  fixed  at  R.  2-8  per  acre,  so  that  by  paying  10  per 
cent,  of  this,  or  four  annas  per  acre,  a  title  was  obtained. 
Moreover,  many  large  tracts  were  obtained  by  speculators  in 
anticipation  of  measurement,  for  a  merely  nominal  payment. 
A  despatch  from  the  Secretary  of  State  subsequently  required 
in  addition  to  these  provisions  that  grants  should  be  surveyed 
before  sale,  and  that  all  sales  should  be  by  auction  to  the 
highest  bidders  above  a  fixed  upset  price. 

'  In  granting  waste  lands  under  the  above  rules,  some  abuses 
were  unfortunately  allowed  to  occur.  There  was  a  great  rush 
upon  tea-planting  ;  speculators  bought  upon  credit  Government 
wastes  wherever  they  could  get  them,  and  Government  officers 
were  so  far  carried  away  by  the  mania,  that  they  relaxed  the 
rules  as  to  surveying  wastes  before  they  were  sold,  and  in 
other  particulars.  It  followed  that  large  areas  of  waste  were 
sold  to  jobbers,  who  transferred  them  at  a  profit,  or  threw 
them  up  if  they  could  not  transfer  them  ;  while  in  many  cases 
cultivated  lands  not  regularly  settled  were  sold  as  "  Govern- 
ment waste  lands  "  over  the  heads  of  the  occupiers.  In  other 
cases,  lands  beyond  the  British  border,  in  others  again  valuable 
forest  lands,  were  sold  under  the  Waste  Land  Eules.  Before 
Sir  George  Campbell  came  to  Bengal,  attention  had  been 
directed  to  this  matter,  and,  in  Chittagong  especially,  mistakes 
had  been  recognized.  There  had  in  more  than  one  instance 
been  risk  of  grave  disturbance  with  frontier  tribes  on  account 


CHAP,  ii.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  485 

of  ill-judged  sales  of  waste  land  in  the  occupation  of  border 
people.  To  prevent  complications,  the  Lieutenant-Governor 
published  ad  interim  rules,  which  received  sanction ;  and  orders 
were  passed  that  no  more  land  should  be  sold  revenue-free  in 
perpetuity  without  the  previous  sanction  of  the  Government  of 
India,  excepting  such  small  plots,  not  exceeding  ten  acres  in 
extent,  as  might  be  required  for  buildings  or  gardens. 

'In  1874,  revised  rules  for  the  sale  of  waste  lands,  super- 
seding all  previous  rules  for  the  sale  and  lease  of  waste  lands 
within  the  Lower  Provinces,  were  issued.  The  formation  of 
the  Chief  Commissionership  of  Assam  had,  by  that  time,  with- 
drawn the  districts  in  which  the  chief  transactions  in  waste 
lands  used  to  occur,  from  the  control  of  the  Bengal  Govern- 
ment ;  and,  in  the  districts  left  to  the  Lower  Provinces  in 
which  there  are  waste  lands,  these  sale  rules  remained  in- 
operative, the  terms  having  failed  to  attract  applicants  ;  and 
eventually,  in  May  1879,  the  sale  rules  were  withdrawn,  and 
the  only  rules  now  in  force  in  Bengal  are  those  under  which 
waste  lands  are  leased  for  certain  terms  of  years. 

'  Waste  lands  capable  of  being  leased  exist  in  the  Sundarbans, 
the  Western  Dwars  of  Jalpaiguri,  Darjiling,  Chittagong,  the 
Hill  Tracts  of  Chittagong,  in  Palamau,  in  Lohardagga,  and  to 
a  veiy  small  extent  in  Shahabad.  The  tea  lease-rules  for  the 
Dwars  of  1875  were  at  first  extended  to  Palamau,  but  were 
found  inapplicable,  and  applications  for  waste  land  there 
require  to  be  dealt  with  on  their  own  merits.  For  the  other 
districts  there  are  different  sets  of  rules.  It  may  be  here 
observed  that  one  feature  in  the  Sundarbans  and  Chittagong  is 
that  the  leases  are  sold  by  auction. 

'  There  are  two  classes  of  lease-rules — 

'  (i)  Those  for  large  capitalists  wishing  to  grow  special  crops, 
as  tea,  coffee,  or  cinchona. 

'  (2)  Those  for  small  capitalists  for  ordinary  cultivation.' 

§  5.    Rules  in  Darjiling  and  Jalpaiguri. 

'  The  main  features  of  the  rules  of  the  first  class,  as  appli- 
cable to  Jalpaiguri  and  Darjiling,  published  on  loth  October, 
1878,  are  the  following  : — 

'Declared  forest-reserves  and  land  having  valuable  timber 
in  compact  blocks,  lands  in  which  other  rights  exist,  lands 


486  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

lying  within  sixty  feet  from  the  centre  of  any  public  road,  and 
lands  expressly  exempted  by  Government,  are  not  to  be 
granted.  Each  lot  must  be  compact,  and  not  contain  more 
than  800  acres.  Inquiry  and  survey  at  the  expense  of  the 
applicant  must  ordinarily  precede  the  grant  of  a  lease.  A 
preliminary  five  years'  lease  is  granted  rent-free  for  the  first 
year,  and  at  progressive  rents  for  the  rest  of  the  term.  The 
rights  conveyed  are  heritable  and  transferable,  provided  that 
the  whole  lot  is  transferred,  that  clearance  conditions  are 
observed,  that  the  transfer  is  registered,  and  a  registration  fee 
paid.  The  right  of  Government  to  minerals  and  quarries,  and 
to  payment  for  valuable  trees  on  the  grant,  and  the  right  of 
the  public  to  fisheries,  and  a  right  of  way  along  the  banks  of 
navigable  streams,  are  reserved,  while  provision  is  made  for 
the  construction  and  maintenance  of  proper  boundary-marks, 
the  presence  of  the  lessee  himself  or  of  a  resident  manager  on 
the  grant,  and  for  acquisition  by  Government  of  any  land 
required  for  public  purposes  free  of  cost,  except  by  propor- 
tionate reduction  in  the  rent  and  by  the  payment  of  the  value 
of  any  improvements  in  the  land  taken  up.  If,  after  inspection 
during  the  term  of  the  preliminary  lease,  1 5  per  cent,  of  the 
total  area  shall  have  been  brought  under  cultivation  and 
actually  bears  tea-plants,  the  lessee  is  entitled  to  renewal  for  a 
term  of  years,  and  to  similar  renewals  in  perpetuity,  provided 
that  Government  may  fix  the  rent  on  certain  specified  con- 
ditions on  each  renewal ;  that  the  renewed  lease  be  heritable 
and  transferable  in  so  far  that  only  the  whole  may  be  trans- 
ferred, and  that  only  with  the  consent  of  Government ;  and 
that  all  the  other  conditions  of  the  preliminary  lease  hold  good. 
Failure  to  comply  with  any  of  the  conditions  renders  the  lessee 
liable  to  forfeit  his  lease ;  and  failure  to  apply  for  a  renewal 
before  the  expiration  of  his  preliminary  lease  reduces  him,  if  he 
is  allowed  to  continue,  to  the  status  of  a  tenant-at-will  till  other 
arrangements  are  made.  Grantees  can  club  or  amalgamate 
their  grants  by  transfers,  duly  registered,  on  payment  of  the 
prescribed  fee. 

'  The  second  class  of  rules  for  small  capitalists,  as  applicable 
to  the  Dwars,  published  on  the  23rd  June,  1879,  correspond  in 
the  main  with  the  rules  for  the  grant  of  leases  for  tea-cultiva- 
tion. The  differences  are  briefly  these  :  Ordinarily  the  lot 
must  not  be  less  than  ten  acres  or  contain  more  than  200 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  48.7 

acres  \  The  survey  fee  is  to  be  three  annas  an  acre,  and  no 
further  sum  will  be  demanded  nor  any  refund  made,  while  in 
the  case  of  tea-leases  the  fee  is  fixed  at  one  rupee  an  acre  and 
the  applicant  is  entitled  to  a  refund  of  any  surplus,  or,  if  the 
expenses  exceed  the  deposit,  has  to  make  good  the  deficiency. 
Renewal  of  the  preliminary  lease  is  conditional  on  one  half 
of  the  total  area  held  being  occupied  by  homesteads,  or  cul- 
tivated or  left  fallow,  according  to  good  husbandry,  or  other- 
wise fairly  turned  to  account  for  agricultural  purposes.  The 
periods  of  renewals  are  to  be  conterminous  with  the  period  of 
Settlement  of  the  district,  current  at  the  time  of  renewal. 
Sub-infeudation  in  the  first  degree  only  is  allowable2.  The 
sub-tenant  is,  however,  to  have  from  the  lessee  the  same  pro- 
mise of  renewal  as  the  lessee  himself  has  from  Government, 
and  the  sub-tenant's  rent  is  to  be  determined  by  the  Deputy 
Commissioner.  Kates  of  rent  on  renewal  of  lease  have  been 
fixed  both  in  the  case  of  tea-leases  and  of  leases  of  arable  lands. 
Where  half  the  area  of  the  grant  of  the  arable  land  has  not  been 
brought  under  cultivation,  the  renewed  lease  shall  ordinarily 
include  an  area  of  waste  land  equal  to  the  extent  of  land 
brought  under  cultivation  during  the  currency  of  the  pre- 
liminary lease,  but  in  such  cases  the  Deputy  Commissioner 
has  the  power,  under  certain  restrictions,  of  refusing  renewal 
altogether,  or  of  allowing  it  on  special  conditions.  Each 
description  of  land — tea,  bastoo,  rupit,  &c. — is  charged  at  the 
rate  fixed  in  the  pergunnah  wherein  it  is  situated.  In  the 
case  of  tea-leases  in  the  hills  of  the  Darji'ling  district,  an  all- 
round  rate  of  one  rupee  an  acre  will  be  imposed  on  renewal  of 
the  lease,  subsequent  to  the  expiration  of  the  preliminary  lease. 

'  For  small  capitalists  it  has  been  decided  that  no  rules  are 
necessary  for  Darjiling. 

'  In  consequence  of  re-adjustment  of  the  boundary  between 
Darjiling  and  Jalpaiguri,  the  issue  of  orders  which  have  in- 
directly affected  the  rules,  and  the  grant  of  certain  concessions 
on  the  part  of  Government, — such  as  extending  the  term  for 
renewed  leases,  reducing  the  fee  to  be  charged  on  transfers, 

1  Grants  under  these  rules   are  there  seems  to  be  no  reason  for  such 

heritable,     but     not     transferable  a  restriction. 

during    the    term    of   preliminary  2  The  grantee  may  farm  out  his 

lease.     It  has  been  the  local  custom  rights  of  management,  &c.,  to  one 

not  to  allow  tea  to  be  cultivated  on  person,    but  that  person  may   not 

land  leased  under  these  rules  ;  but  create  a  farm  of  a  farm. 


488  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

and  permitting  partial  transfers. — the  tea-lease  rules  of  1878 
are  under  revision  ;  and  it  is  at  the  same  time  proposed  to 
revise  the  Dwar  arable  land-lease  rules  of  1875.' 

§  6.    The  Ch'dtagong  Districts. 

'  A  set  of  rules  for  the  grant  of  leases  for  tea  cultivation  in 
the  Chittagong  Hill  Tracts,  based  on  the  tea-lease  rules  for 
Jalpaigiiri  and  Darjfling,  was  published  by  Government  on  the 
3oth  June,  1879.  No  charge  is  made  for  trees  on  tea  grants, 
though  the  right  to  levy  tolls  on  forest  produce  exported  either 
by  land  or  water  is  reserved. 

'  There  are  no  rules  for  leases  to  large  capitalists  in  this  dis- 
trict. Government  are  averse  to  granting  waste  lands  in 
Chittagong  proper  for  any  other  purpose  than  ordinary  native 
cultivation.  Here  and  there  may  be  large  tracts  of  waste  land 
better  fitted  for  the  cultivation  of  tea  than  for  anything  else, 
and  a  special  grant  may  be  made  of  such  blocks,  if  necessary, 
on  special  terms. 

'  For  small  capitalists,  the  waste  lands  are  broken  up  into 
compact  blocks  of  fifty  acres  each,  and  the  lease  of  each  lot 
sold  by  public  competition.  There  is  no  restriction  as  to  the 
kind  of  crops  that  may  be  grown. 

'  The  whole  of  the  waste  lands  are  not  thrown  open  at  once 
for  sale,  but  the  leases  of  the  surplus  waste-land  blocks  in  one 
village  at  a  time  are  put  up  to  auction  on  a  given  day  on  the 
established  terms. 

'The  leases  are  heritable  and  transferable.  The  rates  are 
fixed  with  reference  to  the  quality  of  the  land.  A  measure- 
ment and  assessment  after  ten  years,  and  another  after  fifteen 
years,  is  provided  for ;  and  in  the  case  of  lands  exposed  to  salt- 
water inundation,  and  requiring  the  protection  of  embank- 
ments, a  larger  area  than  fifty  acres,  up  to  a  maximum  of 
200  for  a  single  applicant,  or  fifty  acres  each  to  several  appli- 
cants jointly,  may  be  granted.  The  other  provisions  generally 
follow  the  rules  for  the  grant  of  tea-leases  in  Jalpaiguri  and 
Darjiling.' 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  489 


SECTION  V. — THE  REVENUE-SYSTEM  OF  CHITTAGONG  *. 

Chittagong  is  one  of  the  eastern  districts  of  Bengal 
between  the  sea-coast  and  the  hills  which  separate  Bengal 
from  Burma.  The  soil  is  rich,  but  in  1793  a  large  portion 
was,  as  might  be  expected,  still  covered  with  luxuriant 
and  tangled  jungle,  the  clearance  being  chiefly  in  the 
level  plains  suited  for  rice-lands.  There  had  been  no 
natural  opportunity,  save  in  exceptional  cases,  for  the 
growth  of  large  Zamindarf  estates.  The  different  settlers 
formed  groups  or  companies,  and  each  cleared  one  plot 
here  and  one  there.  The  leader  of  the  company  was 
required  to  be  the  collector  of  the  revenue  from  as  many 
of  the  settlers  as  chose  to  pay  through  him,  and  therefore 
came  to  be  looked  on  as  the  superior  owner  of  the  whole 
of  the  scattered  group  of  holdings  which  paid  through 
him.  The  group  was  called  a  '  taraf,'  and  the  person  who 
was  at  the  head  (or  his  descendant)  was  called  '  tarafdar.' 
It  also  happened  that  settlers  were  called  on  by  the 
Muhammadan  conqueror  for  help  and  feudal  service,  and 

1  Properly  Chattagraon  or  Chat-  to  the  chiefs,  and  the  latter  pay  the 

tagram.  '  tribute '  or  quit-rent  (or  whatever 

The  text  refers  to  the  regular  dis-  it  is  proper  to  call  it)  above  alluded 

trict  and  not  to  the  hilly  portion  to. 

known     as     the     Chittagong    Hill  The  cultivation  is  still  chiefly  of 

Tracts.     In  these  the  only  revenue  the  temporary  kind  called  '  jum,'  so 

is    a    tribute    paid   by   the    chiefs.  natural  to  all  semi-barbarous  people 

Formerly  it    was    taken    in    kind  in  tropical  hill  countries,  and   an 

(cotton),  according  to  the   popula-  attempt  has  been  lately  made  to  re- 

tion  ;  this  was  afterwards  converted  cord    in    a    simple   way    (so   as  to 

into  a  money  payment.     This   re-  gradually  get  them  fixed)  the  rights 

venue  was  consequently  shown  in  and  interests  of  the  different  clans 

the  old   accounts   as  derived  from  or  tribes  and  their  chiefs  and  head- 

the  '  kapas  mahal/  and  became  fixed  men.     The  record  is  called  the  'jum 

by  custom.  book.' 

By  Act  XXII  of  1860  the  Hill  dis-  There   are  a   certain   number   of 

trict  (as  defined  in  a  schedule  to  the  estates   in   which    lands    are    per- 

Act)  was  removed  from  the  opera-  manently  cultivated,  and  these  may 

tion  of  the  General  Regulations  and  be   under  a  Settlement  under  the 

put  under  a  Deputy  Commissioner.  ordinary  law.     A  portion  of  the  dis- 

Simple  rules  regarding  judicial  pro-  trict   called   the   '  khas    mahal '    is 

cedure  have  been  drawn  up  under  reserved  from  the  jurisdiction  of  the 

the  Act,  and  no  revenue  Settlement  chiefs,  for  the  purpose  of  making 

has  been  made.    But  there  is  a  capi-  land  grants  to  settlers.     There  are 

tation  tax  payable  by  householders  also  State  forests  in  this  tract. 


490  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

were  then  recognized  as  jagir-grantees  of  their  land,  holding 
it  by  stated  area.  So  also  '  tarafs '  were  founded  by  the 
military  force  sent  to  defend  the  province,  and  these  tarafs 
were  also  held  in  jagir  in  lieu  of  pay.  The  consequence 
was,  as  early  as  1 764,  all  the  occupied  lands  (which  alone 
came  under  Settlement)  having  been  granted  by  area, 
had  been  actually  measured *.  The  Permanent  Settlement 
then  extended  only  to  the  measured  lands  as  they  stood  in 
1764. 

All  land  cultivated  subsequent  to  that,  is  locally  spoken 
of  as  'noabad'  (nauabad =  newly  cultivated).  And  the 
ways  in  which  this  nauabad  came  to  be  cultivated  were 
various.  Under  Regulation  III  of  1828,  such  cultivators 
would  have  no  title  whatever;  but  this  was  not  at  first 
looked  to  :  assessment  was  the  main  object. 

In  the  first  place  the  'tarafdars'  began  to  encroach  on 
the  waste  all  round,  and  extend  all  their  cultivation  without 
authority.  This  led  to  repeated  re-measurements  on  the 
part  of  the  authorities,  and  to  a  great  deal  of  oppression 
and  bribery,  owing  to  the  action  of  informers  and  others 
who  threatened  to  expose  the  encroachments,  if  not  paid  to 
keep  silence.  A  great  number  of  other  persons,  mere 
squatters,  also  cultivated  lands. 

§  i.    The  Noabad  Taluqs. 

All  the  '  nauabad '  lands  could  claim  nothing  but  a 
temporary  Settlement.  It  happened,  however,  that  one 
of  the  old  estate-holders  laid  claim  by  virtue  of  a  sanad, 
which  afterwards  proved  to  be  forged,  to  have  had  all  the 
waste  in  the  district  granted  to  him  in  1797.  An  immense 
correspondence,  ending  in  a  lawsuit,  followed,  and  lasted 
for  nearly  forty  years  2.  The  result  was  that  Government 

1  See   Chapter  III   (on  Tenures)  whole,  without  discriminating  those 
for  some  further   remarks   on  the  lands  to  which  he  had  a  just  title, 
'  taraf.'     See   also   Cotton's  Memor-  from  those  fraudulently   obtained. 
andum  on  Revenue   Administration   of  The  Sudder  Court  decreed   in   his 
Chittagong  (1880),  pp.  7,  8,  10.  favour  for  the   original  estate,   but 

2  When  the  fraud  was  discovered,  gave  Government  the  rest.     (Mac- 
Government  dispossessed  him  of  the  neile's  Memorandum,  Chapter  IV.) 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPOEARY    SETTLEMENTS.  49 1 

recovered  its  right,  but  had  to  allow  the  Zammdar  so 
much  land  as  really  belonged  to  his  original  estate.  This 
could  not  be  found  out  without  a  survey,  and  the  oppor- 
tunity was  taken  to  survey  the  whole  district,  with  a  view 
to  the  proper  separation  of  the  old  permanently-settled 
lands  of  1764  from  the  nauabad  lands.  The  process  took 
seven  years  to  complete  (from  1841-1848),  and  the  Settle- 
ment was  made  by  Sir  H.  Ricketts.  All  the  'nauabad' 
lands  were  surveyed,  whether  held  by  squatters  or  taken 
as  encroachments  by  the  original  tarafdars  ;  but  each  plot 
separately  occupied  was,  as  a  rule,  formed  into  a  separate 
'taluq,'  though  some  few  were  aggregated:  32,258  little 
estates  were  thus  formed,  ca-lled  in  revenue  language,  the 
'  noabad  taluqs.'  A  small  number  (861)  of  these,  that  paid 
R-5o  revenue  and  upwards,  were  placed  directly  under 
the  Collector,  and  the  host  of  smaller  ones  were  grouped 
into  196  blocks,  each  of  which  was  at  first  given  out  to 
a  '  circle  farmer '  who  was  to  be  responsible  for  collecting 
the  revenue.  The  system  was  afterwards  abandoned  in 
favour  of  khas  management  by  the  aid  of  local  revenue 
officers,  on  the  analogy  of  a  raiyatwdri  management. 

Nor  was  this  the  only  trouble  in  Chittagong.  The 
invalid  revenue-free  grants,  to  which  I  have  already  alluded 
as  liable  to  resumption  and  assessment,  were  peculiarly 
numerous  and  intricate  ;  even  after  relinquishing  all  cases 
in  which  the  holding  did  not  exceed  10  bighas,  there  were 
still  36,683  petty  estates  of  this  class  separately  to  be 
settled.  Many  of  these  had  to  be  permanently  settled 
under  the  law  alluded  to  previously  (see  page  427). 

There  were  also  a  large  number  of  small  grants  or  leases 
made  by  the  revenue  authorities  under  the  designation  of 
clearing  or  'jangalburi '  leases l. 

Thus  the  Chittagong  district  consists  of  a  mosaic  of 
petty  estates  ;  here  a  plot  of  old  permanently-settled  land, 
next  a  jangalburi  plot,  then  a  recovered  and  assessed  en- 
croachment, next  a  resumed  lakhiraj  holding,  and  so  forth. 

1  There  were  1290  of  them,  of  twenty-five  years,  gave  only  R.  2,475 
which  1002,  settled  originally  for  revenue  between  them. 


492 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


The  table  already  given  will  show  how  the  estates  are 
now  grouped  under  the  head  of  'permanently  settled,' 
'  temporarily  settled,'  and  Government  estates  *. 

The  work  of  revenue  collection  in  the  petty  estates  will 
now  be  facilitated,  inasmuch  as  recent  orders  have  resulted 
in  the  issue  of  a  proclamation  2  notifying  that,  for  the  term 
of  one  year,  petty  estates  permanently  settled  and  paying 
less  than  one  rupee  per  annum  may  be  redeemed  on  a 
payment  of  ten  times  the  annual  jama'. 

The  question  of  how  to  deal  with  the  nauabad  lands 
or  taluqs,  was  for  a  long  time  in  suspense.  At  one  time 
a  Permanent  Settlement  was  offered,  but  on  such  terms 
that  but  few  accepted  it.  It  was  then  determined,  generally, 
that  the  nauabad  taluqdar  was  a  tenure-holder  on  an  estate 
belonging  to  Government.  The  Settlement  of  1848  was 
made  for  fifty  years  in  the  case  of  taluqs  which  had  their 
cultivation  fairly  fully  developed,  and  for  twenty-five  years 
in  jangalbiiri-taluqs,  where  much  land  was  still  waste.  In 
1875-76,  the  re-settlement  of  these  latter  began,  and  the 
measurements  are  now  complete.  A  question  then  arose 
as  to  whether  some  of  these  taluqs  (and  some  resumed 
revenue-free  taluqs)  were  legally  liable  to  re-settlement 
at  all.  An  order  also  had  been  obtained  that  4913  tarafs 
of  the  Government  estate  were  not  liable  to  re-settlement. 
In  respect  of  all  these,  it  has  ultimately  been  determined 
that  they  are  liable:  but  it  was  agreed  not  to  re-settle 
the  4913  estates  till  the  fifty  years'  leases  fell  in  in 


ment  purposes  they  are  grouped  into 
five  circles,  each  circle  being  called 
an  estate,  and  bearing  a  name  as  the 
Town  khas  Mahal,  the  Ranjan  Ma- 
hal, &c.,  &c.  (Report,  1883,  p.  29.) 
a  Revenue  Report,  1887-88,  Section 

55- 

J  Revenue  Report  for  1885  86,  Sec- 
tion 114. 


1  In  the  Revenue  Report  (1888-9) 
the  map  of  Chittagong  shows  how 
the  Government  and  private  estates 
are  intermingled,  and  the  '  Settle- 
ment '  map  appended  to  this  volume 
endeavours  to  show  (though  only 
roughly)  the  same  condition.  The 
real  number  of  the  Government  es- 
tates is  about  45,000,  but  for  manage- 


CHAP, ii.j  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  493 


SECTION  VI. — THE  CHUTIYA  NAGPUR  DISTRICTS. 

We  shall  have  more  to  say  about  these  districts  under 
the  head  of  Tenures,  because  it  is  in  them  that  we  have 
certain  relics  of  one  of  the  original  village-systems, — that 
of  the  Kols  and  kindred  tribes,  Hos,  Mundas,  and  also  of 
the  southern  or  Dravidian  Uraons. 

Here,  however,  we  are  concerned  with  the  Revenue 
Settlements. 

A  portion  of  each  of  the  present  districts  that  was 
formerly  attached  to  the  old  Collectorates  of  that  date, 
came  under  the  Permanent  Settlement. 

§  i.    Mdnbhtuum. 

Nearly  all  Mdnlhum  is  permanently  settled  by  treating 
as  '  Zamindar '  (with  a  fixed  revenue)  the  chiefs  over 
parhds  or  groups  of  villages,  which  the  old  native  tribal 
organization  originated.  There  are  but  two  temporarily- 
settled  estates  in  the  district. 

§  2.    Singhbkum. 

The  northern  portion  consists  of  the  permanently-  settled 
pargana  of  Dhalbhum  formerly  attached  to  Midnapore,  and 
of  two  chiefs'  estates  (Sarai-kalan  and  Kharsawan)  under 
political  control,  and  one  estate  permanently  settled  and 
two  temporarily  settled  in  the  subdivision  of  Dhalbhum. 

The  rest  of  the  district  consists  'of  the  tract  called 
Kolhan  *  (1905  square  miles)  occupying  the  whole  south- 
west portion  of  the  district,  and  forming  a  '  raiyatwari 
tract '  and  the  confiscated  estate  of  Parahat  *. 

In  both  these  districts  and  in  Manbhum,  lands  are  never 
sold  for  arrears  of  revenue  ;  and  all  sales  and  mortgages  of 
land  require  the  sanction  of  the  Commissioner. 

1  Kolhan  is  sometimes  called  Ho-       (or  Porahat)  estate  in  Government  of 
desam — the  settlement  of  Hos.  India  (Itev.  and  Agr.)  Proceedings  for 

2  There  is  a  history  of  the  Parahat      February,  1889. 


494  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

§  3.    Hazdribdgh. 

Here  there  are  four  principal  subdivisions  according  to 
the  different  Settlement  arrangements  : — 

(a)  Rdmgarh  was  originally  a  single  estate ;  but  it 
has  since  been  split  up  into  four  separate  estates, 
one  being  the  Government  estate  occupied  by 
cantonments,  &c.,  around  Hazaribagh,  called  (the 
'  Government  enclosure  '  or)  '  Sirkari-hata ' ;  the 
second  being  the.Zamindarf  of  Kodarma,  confis- 
cated in  1841,  and  now  a  Government  estate,  the 
third  the  remaining  part  of  the  Zamindari  of 
Ramgarh ;  the  fourth  the  Kendua  estate,  —  a 
Government  '  tauflr '  estate  made  up  of  resumed 
surplus  lands  and  farmed  for  twenty  years. 

(6)  The  Kunda  pargana  and  estate. 

(c)  The   Kharakdiha    estates,   one   of    which   is   per- 

manently settled,  one  is  revenue-free,  and  others 
are  Government  estates. 

(d)  The  Kendi  pargana,  which  is  permanently  settled. 
The  whole  district  is  composed  of  68  permanently-settled 

and  1 86  Government  estates. 

§  4.    Lohdrdagga. 

The  Palamau  subdivision,  occupying  the  north-western 
portion  of  the  district,  is  a  'Government  estate  or  'khas 
mahal '  shown  partly  as  '  Government  estate '  and  partly  as 
'  raiyatwari  tract.'  It  contains  some  good  State  forests. 
The  rest  of  the  district  is  settled  with  the  Maharaja  of 
Chutiya  Ndgpur  as  a  sort  of  permanently-settled  estate, 
but  it  is  looked  upon  rather  as  a  tribute-paying  chiefship, 
and  has  never  been  held  liable  to  sale  for  arrears  of 
revenue. 

§  5.    General  Remarks. 

In  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  districts  there  are  some  curious 
subordinate  tenures,  provision  for  the  record  and  declar- 


CHAP.  II.]  THE    TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  495 

ation  of  which  has  been  made  in  the  Bengal  Act  II  of  1869. 
These  tenures  will  be  dealt  with  in  the  chapter  devoted  to 
the  subject  of  tenures. 

But  as  regards  Settlement  arrangements,  it  must  here  be 
mentioned  that  the  Act  contemplated  the  appointment  of 
one  or  more  special  Commissioners,  who  were  to  have 
exclusive  jurisdiction  to  try  and  determine  all  disputes 
regarding  tenures  in  the  estates,  and  to  make  a  record 
(which  was  final  and  authoritative),  regarding  the  right 
to  the  different  lands  and  the  privileges  attaching  to  each. 
The  fact  that  a  chief  had  been  recognized  as  Zamindar, 
or  that  the  Government  was  the  superior  owner,  did  not 
prevent  this. 

The  tenures  were  based  on  the  peculiar  arrangement 
(already  alluded  to)  that  besides,  or  rather  anterior  to,  the 
plan  of  allotting  a  share  in  the  produce  to  the  chief  or 
overlord,  the  ancient  system  was  to  set  apart  certain  lands 
for  the  king  or  the  chief.  Thus  in  every  village  these 
lands  were  called  (majhhas)  and  in  later  times  became 
the  Settlement-holding  proprietor's  lands,  whoever  he 
might  be — a  descendant  of  the  chief,  a  purchaser,  or  a 
person  with  a  merely  prescriptive  title.  Certain  other 
lands  were,  on  the  same  principle,  allotted  to  the  original 
founders  of  the  village  who  held  the  office  of  headmen, 
&c.,  others  to  the  priest  for  himself  and  for  the  worship 
of  various  deities ;  others  were  taken  by  the  mahto,  or 
collector,  who  was  (at  a  later  period)  put  in  by  the  chief 
to  look  after  his  interests ;  others,  again  (called  bet-kheta) 
were  assigned,  in  lieu  of  wages,  to  the  labourers  who 
cultivated  the  once  royal  or  majhhas  lands. 

Such  a  system,  in  later  days,  gave  rise  to  great  facilities 
for  wrong-doing.  The  more  powerful  would  annex  lands 
and  drive  out  the  feebler.  The  object  of  the  special  record 
was  to  restore  the  rightful  holders  (who  had  had  possession 
within  a  reasonable  limit  fixed  by  the  Act),  and  to  secure, 
by  record,  these  rights  with  the  privileges  attaching  thereto, 
in  the  majhhas  lands  and  in  lands  in  which  rights  of  the 
original  founders  (bhuinhar)  existed. 


49$  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  VII. — SANTAL  PERGUNNAHS  l. 

A  glance  at  the  map  shows  this  district  to  consist  of 
a  central  hilly  portion  which  begins  in  the  north  and 
extends  downwards ;  this  is  the  Government  estate,  or 
'  Daman-i-Koh ' :  below  this,  on  either  side,  and  at  the 
south,  is  plain  country  which  was  permanently  settled. 

Regulation  III  of  1872  applies  to  the  whole  district,  and 
gives  certain  rules  for  the  fixing  of  the  cultivators'  rents ; 
so  that  in  fact  the  Permanent  Settlement  only  affects  the 
right  in  the  soil  and  the  fixity  of  the  Government  assess- 
ment on  the  landlords. 

The  Santal  Parganas  were  first  removed  from  the  oper- 
ation of  the  ordinary  law  by  Act  XXXVII  of  1855^  which 
provided  for  a  special  superintendence.  And  this  Act  has 
been  continued  and  amplified  by  the  "Regulation  III  of 
1873  which  declares  the  laws  in  force.  It  is  important 
to  remember  that  Act  XXXVII  declares  that  no  Act  of 
the  Legislature,  either  past  or  future,  shall  apply  to  the 
Santal  Parganas  unless  they  are  expressly  named  in  the 
Act.  This  is  why  the  Forest  Act  of  1878  does  not  apply, 
nor  has  it  yet  been  extended  under  the  Regulation  of  1872. 
The  old  Forest  Act  of  1865  was  specially  extended,  and 
consequently  still  remains  in  force,  but  will  probably  be 
repealed. 

Part  of  the  plain  or  old-settled  tract,  is  regularly  culti- 
vated, but  part  of  it  is  hilly  and  still  much  covered  with 
jungle.  This  portion  is  largely  peopled  and  cultivated  by 
Santal  immigrants.  These  brought  their  village  institutions 
with  them  and  settled,  each  village  paying  rent  to  the 
existing  Zamindar  landlord.  Practically,  all  the  village 
tenures  are  permanent  and  alienable — subject  only  to  the 
superior  landlord's  rent.  As  a  rule,  the  landlord  gets  his 
rent,  not  direct  from  the  raiyats,  but  through  a  village 

1  The  limits  of  this  district  are  2  The   schedule  to   this  Act  has 

described  in  a  schedule  annexed  to      been  replaced  by  the  revised  schedule 
Act  X  of  1857.  in  Act  X  of  1857. 


CHAP.  H.]  THE    TEMPORABY    SETTLEMENTS.  497 

headman ;  so  that  in  fact  the  Zamfndar  is  really  more 
like  a  pensioner  drawing  a  rent  from  the  land,  but  not,  as 
a  rule  (for  there  are  some  lands  under  his  direct  manage- 
ment), interfering  in  the  cultivation  or  management  of  the 
villages. 

§  i.    The  Ddman-i-Koh. 

As  early  as  1780  A.D.  the  tract  known  as  the  Daman-i- 
Koh  was  withdrawn,  by  an  act  of  State,  from  the  general 
Settlement,  and  was  made  a  separate  '  Government  estate  V 
This,  however,  practically  meant  that  the  Government  took 
the  tribes  under  its  own  immediate  management  and  did 
not  recognize  any  Zamindar,  or  intermediate  landlord,  as 
having  any  hold  over  this  wild  region. 

The  Santals  are  not  the  original  inhabitants  of  this  tract, 
but  two  or  three  Kolarian  tribes,  now  indiscriminately 
known  as  '  Paharias.'  The  Paharias  cultivate  chiefly  by 
'jum,'  or  shifting  cultivation,  already  described.  At  first 
there  was  no  Settlement ;  or  rather  the  usual  order  of 
Settlement  was  reversed ;  the  people  did  not  pay  anything 
to  Government,  but  the  Government  paid  them  an  annual 
grant  to  support  their  headmen  and  tribal  officers.  These 
officers  seem  to  be  the  relics  of  the  old  days  when  the  hills 
were  nominally  within  the  adjacent  Zamindari  estates, 
There  were  local  divisions  of  the  separated  tract,  described 
by  the  imported  term  '  pargana.'  Over  such  a  division 
there  was  a  '  sardar/  with  his  '  naib '  or  deputy ;  while 
the  headman  over  a  village  was  the  '  manjhi.'  The 
pargana  division  has  long  fallen  into  disuse ;  but  the 
sardars  and  others  survive,  drawing  their  pensions.  This 
is  a  relic  of  the  old  Kolarian  plan  of  village  government 
with  nothing  above  it  but  the  chief  of  a  group  of  villages. 
The  old  terms  were  lost,  and  the  present  equivalent  Persian 
names  of  office  were  adopted. 

The  Santals  then  seem  to  have  immigrated  in  consider- 

1  I  am  indebted  for  this  informa-       and  to  a  Memorandum  on  the  Santdl 
tion  to  the  kindness  of  Mr.  W.  Old-       Settlement  by  Mr.  C.  W.  Bolton,  C.S. 
ham,     the     Deputy-Commissioner, 

VOL.  I.  K  k 


498  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

able  numbers,  and  cultivated  all  the  valleys  and  lower 
slopes,  so  that  the  wandering  Paharias,  with  no  settled 
cultivation,  became  confined  to  the  hillsides ;  since  that 
time,  the  Paharia  headmen  have  begun  to  claim  specific 
properties  in  the  hill-tops  and  slopes,  which,  however, 
Government  does  not  theoretically  recognize,  it  having  all 
along  claimed  the  region  as  a  '  Government  estate.'  No 
interference  with  these  people  is,  however,  contemplated ; 
and  they  have,  of  course,  wofully  abused  and  destroyed  the 
forest.  It  has  been  long  a  question  whether  part  of  the 
forest  could  not  be  put  under  regular  conservancy;  and 
quite  recently  it  has  been  determined  to  enforce  simple 
rules  in  a  portion  of  the  area. 

§  2.    The  Settlement. 

The  Settlement  arrangements  of  the  cultivated  villages 
of  the  Santal  Parganas  are  governed  by  the  Regulation  III 
of  1872,  the  manjhi  or  headman  of  each  village  collecting 
and  paying  in  the  rents  to  Government  or  to  the  owner,  as 
the  case  may  be,  and  being  allowed  8  per  cent,  as  his 
'commission.'  The  Regulation  contemplates  the  record  of 
all  classes  of  interests  in  land  and  fixing  of  all  rents  (those 
in  Permanently-Settled  estates  not  excepted),  whether 
payable  to  a  proprietor  or  to  Government ;  these  rents  are 
to  remain  unchanged  for  at  least  seven  years. 


SECTION  VIII. — jALPAiauirf  AND  DAEJILING. 
§  i.   Jalpdigfi/rt. 

That  part  of  the  district  which  is  south-west  of  the  Tista 
river  is  all  permanently  settled,  having  been  formerly  part 
of  the  old  Rangpur  Collectorate.  The  remaining  part  of 
the  district,  north  of  the  Kuch-Bihar  (tributary)  state,  and 
extending  to  the  borders  of  the  Goalpara  district  of  Assam, 
comprises  the  Bhutan  (or  Western)  Dwars 1. 

1  In  a  notification,  No.  308,  dated      March  sth,  1881),  the  laws  in  force 
3rd  March,   1881   (Gazette  of  India       in  Jalpaiguri  and  Darjiling  (besides 


CHAP,  ii.]          THE   TEMPORARY    SETTLEMENTS.  499 

The  district  as  a  whole  is  called  a  'non-regulation' 
district,  but  the  whole  body  of  ordinary  law  is  in  force 
in  the  'regulation  portion,'  to  which  the  Permanent 
Settlement  extended. 

The  Dwars  lie  along  the  foot  of  the  hills,  and  were  taken 
from  theBhutias  in  1865.  In  1870  the  country  was  settled 
for  ten  years,  and  again  in  1880  for  ten  years  more.  The 
whole  constitutes  a  Government  estate  managed  as  a 
'raiyatwari  tract.'  The  Settlement  is  made  with  the  soil 
occupants  called  'jotdars,'  whose  tenures  are  recognized  as 
fixed  tenancies,  with  a  rent  unalterable  for  the  term  of 
Settlement.  The  '  jot '  is  saleable  for  arrears  of  revenue  l. 

In  some  of  the  '  girds '  or  parganas  (of  which  the  Dwars 
contain  nine  in  all)  the  Settlement  was  made  with  farmers 
without  proprietary  rights,  who  were  allowed  1 7  £  per  cent. 
on  the  revenue,  as  their  remuneration  and  profit.  When 
the  Settlement  is  with  the  jotdar,  the  revenue  collection  is 
made  by  '  tahsildars,'  who  are  remunerated  by  an  allowance 
of  10  per  cent,  on  the  revenue. 

§  2.    Darjiling. 

This  district  also  may  be  described  as  divided  into  several 
different  tracts : — 

(1)  In  the  north-west  corner  a  large  estate  (115 
square  miles)  has  been  granted  on  a  perpetual  rent 
to  the  Chebu  Lama. 

(2)  The  old  Darjiling  territory  ceded  by  Sikkim 
(a)2  ^  in  1835 — a  long  strip  of  138  square  miles,  extend- 
ing down  to  the  Tarai  near  Pankhabari. 

(3)  Two  strips  on  each  side  of  this,  acquired  in 
1850,  bring  the  district  up  to  the  Nepal  frontier  on 
one  side  and  to  the  Tista  river  on  the  other. 

Act  XIV  of  1874)  have  been  declared.  3rd,  1881,  the  laws  in  force  in  Dar- 

All  the  '  Regulation '  laws  apply  to  jiling  are  specified.  For  this  pur- 

the  Jalpaiguri  district  up  to  the  pose  the  district  is  divided  into 

Tista  river.  The  Western  Dwars  three  portions — (a)  the  hills  west  of 

are  separately  provided  for.  the  Tista  ;  (6)  the  Darjiling  Tarai  ; 

1  Some  further  details  will  be  (c)  the  Damsong  subdivision  (east  of 

found  in  the  chapter  on  Tenures.  the  Tista). 

3  By  the   Notification  of  March 

K  k  2 


5OO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  ir. 

(6)  The  Tarai  below  Pankhabari,  also  annexed  in  1850. 

(c)  The  Damsong  subdivision,  or  hill  portion  of  the 
Bhutia  territory  about  Dalingkot,  taken  in  1 865  (east  of  the 
Tista,  west  of  the  Jaldaha,  and  north  of  the  Western  Dwars 
in  the  Jalpaiguri  district  just  alluded  to). 

Nearly  all  the  territory  in  (a  2  and  3)  seems  to  have  been 
dealt  with  under  various  '  waste-land  rules '  and  now  to 
consist  of — 

(1)  Estates  sold  or  granted  or  commuted  into  '  fee-simple' 

or  revenue-free  holdings. 

(2)  Estates  '  leased,'  i.  e.  granted  to  persons  who  pay  re- 

venue according  to  their  lease. 

(3)  Government  estates  appropriated  to  forests,  to  station- 

sites,  military  purposes,  &c.,  and  waste  not  yet 
disposed  of. 

In  the  tract  (6)  there  were  some  lands  at  first  settled  for 
short  terms  (three  years)  with  Bengalis,  the  Settlement- 
holders  being  called  chaudharis  of  'jots '  or  groups  of 
cultivation.  The  chaudharis  were,  however,  abolished  in 
1864,  and  the  Settlement  was  made  with  the  jotdars,  or 
cultivators  of  the  jot. 

In  the  upper  Tarai  are  also  Settlements  for  short  terms, 
made  with  Mech  and  Dhimal  caste-men,  who  pay  a  certain 
rate  on  each  '  dao '  or  hoe  used  for  cultivating.  Some 
jungle-clearing  leases  for  five  years  were  also  given.  In 
1867  there  was  a  survey  and  Settlement  under  the  modern 
procedure  for  thirty  years. 

In  the  Damsong  subdivision  (c)  at  first  only  a  capitation- 
tax  was  collected ;  the  tract  will  probably  ultimately  be 
surveyed  and  brought  under  temporary  Settlement l. 

1  The  map  in  the  Revenue  Eeport      Lamp's  (P.  S )  estate  in  the  north  : 
colours  the  whole  district  as  '  Go-       this  is  hardly  satisfactory, 
vernment  estates  '  except  the  Chebu 


CHAPTER  III. 

THE   LAND-TENURES. 

SECTION  I. — GENERAL  REMARKS. 

THE  task  of  writing,  in  moderate  compass,  an  account  of 
the  LAND-TENURES  OF  BENGAL  is  a  difficult  one,  for  two 
reasons.  In  the  first  place,  it  is  not  easy  to  hit  upon  a 
grouping  or  classification  which  is  suitable ;  and  yet  some 
classification,  based  on  an  intelligible  principle,  is  indispens- 
able. Otherwise  the  tenures  will  only  be  presented  to  the 
reader  in  a  haphazard  catalogue.  Most  of  our  books  adopt 
this  latter  method,  with  the  result  that,  while  the  memory 
is  bewildered  over  a  string  of  names  that  often  are  not 
worth  remembering,  those  real  distinctions  and  actual 
varieties  of  land-tenure  which  are  based  on  custom  and 
on  feelings  and  ideas  about  landholding,  and  are  therefore 
worth  remembering,  are  undistinguished  and  forgotten. 
The  second  difficulty  arises  from  the  enormous  mass  of 
records  and  authorities.  But  little  attempt  has  hitherto 
been  made  to  digest  it.  The  Fifth  Report  to  the  Committee 
of  the  House  of  Commons  of  1813  is  a  great  mine  of  infor- 
mation, but  neither  classified  nor  arranged.  In  Harington's 
Analysis,  again,  is  a  formidable  collection  of  papers.  Mr. 
Phillips,  with  his  usual  industry,  has  given,  in  the  Tagore 
Lectures  (1875),  a  mass  of  information  scattered  through 
various  lectures,  but  in  a  rather  bewildering  fashion.  Dr. 
Field  has  collected  all  the  best  authorities  in  his  Land- 
holding  in  Various  Countries.  In  an  anonymous  work 
called  The  Zamtnddri  Settlement  of  Bengal*  another  vast 

1  2  vols.     Calcutta:  Brown  &  Co. ,  1879. 


502  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

mass  of  authorities,  of  very  various  value,  is  piled  up.  And 
these  are  only  the  more  accessible  of  the  references  ;  I  have 
not  mentioned  Special  Reports,  Notes,  and  Monographs, 
whose  name  is  legion. 

In  this  chapter  I  have  therefore  to  make  the  attempt  to 
present  the  student  with  a  classified  account  of  tenures,  and 
in  doing  so,  not  merely  to  re-quote  the  authorities  en  masse, 
but  to  rigidly  exclude  all  that  does  not  appear  to  be  of 
real  importance  and  weight.  This  should  enable  a  reader 
to  dispense  with  a  reference  to  bulky  and  inaccessible 
volumes,  except  in  case  he  wishes  to  make  some  special 
study  and  go  into  '  original  sources  V 

In  dealing  with  Bengal  tenures,  I  propose  to  relegate  to 
separate  sections  the  tenures  observed  in  the  SantalParganas, 
Chutiya  Nagpur,  Orissa,  and  Chittagong.  There  are  special 
historical  features  about  these  localities  which  fit  them  for 
separate  notice  ;  but  they  are  full  of  interest,  and  indeed  it 
is  in  these  places  that  we  find  survivals  which  are  of  the 
highest  importance  in  connection  with  the  early  history  of 
land-customs. 

Taking,  then,  the  districts  of  Bengal  proper  and  Bihar, 
we  shall  find  that  the  original  village  organization  has  too 
far  decayed  to  enable  us  to  start  from  it  as  a  basis  of  land- 
tenure  investigation  ;  what  traces  of  it  survive  in  headmen's 
privileges  and  grants  of  land  for  village  service,  will  now 
and  again  come  to  notice  as  we  explore  the  peculiarities  of 
the  landlord's  right,  and  the  origin  and  nature  of  the  tenures 
under  him. 

In  a  word,  in  Bengal  the  Zamindar  has  become  the  central 
figure,  and  our  study  must  start  with  him  and  with  the 
'  independent '  landholder,  jagirdar,  and  other  '  actual 
proprietor,'  whom  the  Regulations  placed  on  the  same 
footing. 

The  '  actual  proprietors,'  to  state  the  matter  in  other 
words,  may  be  great  Zamindars,  or  they  may  be  lesser 

1  The  labour  of  this  task  has  been  Memorandum  on  Land-Tenures  which 
much  lightened  by  the  excellent  Mr.  J.  S.  Cotton,  C.S.,  has  prepared. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  503 

estate-holders,  all  equally  now  raised  to  the  status  and  legal 
privileges  of  the  Regulation  proprietor. 

In  close  connection  with  proprietary  tenures  paying 
revenue,  are  the  lakhiraj  holdings  allowed  as  valid.  They 
may  be  mere  assignments  of  revenue,  but  often  include  the 
ownership  of  the  land  as  well.  Some  of  these  have  become 
landlord-estates ;  other  smaller  ones  have  remained  under 
the  proprietor,  and  therefore  fall  into  the  class  of  subordinate 
'  tenures,'  just  above  the  grade  of  '  raiyat.' 

As  we  pass  out  of  the  class  of  fully  proprietary  tenures, 
we  enter  on  a  border-land,  which  in  Bengal  is  a  most 
curious  one, — I  refer  to  the  region  of  tenures  which  we 
cannot  classify  as  proprietary,  and  are  yet  not  exactly 
tenancies. 

The  latest  attempt  of  the  legislature  to  deal  with  the 
subject  has  not  resulted  in  a  complete  definition  ;  but  it  has 
given  us  the  term  '  tenure '  for  this  class  of  rights ;  and 
we  can  describe  their  peculiarities  and  privileges,  if  we 
cannot  frame  a  definition. 

Some  of  these  tenures  practically  represent  relics  of  older 
rights  which  gave  way  beneath  the  growth  of  the  Zamin- 
ddri  right,  but  still  showed  some  traces — as  we  can  see  the 
remains  of  the  original  tree  under  its  overgrowth  of  the 
many -rooted  Ficus  in  an  Indian  forest.  And  even  where 
the  holder  of  such  right  possesses  a  document  in  the  nature 
of  a  grant  from  the  Zamindar,  or  some  other  authority,  it 
by  no  means  follows  that  the  right  really  originates  in  con- 
tract, or  in  an  act  of  pure  donation  by  the  superior.  Other 
such  tenures  (as  already  indicated)  are  due  to  the  desire 
of  the  landlord  to  disembarrass  himself  of  the  direct 
management  of  the  whole  or  part  of  his  estate  ;  he  creates 
tenures  in  favour  of  persons  who  will  pay  him  a  fixed  sum, 
and  make  what  they  can  out  of  the  land.  Other  such 
tenures  are  again  due  to  the  desire  to  encourage  the  bring- 
ing of  the  waste  under  cultivation,  for  which  purpose  a 
fixed  tenure  and  favourable  terms  are  needed — backed,  no 
doubt,  by  the  strong  and  long-established  feeling  of  right 
in  favour  of  him  '  who  first  cleared  the  land.'  There  are 


504  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

other  tenures  also  originating  in  grants  free  of  rent  for  the 
rendering  of  certain  services. 

Further  detail  would  be  here  unintelligible  ;  but  what 
has  been  said  will  show  that  we  have  an  ample  supply  of 
material  for  a  separate  section  on  '  Tenures '  (in  the  tech- 
nical sense).  When  we  come  down  to  the  lowest  grade — 
'  raiyat-holdings,'  or  cultivating  tenancies — it  is  obvious 
that  we  have  also  much  to  consider.  The  whole  battle  of 
the  tenant-question  in  Bengal  is  before  us,  and  the  history 
of  the  many  attempts  to  define  and  secure  different  grades 
of  tenant-right.  These  are  the  divisions  of  our  chapters  on 
Land-Tenures. 


SECTION  II. — THE  ZAMfNDAR  LANDLORD. 

§  I.  General  Remarks. 

I  have  said  enough  in  the  earlier  chapters  to  make  the 
student  familiar  with  the  name  Zamindar.  How  the  later 
and  declining  Mughal  ruler  adopted  the  plan  of  collecting 
his  revenue  through  agents  who,  having  contracted  to  find 
a  certain  sum  for  the  Treasury,  were  left  to  manage  the 
land  as  they  pleased — that  has  all  been  described.  The 
question  what  is  the  true  nature  of  the  Zamindar's  office  or 
title  has  been  discussed  in  various  books.  But  in  point  of 
fact  it  is  quite  impossible  to  bring  all  the  facts  which  were 
true  about  the  Zamindars  at  one  time  and  at  another, — to 
bring  all  these  facts  to  a  focus  and  then  to  make  them  fit  in 
with  tolerable  exactitude,  to  any  definition  of  right  or  title 
to  be  found  in  an  English  law-book  or  dictionary.  Looked 
at  with  reference  to  the  circumstances  of  a  certain  period 
of  Bengal  history,  and  with  reference  to  the  terms  of  deeds 
of  appointment,  it  is  easy  to  say  that  the  Zamindar  was 
only  a  revenue  official — a  tax-gatherer  if  you  please. 
Looked  at  with  reference  to  the  practical  position  actually 
held,  I  do  not  think  that  any  one  who  dispassionately  con- 
siders what  influence  and  hold  over  the  land  (and  the 
raiyats)  the  Zamindar  really  had  in  1789,  will  hesitate  to 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  505 

conclude  that  it  was  right  to  call  him  '  landlord/  provided 
the  subordinate  rights  were  adequately  secured. 

There  are  allusions  to  Zamindars  even  in  Akbar's  time, 
in  the  Ayin-i-Akbari ;  but  certainly  not  to  a  '  Zamindar '  as 
holding  an  office  or  function  created  for  the  realization  of 
the  revenues  of  a  certain  tract,  and  charged  with  police  and 
other  duties.  Indeed,  the  term  was  then  used  as  synony- 
mous with  '  bhiimi '  (evidently  the  Hindu  term  for  the 
natural  proprietor  or  lord  of  the  soil).  This  alone  should 
at  once  indicate  what  Ab-ul-Fazl  meant.  In  one  place 
certain  zamindars  are  mentioned  as  having  functions  like 
jagirdars,  but  any  landholder  might  have  been  employed  or 
granted  allowances  to  keep  a  force  of  foot  or  horsemen  to 
maintain  order  locally.  I  have  already  alluded  to  the  fact 
that  in  most  provinces  where  the  Mughal  power  extended 
its  conquest,  there  were  found,  as  in  Oudh,  local  Rajas  or 
chiefs  holding  considerable  areas  of  country  as  rulers l, 
having  both  their  own  private  lands  and  certain  rights 
and  dues,  as  ruler,  over  the  whole  country.  Such  chiefs 
could  not  resist  the  Mughal  arms  to  the  extent  of  main- 
taining their  independence,  but  yet  might  give  great 
trouble  in  outlying  districts ;  it  was,  therefore,  often  a 
matter  of  policy  to  leave  them  in  possession,  on  condition 
that  they  would  pay  over  to  the  Imperial  Treasury  a  cer- 
tain proportion  of  the  revenue  collected  from  the  villages. 
If  a  chief  accepted — as  he  would  be  obliged  to  do — that 
position,  unless  he  were  expressly  recognized  as  holding 
revenue-free,  or  as  assignee  of  the  revenue  for  special 
service,  he  would  be  called  '  landholder ' — Zamindar.  In 

1  '  Native  leaders,  sometimes  lead-  common  origin  of  many  of  the  most 
ing  men  of  Hindu  clans  who  have  considerable  modern  families,  both 
risen  to  power  as  guerilla  plunderers,  in  the  north  and  in  the  south.  To 
levying  black-mail,  and  eventually  our  ideas,  there  is  a  wide  gulf  be- 
coming to  terms  with  the  Govern-  tween  a  robber  and  a  landlord,  but 
ment,  have  established  themselves,  not  so  in  a  native's  view.  It  is  won- 
under  the  titles  of  Zamindar,  poly-  derful  how  much  in  times  such  an 
gar,  &c.,  in  the  control  of  tracts  of  those  of  the  last  century,  the  robber, 
country  for  which  they  pay  a  re-  the  Raja,  and  the  Zamindar  run  into 
venue  or  tribute,  uncertain  under  a  one  another.' — (Campbell's  Land- Ten- 
weak  power,  but  which  becomes  a  ures  in  India:  CobdenClub  Papers,  1876, 
regular  land  revenue  when  a  strong  p.  142.) 
power  is  established.  This  is  a  very 


506 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


the  same  way,  when  the  authorities  wished  to  show  some 
local  landholder  of  lesser  status,  some  kind  of  favour, 
they  gave  him  a  grant  of  a  local  tract  over  which  he 
was  to  collect  the  revenues ;  and  this  smaller  grant  they 
called  '  taluqdari.'  According  to  the  size  of  the  estate  and 
the  influence  of  the  holder,  the  grantee  was  allowed  to  be 
in  direct  relation  with  the  State,  or  was  placed  in  a  privi- 
leged position,  but  made  to  pay  through  a  greater  '  Zamin- 
dar.'  An  instance  of  this  is  afforded  by  the  case  of  many 
village  headmen  in  Bhagulpur  and  the  petty  landholders  of 
Chittagong,  all  of  whom  were  vaguely  called  '  taluqdars.' 

Let  us  confine  ourselves  here  to  the  Zaminddr. 

I  do  not  think  that  the  student  need  trouble  himself 
with  anything  more  than  can  be  gathered  from  a  few  really 
authoritative  sources.  There  are  the  minutes  of  Mr.  Shore 
and  Lord  Cornwallis,  both  based  on  very  valuable  native 
authorities  of  the  time  *,  and  these  give  what  I  may  call  the 
landlord  view.  On  the  other  side,  the  chief  authority 
urging  the  '  official '  nature  of  the  Zamindar's  position  was 
Mr.  James  Grant,  who  wrote  a  history  of  the  '  Northern 
Sirkars'  2  of  Madras  (where  there  were  also  Zammdars),  and 
who  afterwards  became  '  Chief  Sarishtaddr '  under  the 
Bengal  Government,  and  published  an  Enquiry  into  the 
nature  of  Zemindary  tenures  in  the  landed  property  of 
Bengal,  I79O3.  The  opinion  of  Mr.  Harington  himself 
(his  service  extended  from  1780  to  1823)  is  entitled  to 
the  greatest  weight,  as  he  was  in  the  service  all  through 
the  period  when  the  inquiries  were  going  on.  I  shall 
therefore  quote  it,  as  found  in  the  Analysis,  in  some 
detail. 


1  A  number  of  these,  on  which 
Mr.  Shore  based  his  minute  of  1 788, 
are   given   in    Harington,  vol.   iii., 
and  in  the  Reprint  of  Harington's 
chapter  on  the   Rights    of    Land- 
holders. 

2  Political  Survey  of  the  Northern  Cir- 
cars,   dated   aoth   December,    1784 ; 
also  an  Analysis  of  the  Finances  of  Ben- 


gal   (April,   1786)  ;   Appendices    to 
the  Fifth  Report. 

3  This  was  answered  by  Mr.  C. 
W.  B.  Rouse,  Secretary  to  the  Board 
of  Control,  in  a  Dissertation  con- 
cerning the  Landed  Property  in 
Bengal.  Mr.  Grant  was  a  good  deal 
followed  in  Patton's  Principles  of 
Asiatic  Monarchies,  1801. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  507 

§  2.    Origin  of  Zaminddrs. 

Mr.  Shore  said  that  the  origin  of  '  Zamindars '  was  un- 
certain l.  There  probably  never  was  a  time  when  a  Mughal 
governor  or  emperor  deliberately  conceived  the  plan  of 
creating  an  official  collector  of  rents,  or  invented  as  a 
title,  the  word  '  Zamindar,'  and  making  a  decree  or  regula- 
tion defining  the  rights  and  duties.  But,  as  already  stated, 
persons  who  had  a  real  estate  of  some  kind  or  degree  over 
villages  and  districts,  were  always,  from  the  earliest  times  of 
Muhammadan  rule,  spoken  of  generically  as  '  zamindars ' ; 
and  if  they  received  a  warrant  or  sanad  from  the  ruling 
power,  for  any  purpose,  it  would  probably  speak  of  them 
as  being  (official)  Zamindars.  If,  as  I  have  already  stated, 
they  were  people  of  minor  importance,  they  would  be 
called  '  taluqdar,' — holder  of  a  portion  of  land — a  '  depen- 
dency/ as  the  word  implies,  not  a  great  and  independent 
estate.  Persons  recognized  as  '  Zamindars '  and  some  of 
the  superior  '  taluqdars '  were  no  doubt  allowed  to  collect 
themselves,  and  to  pay  in  direct,  the  revenue  for  their 
territories.  The  rest  of  the  country  was  managed  solely 
by  State  officers  who  collected  through  the  heads  of  villages 
from  the  cultivators.  The  Mughal  system,  it  should  be 
always  borne  in  mind  (with  the  exception  of  the  country 
held  on  service  grants,  or  by  such  local  magnates  as  it  was 
politic  to  recognize),  was  essentially  raiyatwdri ;  it  went 
straight  to  the  cultivator  through  the  headman  of  each 
village.  The  original  system  then  did  not  countenance 
farming  the  revenues  ;  so  that  chiefs  and  others  (recognized 
landholders)  would  not  then  have  been  known  by  any 
particular  name  or  official  status.  Probably,  the  degree  of 
actual  power  which  the  landholder  had  in  managing  his 
estate,  varied  with  the  wealth,  respectability,  and  influence 
of  each  chief  or  grantee,  and  especially  with  his  nearness  to, 
or  remoteness  from,  the  centre  of  control.  But  it  would 
seem  that  when  the  Emperor  Farukhsiyar  ascended  the 

1  Minute  of  and  April,  1788. 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 


throne  in  1713  A.  D.,  the  decline  of  the  Empire  had  already 
begun,  and  decline  was  always  marked  by  relaxation  of 
control,  not  only  over  the  outlying  provinces,  but  over  the 
whole  administrative  machinery,  and  by  the  substitution  of 
plans  of  farming  the  revenues  of  convenient  tracts.  Then 
it  was  that,  besides  the  Rajas,  chiefs,  and  ancient  grantees, 
who  had  a  real  hold  over  the  country,  and  were  already 
spoken  of  as  the  Zamindars,  other  classes  of  persons  were 
employed  as  farmers,  and  the  same  name  and  the  same 
designation  came  to  be  applied  to  them  also.  As  a  matter 
of  fact,  we  find  ex-officials  possessed  of  wealth  and  energy 
— 'amils,  karoris,  &c., — also  bankers  and  Court  favourites, 
receiving  the  name  of  Zamindar. 

And  such  persons  would,  besides  taking  the  name, 
also  ape  the  dignities  and  importance  of  the  older  land- 
holders. 

This  class  of  Zamindar  would  commence  with  neither  the 
prestige  nor  with  the  customary  incidents  of  tenure  which 
generations  had  established  in  the  case  of  the  others.  The 
old  Raja,  for  instance,  was  already  well  established  in  his 
right  to  take  a  share  of  the  produce,  besides  having  a  more 
or  less  definite  claim  to  all  waste  land,  and  certainly  the 
unquestioned  right  of  bringing  it  under  cultivation,  for 
which  purpose  he  made  grants  or  located  his  own  '  tenants.' 
He  had  also  tolls  and  dues  of  all  kinds  from  traders  and 
artisans,  fees  from  woodcutters  in  the  forest,  and  transit 
duties.  His  estate  was,  of  course,  hereditary,  and  probably, 
if  it  was  that  of  a  Raja  or  greater  chief,  the  custom  of 
primogeniture  was  established.  Opportunities  for  getting 
the  best  lands  absolutely  into  his  own  hands  were  not 
wanting.  As  the  public  authority  declined,  his  oppor- 
tunities increased  ;  no  wonder  that  in  time  he  grew  to  be  a 
landlord,  and  that,  in  1789,  he  was  recognized  as  such.  The 
later  class  of  revenue-farmers  was  originally  in  no  such 
favourable  position  :  they  had  certainly  no  right  to  succeed 
by  inheritance,  nor  could  they  make  a  grant  of  any  land 
except  their  own.  They  held  a  sanad,  which  professed 
to  convey  no  property  in  anything,  but  merely  to  fix  duties 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  509 

and  require  obedience  and  faithful  service,  and  moreover 
they  had  to  subscribe  a  recognizance  for  due  observance, 
and  a  stipulation  for  the  amount  of  revenue  to  be  paid  in, 
which  was  supposed  to  be  the  total  rental,  less  a  fixed 
allowance  for  the  expense  and  risk  of  collection,  usually 
one-tenth  of  the  whole,  with  or  without  an  allowance  in 
money  or  land  specially  granted  as '  nankar '  or  subsistence. 
It  is  quite  certain  that  before  the  system  si  farming 
came  into  vogue,  and  Zamindars  of  this  class  were  ap- 
pointed, the  village  cultivators,  where  there  were  no  chiefs 
over  them,  had  a  customary  tenure,  which  was  certainly, 
however  decayed  or  weakened,  a  proprietary  right,  in 
their  holdings.  Therefore  the  Zamindars,  when  put  over 
them,  could  not  be  proprietors  in  the  sense  of  absolute 
owner,  entitled  to  the  usus,  abusus,fructus  et  vindicatio  of 
European  law.  Nevertheless,  the  '  Zamindar '  had  some 
land  to  begin  with  ;  he  soon  bought  up,  took  in  mortgage, 
and  otherwise  made  himself  master  of,  other  lands:  he 
cultivated  the  waste  with  his  own  tenants,  and  it  became 
his.  And  it  is  very  likely  that  in  these  matters  the  lower 
order  of  men  were  more  pushing  and  energetic  than  the  old 
nobility;  so  that  in  the  end,  what  with  the  growth  of  the 
modern  estates,  and  the  decay  of  the  older  ones, — for  noble 
families  die  out,  quarrel,  break  up,  become  bankrupt  and 
lose  their  lands, — all  Zaminddris  came  to  be  looked  upon  as 
one  and  the  same,  and  their  ancient  differences  of  origin 
ignored.  In  1788  Mr.  Shore  said  that  most  of  the  (then 
existing)  considerable  Zamindars  might  be  traced  to  an 
origin  within  the  last  century  and  a  half1. 

1  The  following   passage  is  from  mendation   of  Ratn   Chand,  when 

Ghulam     Husain,     the     historian  corruption  pervaded  every  depart- 

(author  of  the   Sayyar-muta,dkhirin,  ment  of  the  State,  the  unprincipled 

'  deeds  of  the  moderns  ').     He  was  Zamindars,   by    ingratiating    them- 

the  son  of  a  Na/im  or  Governor  of  selves  with  the  rulers  for  the  time 

the  Bihar  province.     He  was  one  of  being,  distressed  the  inferior  zamin- 

those  to  whom  questions  were  ad-  dars    (i.  e.   persons   who  had   been 

dressed  regarding  the  history  and  recognized  over  smaller  estates)  by 

status  of  Zamindars  before  the  Per-  every  possible  mode,  until  they  were 

manent  Settlement.     '  Since  the  de-  reduced  to  the  necessity  of  selling 

cline  of  the  constitution  in  the  reign  their  saminddris  to  their  oppressors, 

of  Farukhsiyar  and  the  introduction  who  thenceforward  became  ....  the 

of  the  farming  system  at  the  recom-  acknowledged  proprietors  of  them. 


5*0 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


§  3.    Incidents  of  the  Zaminddri  as  it  was  understood 
after  1713  A.D. 

(A)  Hereditary  Succession. 

The  title,  if  it  was  that  of  a  Raja  or  other  chief,  who 
became  Zamindar,  was  naturally  hereditary.  Only  the 
ruling  power  took  care  to  keep  the  heirs  in  mind  of 
their  subordinate  position,  by  exacting  a  fine  or  fee  at 
each  succession,  as  well  as  by  renewing  the  sanad  or  grant. 
When  Mr.  James  Grant  says  the  office  was  not  hereditary 
till  after  Nadir  Shah's  time  in  1739  A.D.1,  he  is  speaking  of 
those  revenue-farmers  who  had  no  natural  connection  with 
the  soil,  but  got  the  official  position. 

One  thing  that  helped  the  general  recognition  of  the 
hereditary  right,  was  the  fact  that  many  Zamindaris  were 
created  for  restoring  cultivation  or  on  condition  of  clearing 
the  waste  (jangalburi),  and  these  were  always  recognized 
(from  the  first)  as  passing  from  father  to  son,  because  a 
single  lifetime  would  hardly  suffice  to  develop  the  estate ; 
or,  at  all  events,  it  would  be  most  natural  to  continue  it  to 
the  son,  who  would  have  local  experience  at  the  time  when 
the  estate  was  probably  just  beginning  to  be  a  settled  and 
steadily -paying  one  2. 

(B)  The  form  of  appointing  Zaminddrs. 
To  begin  with,  when  the  State  affairs  were  still  managed 


Other  Zamindars,  having  desolated 
their  lands  by  mismanagement  and 
dissipation,  were  obliged  by  the 
ruling  power  to  dispose  of  them  to 
more  prudent  and  opulent  Zamin- 
dars for  the  liquidation  of  their 
balances.  The  title  of  the  pur- 
chasers of  such  lands  was  considered 
good  and  valid.  Towards  the  close 
of  the  reign  of  Muhammad  Shah 
(Farukhsiyar's  successor  in  1719) ... 
certain  Zamindars  by  attaching 
themselves  to  these  (certain  State) 
officers  acquired  great  influence,  and 
either  by  force  or  under  different 
pretences,  unjustly  possessed  them- 
selves of  the  estates  of  inferior 


(smaller)  landholders,  till  at  length 
becoming  rich  and  powerful .... 
they  declared  themselves  proprietors 
of  the  lands  thus  unfairly  acquired.' 

1  Fifth  Report,  vol.  iL  156. 

"  The  author  of  Land  Tenures  5j/  a 
Civilian  probably  puts  it  correctly 
when  he  says  (p.  72)  that  '  the  office 
of  Zamindar  could  not  be  claimed  as 
hereditary,  though  by  long  custom, 
and  perhaps  out  of  policy,  the  chil- 
dren of  deceased  contractors  were 
very  generally  admitted  as  successors 
to  their  parents  ;  they  were  not  in 
all  cases  appointed,  and  sometimes 
were  ousted.' 


CHAP.  III.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  5 1  I 

with  some  care  and  attention  to  detail,  the  Zamindar  who 
proposed  to  farm  a  considerable  area,  had  to  go  through 
a  somewhat  formidable  office-procedure.  No  doubt  all  this 
detail  was  not  exacted  from  the  '  Zamindars '  of  the  old 
Hindu  aristocracy,  who  simply  accepted  a  sanad  with 
a  fixed  sum  entered  in  it.  It  was  otherwise  with  the 
farmers,  though  even  they,  in  time,  ceased  to  receive  the 
sanad,  except  in  special  cases,  and  then  chiefly  in  case  they 
sought  it  as  a  protection  against  rival  claimants l.  The 
original  procedure  was  for  the  new  Zamindar  to  petition 
the  provincial  governor  informing  him  that  the  office  was 
vacant — let  us  suppose  by  death, — and  adding  that  the 
petitioner  desired  favour  as  the  heir  or  successor.  The 
Governor  would  reply,  in  the  case  of  a  person  of  some 
consideration,  by  letters  of  condolence,  &c.  This  prepared 
the  way  for  the  submission  of  the  'arzi,  or  formal  petition, 
offering  to  be  responsible  for  the  usual  revenue  total, 
together  with  any  balance  that  might  be  outstanding.  On 
receipt  of  this,  the  Government  officer  prepared  a  fard 
sawdl — an  abstract  of  the  petition  with  necessary  inform- 
ation as  to  figures,  &c., — and  asked  for  the  orders  of  his 
superior.  On  the  orders  being  received,  the  proper  officer 
made  out  an  exact  schedule  of  the  villages  or  component 
parts  of  the  estate,  and  of  the  assessment  expected  from 
each,  the  deductions  allowed,  and  the  balance  payable  to 
the  treasury.  This  was  the  fard-i-haqiqat  (or  '  statement 
of  the  true  facts')2.  The  expectant  Zamindar  had  then  to 
give  a  sort  of  recognizance  or  'muchalka,'  a  document3 
which  acknowledged  his  responsibility  for  the  revenue 
stated  in  abstract,  and  for  the  performance  of  the  duty : — 
as  Mr.  Phillips  puts  it, — 

'to  observe  a  commendable  character  towards  the  body  of 
the  inhabitants  at  large,  to  endeavour  to  punish  and  expel 
the  refractory,  and  to  extirpate  robbers  ;  to  conciliate  and 
encourage  the  raiyats,  and  to  promote  the  increase  of  cultiva- 

1  Harington,  vol.  iii.  337.  proper  officer. 

2  It  is  an  elaborate  document  in          3  Also  called  '  qabuliyat '  or  ac- 
four  columns,  each  filled  up  by  the      ceptance. 


5 1 2  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

tion  ;  ....  to  take  care  that  travellers  might  pass  in  safety, 
and  that  no  robbery  or  murder  should  be  committed  ;  and  if 
any  one  should  be  robbed,  he  agreed  to  be  responsible  for 
producing  the  culprits  with  the  property,  or  to  make  good  the 
loss J ;  to  repress  drunkenness  and  all  kinds  of  irregularity  ;  to 
pay  punctually  the  assessment,  less  the  items  of  allowed  deduc- 
tions (mazkurat) ;  to  transmit  to  the  Government  office  the 
official  papers  required.' 

Lastly,  the  Government  office  issued  the  '  sanad '  (called 
also  'parwana')  addressed  to  the  Government  officials  in 
the  limits  of  the  Zamindari,  and  to  the  village  accountants 
(patwaris),  village  headmen,  who  were  called  (in  the  Per- 
sian revenue  language,  but  not,  of  course,  by  the  people) 
'  muqaddarn.'  It  recited  the  Zamindar' s  duties,  prohibited 
his  levying  abwdb  or  cesses  without  authority,  and  com- 
manded the  local  officers  and  others  to  receive  him  as 
Zamindar,  and  to  take  all  pargana  papers  and  accounts 
signed  by  him,  as  authentic 2. 

It  is  quite  obvious  from  the  terms  of  such  documents, 
that  the  holders  of  them,  as  such,  were  neither  constituted 
soil-proprietors,  nor  treated  therein,  as  in  any  such  posi- 
tion. But  then  the  executor  of  such  a  series  of  documents 
might  have  rights  independently  of  them,  and,  what  is  of 
more  importance,  might  in  time  easily  grow  into  a  new 
position.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  when  we  reflect  on  the 
emoluments  and  opportunities  of  the  Zamindar,  his  power 
of  getting  land  by  sale  and  mortgage,  his  '  right '  of  ousting 
obnoxious  men,  and  by  taking  possession  when  an  unfortu- 
nate owner  absconded — perhaps  to  avoid  exactions  which 
had  become  intolerable,  perhaps  in  his  inability  to  pay  his 
'  rent ' — it  is  not  difficult  to  perceive  how  the  Zamindar 
grew  into  his  ultimate  position.  When  this  virtual  owner- 
ship had  gone  on  for  several  generations,  and  had  become 

1  This  is  a  very  ancient  custom  in  Minute  of  April,  1788),  and  Phillips 
parts  of  India.     In  the  Rajputana  gives  a  translation  of  the  sanad  (of 
States  it  was  common  till  quite  of  Muhammad   Shah's   reign)  in  A.D. 
late  years.  1 735-6  granted  to  the  Zamindar  of 

2  Specimen  sanads  are  given  in  Rajshahi. 
Harington  (Appendix  9  to  Shore's 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  5 1 3 

consolidated,  the  fact  of  a  formerly  different  status  very 
naturally  became  little  more  than  a  shadowy  memory. 
Our  early  legislators  of  1793  could  then  hardly  avoid  call- 
ing the  Zammdar's  right  a  proprietary  one,  and  treating  it 
accordingly  ;  though,  as  I  have  already  shown,  they  limited, 
or  intended  to  limit,  the  right  thus  conferred,  with  a  view 
to  securing  at  least  so  much  of  the  original  right  of  the 
now  subordinate  village  landowners  as  could  still  be 
established. 

(C)  Power  of  Transfer. 

In  one  respect,  however,  the  recognition  accorded  to  the 
Zammdar's  right  in  1793  was  a  material  advance  beyond 
what  practice  had  hitherto  sanctioned.  Powerful  as  the 
Zamindar  became  in  managing  the  land,  in  grasping  and 
in  ousting,  he  had  no  power  of  alienating  his  estate ;  he 
could  not  raise  money  on  it  by  mortgage,  nor  sell  the  whole 
or  any  part  of  it.  This  clearly  appears  from  a  proclama- 
tion issued  on  ist  August,  1786;  the  illegal  practice  'of 
alienating  revenue  lands '  is  complained  of ;  the  '  gentlemen 
appointed  to  superintend '  the  various  districts,  are  invited 
zealously  to  prevent  the  '  commission  of  this  offence ' ;  and 
the  Zamindar,  chaudhari,  taluqdar,  or  other  landholder  who 
disobeys  is  threatened  with  '  dispossession  from  his  lands  V 

But  such  a  limitation  was  soon  thought  to  be  inconsistent 
with  the  'proprietary  right'  which  it  was  the  policy  of 
Government  to  secure  and  develop ;  and  it  was  abandoned 
accordingly.  Several  of  the  Regulations  allude  to  the 
power  of  alienation,  as  now  for  the  first  time  conceded. 
(See,  for  example,  Section  9  of  Regulation  I  of  1793,  quoted 
at  p.  410 ) 

The  right  was  unrestricted,  provided  only  that  transfers 
should  not  be  inconsistent  with  the  Hindu  or  Muhammadan 
law  (whichever  applied),  or  to  any  Regulation ;  that  they 
should  be  registered  before  the  Collector,  so  that  the  revenue 
liability  might  be  known ;  and  that  the  transferee  would 

1  This  proclamation  will  be  found  Mr.  Cotton's  Revenue  History  of  Chitta- 
reprinted  in  Appendix  F,  p.  179,  of  gong. 

VOL.  I.  L  1 


5  H  I^AND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  ll. 

be  answerable  for  the  revenue,  or  for  a  portion  of  the 
revenue,  in  case  of  sale  of  a  part  of  the  estate  to  which  the 
revenue  share  was  allotted  on  principles  stated  in  the 
Regulation. 

(D)  Emoluments  of  the  Zaminddr. 

Originally  the  Zamindar  was  bound  to  account  for  all  he 
collected  from  the  raiyats ;  these  payments  were  not  his 
rents  but  the  revenue  assessed  by  the  State,  and  increased 
from  time  to  time.  He  was  to  pay  in  all  to  the  treasury, 
less  a  certain  percentage  and  some  cash  allowances,  which 
were  carefully  specified.  But  this  strictness  died  out  in 
time ;  for  the  very  laxity  of  rule  which  induced  the  Gover- 
nors to  save  themselves  trouble  by  handing  over  the  entire 
management  to  Zamindars,  operated  also  to  prevent  any 
scrutiny  into  details.  More  and  more,  therefore,  the  Za- 
mindar got  to  be  a  mere  contractor  for  a  fixed  sum,  and 
able  to  make  his  own  terms  with  the  raiyats. 

In  the  original  accounts  we  find  that  the  Zamindar  was 
allowed — 

(i)  His  percentage  called  '  dastur-zamindari '  ; 

(a)  An  allowance  called  nankar  (lit.  bread  of  service): 
this  was  at  first  in  cash  (as  a  deduction);  but 
afterwards  lands  called  'nankar'  were  held 
revenue-free ; 

(3)  The  mazkurat  (or  '  specific  items '),  being  the  charges 

of  collection,  such  as  headman's  fees  (muqaddami), 
wages  for  servants  and  messengers  (paikan),  ex- 
penses of  office  (daftar-band  and  sarinjamf),  and  a 
number  of  others ; 

(4)  Fees  (nimtaki — half  a  '  taka '  (or  paisd  in  the  rupee) 

to  the  kanungo ; 

(5)  Charitable  allowances,  being  remissions  for  '  aima ' 

and  'inam'  holdings  (plots  left  free  to  religious 
persons,  teachers,  village  servants,  &c.) ;  qadam- 
rasiil,  fees  paid  for  preservation  of  'footprints  of 
the  Prophet,'  also  (khairdt)  alms  ;  and  daily  allow- 
ance to  religious  mendicants  and  others  (rozina). 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND   TENUBES.  5 1 5 

(E)  Tfie  Zaminddr's  Private  Lands. 

In  many  cases  the  Zaminddr  had  private  lands  called 
'nij-jot'  (the  Hindi  equivalent  of  the  Persian  c  khud-kasht,3 
and  the  same  as  the  '  sir '  of  other  parts) — i.  e.  lands  of  his 
family  which  he  cultivated  with  his  own  labour  or  personal 
tenants.  From  these  the  State  might  or  might  not  take 
revenue. 

A  large  portion  of  the  estates,  in  many  districts,  was 
waste,  and  the  duty  of  the  Zamindar  was  to  extend  cul- 
tivation, not  (originally)  for  his  own  profit,  but  with  a  view 
to  revenue  from  additional  fields  profiting  the  Treasury. 
But  when  the  Zamindar's  revenue  came  to  be  a  lump  sum 
fixed  by  bargain,  it  further  resulted  that  all  new  cultivation 
was  solely  a  benefit  to  him  as  contractor.  Not  only  so, 
but  as  all  the  waste  lands  would  be  unoccupied  and  there 
would  be  no  resident  or  ancient  '  raiyats,'  to  claim  any 
special  terms,  it  followed  that  the  land  was  cultivated  by 
real  contract-tenants,  and  of  course  was  acknowledged  to 
be  the  property  of  the  Zamindar  under  the  name  of 
' khamdr1.' 

A  third  kind  of  land  which  the  Zamindar  came  to  hold 
was  under  the  head  of  '  nankar,'  already  mentioned.  When 
this  allowance  was  made  up  by  granting  certain  lands  free 
of  revenue,  the  Zamindar,  very  naturally,  absorbed  them  as 
his  own  property  2. 

This  custom  of  '  nankar '  spread  wide,  and  in  the  Northern 

1  '  Khamar '  is  an  Uriya  or  Ben-  khamar  lands  that  we  have  is  in  the 
gali  word  meaning '  threshing-floor,'  Instructions  to  Supervisors  (1769).  The 
and  indicates  lands  the  produce  of  Revenue  Committee  remark  that 
which  is  divided  on  the  threshing-  such  lands  have  no  natural  tenants, 
floor  between  the  cultivator  or  the  and  that  the  Zamindar  cultivates  by 
soil-owner.  Naturally  in  new  lands,  contract,  making  advances  to  cul- 
where  at  first  cultivation  is  pre-  tivators,  and  receiving  back  his  ad- 
carious,  liable  to  fail  or  to  be  de-  vance  with  interest  and  a  share  in 
stroyed  by  deer,  pigs,  and  wild  the  produce  (one-half  to  two-thirds), 
beasts  from  the  neighbouring  — (Colebrooke's  Supplement  to  the 
jungles,  the  terms  of  the  tenancy  Digest,  pp.  182.  183.)  At  that  date  the 
are  not  a  cash  rent  but  a  '  bhaoli,'  Committee  thought  this  was  an  en- 
or  division  of  produce.  This  saves  croachment,  and  desired  that  the 
the  tenant  from  loss,  as,  if  the  crop  waste  when  cultivated  should  be 
fails,  or  is  only  a  partial  one,  no  de-  '  raiyati '  land — i.  e.  liable  to  pay  to 
mand,  or  only  a  limited  one,  can  be  the  State  through  the  Zamindar. 
made  on  him.  The  first  mention  of  2  Harington,  iii.  320. 

L  1  2 


516  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

Sirk&rs  of  Madras  was  found  enjoyed  under  the  local  name 
of  'savaram1.' 

§  4.    Other  Items. 

As  the  Zamindar  owned  the  waste  in  his  estate,  so  he 
owned  '  manorial  rights,'  such  as  fisheries,  and  produce 
from  fruits  or  from  grazing,  and  sale  of  jungle  products. 
These  were  the  c  sayer  '  items,  already  spoken  of  in  another 
connection.  The  Zamindar  appears  to  have  levied  a  small 
fee  called  'parjot'  (or  in  Persian  'muhtarfa'),  on  non -agri- 
cultural residents  in  the  villages,  exactly  as  the  Panjab 
village  landlords  do  to  this  day.  It  may  be  likened  to 
a  kind  of  ground-rent  for  the  house-site. 

§  5.   Mdlikdna. 

This  term  so  often  occurs  in  Bengal  (and  indeed  in  all 
revenue  literature)  that  I  may  take  this  opportunity  to 
explain  it. 

The  revenue  responsibility  being  on  the  land,  Government 
is  entitled  to  exclude  the  proprietor  who  refuses  what  the 
authorities  deem  a  reasonable  assessment ;  but  in  such  cases 
it  grants  a  '  malikana,'  or  ex-proprietary  allowance,  to  sup- 
port the  recusant  during  the  period  of  his  exclusion.  This 
is  not  less  than  five  nor  more  than  ten  per  cent,  on  the 
revenue. 

See  Sec.  But  the  term  malikana  has  also  a  wider  application :  it 
vin  of  refers  to  any  portion  of  the  produce,  or  payment  made  in 
1793;  and  acknowledgment  of  a  proprietary2,  or  more  commonly  an 
1822,  Sec°  ex-proprietary,  right  or  title.  It  is  well  illustrated  in 
5,  el.  2.  Bihar ;  there  the  villages  appear  in  many  cases  to  have 
come  under  the  landlord  claims  of  men  who  were  leaders 

1  A  Telugu  word  obtained  from  as   his  share  or  profit.     It  is  also 
the    Persian    '  Chayar,'    a    certain  commonly  used  to  signify  the  allow- 
measure  of  land. — (Wilson.}  ances  paid  to  a  person  as  having 

2  Thus   the    term    is    sometimes  some  claim,  but  not  enough  to  entitle 
used  to   mean   the  portion  of  the  him  to  a  Settlement.     In  this  sense 
total  assets  which ,  on  a  Settlement,  we  often  find  it  used  in  the  North- 
Government  leaves  to  the  proprietor  Western  Provinces  and  Oudh. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  5  1 7 

of  troops  and  minor  chiefs,  or  cadets  of  noble  families, 
who  so  often,  as  we  have  already  seen,  established  themselves 
as  landlords  over  single  villages  and  small  estates.  Small 
owners  of  this  class  cannot  make  terms  with  later  con- 
querors, as  large  estate-holders  can  ;  and  it  came  to  pass  that, 
under  the  Muhammadan  rule,  such  petty  landholders  were 
displaced  either  by  Muhammadan  jagirdars,  who  got  grants 
over  their  heads,  so  to  speak,  or  by  other  minor  grantees 
(lakhirajdars);  further,  under  our  own  earlier  revenue 
system1,  the  country  was  farmed  to  outsiders,  and  in  the 
end  the  new-comers  had  got  so  firmly  fixed  that  the 
Permanent  Settlement  was  made  with  them.  But  such  is 
the  force  of  custom,  that  the -new  grantees,  and  farmers, 
were  always  obliged  to  recognize  the  older  ousted  pro- 
prietors by  making  them  a  '  malikana '  allowance.  When 
our  Government  resumed  a  number  of  the  lakhiraj  estates 
and  assessed  them  to  revenue  and  settled  with  the  present 
holders,  the  estate  was  often  charged  with  paying  the 
'  malikana '  to  the  ousted  proprietor. 

§  6.    Small  Zaminddris  in  Bihdr. 

The  mention  of  the  small  land-holdings  of  Bihar  remind 
us  that  we  must  not  suppose  all  Zamindars  to  have  had 
great  estates.  The  fact  is  that  in  Bihar,  had  it  not  been 
for  the  Bengal  system,  it  would  have  been  found  that  there 
were  village-estates  of  the  landlord  class  in  a  tolerable 
state  of  preservation.  We  have  here  actual  tradition  (see 
Chap.  IV.  page  1 23)  how  the  Aryans  advanced  into  Bihar ; 
and  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  the  petty  landlords  of  the 
Babhan  (the  military  or  Kshatriya  caste)  alluded  to  by  the 
older  writers,  were  just  the  descendants  of  the  chiefs  and 
rulers  who  either  originally,  or  by  the  breaking  up  of  larger 
territorial  rulerships,  acquired  the  position  of  landlords 
over  single  villages  or  over  small  estates  of  two  or  three 
villages.  In  the  course  of  time  some  of  these  small  estate 
holders  were  superseded  by  '  jagir '  grantees  or  farmers  of 
revenue,  as  above  stated,  but  many  of  them  survived,  and 
1  Mr.  Shore's  Minute  of  September,  1 789,  §  2. 


5 1 8  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  it. 

the  family  chief  or  leading  man  among  them,  became  the 
Zamindar.  (The  system  only  admitted  of  one  man  bear- 
ing the  title,  unless  several  expressly  agreed  that  they  were 
co-sharers.)  Some  of  these  families,  though  they  had 
dropped  out  of  rank,  and  were  not  Zamindars  in  possession, 
were  still  so  far  recognized  as  to  receive  the  malikdna 
allowance  as  just  now  explained.  Some  of  them,  as  we 
shall  see  presently,  in  the  Shahabad  district,  fell  into  the 
lower  position  of  'tenure-holders'  (called  guzashta  jot).  But 
the  case  of  Bihar  is  interesting  as  showing  how,  what  in 
the  North -West  Provinces  would  have  produced  village 
landlord-communities,  developed  there  into  small  Zamin- 
ddri  estates.  The  Monghyr  district  affords  another  in- 
stance of  the  existence  of  small  estates  caused  by  the 
subdivision  of  an  original  family  grant  or  acquisition.  I 
have  alluded  to  it  more  particularly  under  the  head  of 
taluqs  in  the  sequel,  because  the  subdivision  of  the 
estate  seems  to  have  resulted  in  the  formation  of  a 
number  of  taluqs,  some  of  which  paid  their  revenue  direct 
to  Government,  and  others  through  one  of  the  larger  estate- 
holders. 

The  rules  by  which  '  taluqs '  were  separated  from  the 
Zamindaris  have  been  alluded  to  before :  in  Monghyr  the 
result  was  that  a  number  of  small  separate  estates  were 
recognized  as  petty  Zamindaris. 

In  Sylhet  and  Chittagong,  the  nature  of  the  holdings  of 
land  was  such,  that,  as  we  shall  see,  the  '  Zamindars '  in 
those  districts  were  quite  small  landholders  *.  In  Benares 
also,  the  'Zamindars'  actually  settled  with,  were  village 
bodies ;  for  the  Raja,  who  would  have  been  the  great 
Zamindar  under  other  circumstances,  had  resigned  his 
claims. 

1  Sylhet  is  treated  of  in  another  Assam.  Chittagong  is  separately 
part  of  the  book,  because  it  is  in  described  further  on. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  519 


§  7.   Authorities  on  the  nature  of  the  Zaminddr's  Right. 

Mr.  Harington's l  definition  (or  rather  description)  of  a 
Bengal  Zamfndar  is  as  follows : — 

'A  landholder  of  a  peculiar  description,  not  definable  by 
any  single  term  in  our  language — a  receiver  of  the  territorial 
revenue  of  the  State  from  the  raiyats  and  other  under-tenants 
of  land — allowed  to  succeed  to  his  Zamlnddri  by  inheritance, 
yet  in  general  required  to  take  out  a  renewal  of  his  title  from 
the  sovereign  or  his  representative  on  payment  of  a  fine  on 
investiture  to  the  Emperor,  and  a  nasdrana  or  present  to  his 
provincial  delegate — the  Nazi'm  ;  permitted  to  transfer  his 
Zaminddri  by  sale  or  gift 2,  yet.  commonly  expected  to  obtain 
previous  special  permission  ;  privileged  to  be  generally  the 
annual  contractor  for  the  public  revenue  recoverable  from  his 
Zaminddri,  yet  set  aside  with  a  limited  provision,  in  land  or 
money,  whenever  it  was  the  pleasure  of  Government  to  collect 
the  rents  by  separate  agency,  or  to  assign  them  temporarily  or 
permanently  by  the  grant  of  a  'jagir,'  or  an  *  altamgha '  : 
authorized  in  Bengal  (since  the  early  part  of  the  eighteenth 
century)  to  apportion  to  the  parganas,  villages,  and  lesser 
divisions  of  land  within  the  Zaminddri,  the  dbwdb  or  cesses 
imposed  by  the  Subadar  (provincial  governor)  usually  in  some 
proportion  to  the  standard  assessment  of  the  Zaminddri  esta- 
blished by  Todar  Mai  and  others,  yet  subject  to  the  discretionary 
interference  of  public  authority,  either  to  equalize  the  amount 
assessed  on  particular  divisions,  or  to  abolish  what  appeared 
oppressive  to  the  raiyat ;  entitled  to  any  contingent  emolu- 
ments proceeding  from  his  contract  during  the  period  of  his 
agreement,  yet  bound  by  the  terms  of  his  tenure  to  deliver  in 
a  faithful  account  of  his  receipts 3 ;  responsible  by  the  same 
terms  for  keeping  the  peace  within  his  jurisdiction,  but  appa- 
rently allowed  to  apprehend  only,  and  deliver  over  to  a 
Musalman  magistrate  for  trial  and  punishment.' 

1  Dr.  Field  notices  that  Mr.  Har-  assumed  this  power,  but  under  the 

ington   gave  this  opinion  to  Lord  British  rule  this  was  at  first  dis- 

Cornwallis  in  1789,  and  that  he  had  allowed,  as  stated  at  p.  513. 

seen  no  occasion  to  alter  it  twenty-  3  This,  of  course,  was  not  done  in 

eight  years  afterwards.  later  times  ;  or  an  account  was  ren- 

*  This     is     more     doiibtful — see  dered,  framed  just  as  was  convenient 

Phillips,   p.   270.     No   doubt  they  for  the  interests  of  the  Zamindar. 


520  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.        [BOOK   II. 

§  8.   Mr.  Shores  Views. 

Mr.  Shore  speaks  of  Zamindars  as  proprietors  of  the  soil, 
— to  the  property  of  which  they  succeed  by  right  of  inherit- 
ance ;  but  he  explains  that  a  property  in  the  soil  must  not 
be  understood  to  convey  the  same  rights  in  India  as  in 
England.  We  can  only,  under  a  despotic  government,  look 
to  the  general  practice  as  acknowledging  a  sort  of  right l. 

In  another  place  2  he  says  expressly  : — 

'  The  relation  of  a  Zamindar  to  Government,  and  of  a  raiyat 
to  the  Zamindar  is  neither  that  of  a  proprietor  nor  a  vassal, 
but  a  compound  of  both.  The  former  performs  acts  of  autho- 
rity in  connection  with  proprietary  right ;  the  latter  has  rights 

without   real   property Much  time  will,   I  fear,   elapse 

before  we  can  establish  a  system  perfectly  consistent  in  all  its 
parts,  and  before  we  can  reduce  the  compound  relation  of  a 
Zamindar  to  Government,  and  of  a  raiyat  to  a  Zamindar,  to 
the  simple  principles  of  landlord  and  tenant.' 

§  9.    Lord  Cornwalliss  Views. 

LORD  CORNWALLIS  expressed  himself  satisfied  with  Mr, 
Shore's  proofs  that  the  Zamfnddr,  though  not  an  absolute 
soil-owner,  was  yet  entitled  to  be  considered  as  a  landlord 
and  recognized  with  a  secure  title,  and  he  added  something 
that  is  important,  as  showing  that  the  recognition  of  the 
Zamindar  was  not  founded  on  a  mere  abstract  decision  on 
historical  evidence,  but  on  a  State  policy  of  justice  and  the 
(supposed)  welfare  of  the  province.  He  says  : — 

'Although,  however,  I  am  not  only  of  opinion  that  the 
Zamindars  have  the  best  right,  but  from  being  persuaded  that 
nothing  could  be  so  ruinous  to  the  public  interest  as  that  the 
land  should  be  retained  as  the  property  of  Government,  I  am 
also  convinced  that,  failing  the  claims  of  right  of  the  Zamindars, 
it  would  be  necessary  for  the  public  good  to  grant  a  right  of 
property  in  the  soil  to  them  or  to  persons  of  other  descriptions. 
I  think  it  unnecessary  to  enter  into  any  discussion  of  the 

1  See  Section  383  of  the  Minute          2  Minute  of  December,  1789. 
of  the  i8th  June,  1789  (Fifth  Report}. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  52  T 

grounds  on  which  their  right  appears  to  be  founded.  It  is  the 
most  effectual  mode  for  promoting  the  general  improvement  that  I 
look  upon  as  the  important  object  for  our  present  consideration1.' 

§  10.    Decision  of  the  Court  of  Directors. 

With  all  these  minutes  and  views  before  them,  the  Court  of 
Directors  came  to  a  conclusion  ;  and  their  final  orders  will 
naturally  be  regarded  as  of  first-rate  importance  2. 

After  stating  that  they  had  previously  stated  their  views, 
but  always  felt  that  the  materials  were  insufficient  for  a 
decisive  opinion,  the  Court  of  Directors  go  on  to  say : — 

'  On  the  fullest  consideration,  .we  are  inclined  to  think  that, 
whatever  doubts  may  exist  with  respect  to  their  original 
character,  whether  as  proprietors  of  land  or  collectors  of  reve- 
nue, or  with  respect  to  the  changes  which  may  in  process  of 
time  have  taken  place  in  their  situation,  there  can,  at  least,  be 
little  difference  of  opinion  as  to  the  actual  condition  of  the 
Zamindars  under  the  Mughal  government.  Custom  generally 
gives  them  a  certain  species  of  hereditary  occupancy,  but  the 
sovereign  nowhere  appears  to  have  bound  himself  by  any  law 
or  covenant  not  to  deprive  them  of  it ;  and  the  rents  to  be  paid 
by  them  remained  always  to  be  fixed  by  his  arbitrary  will  and 
pleasure,  which  were  constantly  exercised  upon  this  object. 
If  considered,  therefore,  as  right  of  property,  it  was  very  im- 
perfect, very  precarious,  having  not  at  all,  or  but  in  a  very 
small  degree,  those  qualities  that  confer  independence  and 
value  upon  the  landed  property  of  Europe.  Though  such  be 
our  ultimate  views  of  this  question,  our  originating  a  system 
of  fixed  equitable  taxation  will  sufficiently  show  that  our  inten- 
tion has  not  been  to  act  upon  the  high  tone  of  Asiatic  despotism. 
We  are,  on  the  contrary,  for  establishing  real,  permanent, 
valuable  landed  rights  in  our  provinces,  and  for  conferring 
such  rights  upon  the  Zamindars  ;  but  it  is  just  that  the  nature 
of  the  concession  should  be  known,  and  that  our  subjects 
should  see  they  receive  from  the  enlightened  principles  of  a 
British  Government  what  they  never  enjoyed  under  their 
own3.' 

1  Fifth  Report,  vol.  i.  591,  quoted  in      tember,  1792,  quoted  by  Dr.  Field. 
Phillips,  p.  276.  3  Those  who  wish  for  further  de- 

2  General  letter,  dated  i9th  Sep-      tails  will  do   well  to   consult  the 


522  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  it, 

§  ii.    Reasons  for  the  difference  of  opinion  as  to  the 
Real  Status  of  the  Zam{nddr. 

It  will  thus  be  easy  to  see  how,  by  singling  out  and 
fixing  the  attention  on  certain  undoubted  features  of  the 
farming  system,  we  can  argue  (and  that  conclusively)  that 
the  '  Zaminddr '  was  originally  only  a  revenue-farmer  and 
an  official.  On  the  other  hand,  by  doing  the  same  in 
respect  of  other  features,  especially  in  the  history  of  those 
Zamindars  who  were  local  chiefs  and  had  been  rulers  under 
a  previous  organization,  but  who  were  employed  in  a  sort 
of  official  capacity  by  the  Mughal  conquerors,  we  can,  with 
equaj  justice,  argue  that  the  Zamindar  was  nearer  a  land- 
lord (in  our  sense)  than  anything  else.  Had  the  Settlement 
been  made  by  Mr.  Holt  Mackenzie  in  1822,  instead  of 
under  Mr.  Shore  in  1789,  it  is  probable  that  the  variety  of 
status  would  have  found  recognition.  Some  Zamindars  of 
the  old  stock  would  certainly  have  been  allowed  as  pro- 
prietors, and  the  villages  protected  by  a  sub-settlement  > 
others  would  have  been  merely  allowed  a  cash  malikana. 
But,  perhaps,  in  so  saying,  I  am  not  allowing  sufficiently 
for  the  fusing  and  equalizing  influence  of  time;  and 
that  really  all  had  come  to  be  very  much  alike.  However 
that  may  be,  certainly  no  one  in  1790  Dreamt  of  making 
any  difference.  To  find  a  general  rule  for  all,  was  what 
was  contemplated ;  and  this  leads  me  to  repeat  that  what 
our  administrators  of  1790  had  to  do,  was  not  to  determine 
a  historical  and  accurate  theory  of  the  Zamindar' s  position, 
but  to  take  facts  as  they  found  them  after  a  century  and  a 
half  of  growth  and  development,  and  to  confer  on  the 
Zamindars  such  a  position  as  was  best,  not  with  reference 
to  what  they  once  were,  but  with  what  they  had  then  prac- 
tically become,  when  the  prescription  of  years,  I  might  say 
of  generations,  had  covered  original  acts  of  illegality  or 
usurpation. 

opinions  of  the  Judges  declared  in  plementary  vol.  204).  A  good  ab- 
1865  in  the  case  known  as  the  Great  stract  will  be  found  in  Phillips, 
Bent  Case  (Beng.  Law  Reports,  sup-  p.  312  seq. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  523 

It  is  very  easy  to  write  that  the  authors  of  the  Perma- 
nent Settlement,  with  a  few  strokes  of  the  pen,  converted 
Muhammadan  tax-gatherers  into  landed  proprietors,  and 
phrases  of  that  sort ;  but  they  are  far  too  summary  to  be 
accurate  or  just. 

Moreover,  from  the  authoritative  declarations  which  I 
have  above  cited,  it  must  certainly  appear  that  no  one 
intended  to  make  the  Zamfndar  an  absolute  owner  of  any- 
thing, but  to  give  him  a  certain  estate  in  land  (which  is 
juristically  a  different  thing),  and  that  limited  by  a  due 
observance  of  the  rights  of  subordinate  holders  and  cul- 
tivators. If,  in  effect,  he  got  more  than  was  intended,  that 
was  because  the  steps  taken"  to  secure  the  inferior  rights 
were  ineffective ;  it  was  not  because  the  authorities  were 
wrong  in  the  view  they  took  of  the  Zamindar's  position. 

§  12.   Modern  legal  view  of  the  Zamindar's  Title. 

The  actual  right  of  the  landlord,  as  it  now  exists,  is  an 
estate  in  the  soil  certainly  less  than  a  '  fee-simple '  of 
English  law,  but  freely  heritable  and  alienable  and  avail- 
able for  mortgage,  sale,  gift,  or  bequest.  It  is,  however, 
limited  by  the  rights  of  tenure-holders  and  raiyats  (i.  e. 
tenants),  when  they  possess  such  under  the  Tenancy  Law, 
or  other  special  law  applicable  to  the  case.  And,  of  course, 
it  is  limited  (like  all  other  rights  in  revenue-paying  lands) 
by  the  Government  right  to  its  revenue  and  the  right  of 
sale  in  case  of  default  to  make  good,  at  due  date,  the  full 
amount  of  that  revenue1.  The  original  intention  most 
probably  was  to  limit  the  landlord's  demands  on  the 
raiyats  much  more  than  the  later  laws  limited  them.  But 
there  is  no  clear  decision  traceable  as  to  whether  all 
'raiyats'  (or  any  but  a  small  class)  were  intended  to 

1  Mr.  Justice  Macpherson  put  it  intended  to  be,  the  absolute  pro- 
well  when  he  said  in  the  Eent  Case  prietor  of  the  soil ....  for  certain 
(p.  214),  '  As  regards  the  legislation  classes  of  raiyats  have  at  all  times 
from  1793  to  Act  X  of  1859,  it,  in  my  had  rights  quite  inconsistent  with 
opinion,  shows  clearly  that  the  [his]  absolute  ownership.' 
Zamindar  never  was,  and  was  never 


524  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

remain  on  for  ever  at  fixed  rents,  or  whether  their  rents 
could  be  raised  from  time  to  time.  Sometimes  we  meet 
with  expressions  that  imply  the  former  or  something  like 
it ;  at  other  times  with  expressions  that  imply  that  rents 
(or  some  rents)  may  be  altered  and  tenants  evicted.  And 
the  legal  powers  actually  put  into  the  hands  of  the  pro- 
prietors were  such  as  to  enable  them  in  practice  both 
to  enhance  and  to  evict ;  it  soon  came  to  be  looked  on  as 
a  matter  of  course,  that  in  most  cases,  they  had  the  full 
powers  of  an  English  landlord.  Then  came  the  revulsion 
of  feeling  which  led  to  the  legislation  of  1859,  and  ulti- 
mately to  that  of  1885;  but  meanwhile  the  prescriptive 
position  which  had  been  growing  steadily  during  seventy 
years,  was  so  strong,  that  opinions  were  much  divided,  and 
the  difficulty  of  legislating  completely  on  the  subject  became 
enormous. 


SECTION  III. — OTHER  PKOPEIETAEY  TENUBES. 

I  have  mentioned  that  revenue-managing  grants  were 
not  always  of  the  rank  or  extent  implied  by  the  title 
Zamindar.  Such  minor  landholders  were  allowed  (by 
sanad  or  otherwise)  an  undefined  position  of  the  same 
kind  but  of  lesser  importance,  and  were  called  taluqdars — 
holders  of  taluqs,  i.  e.  '  dependencies.'  Degrees  of  import- 
ance were  marked  by  the  fact  that  some  were  allowed  to 
pay  direct  to  the  Treasury,  while  others  were  made  to  pay 
through  a  Zamindar. 


§  i.  Taluqddrs. — Holders  of  '  Taluq  Estates! 

Who  were  the  persons  so  recognized?  Some  no  doubt 
were  persons  who  by  ancient  possession,  or  grant  of  the 
Rajas,  or  by  purchase,  had  become  landholders  in  some 
sense,  and  being  recognized  by  the  Muhammadan  governors, 
got  vaguely  entitled  'taluqdars.'  Mr.  Grant  mentions 
that  such  taluqdars  existed  by  royal  grant  in  Bengal  near 


CHAP,  in.]  THE  LAND-TENURES.  525 

Murshidabad  and  Hughli,  and  that  they  were  rich  or 
favoured  persons  who,  desiring  to  be  free  from  the  inter- 
ference of  revenue-agents  and  Zamindars,  obtained  grants 
for  which  they  often  paid  a  consideration  or  fee. 

A  number  of  such  taluqdars  may  have  existed  before  the 
date  of  the  Zamindarf ,  others  arose  as  fragments  of  a  larger 
estate  of  which  the  holders  managed  to  get  themselves 
recognized  as  separate  landholders1.  In  that  case  they  were 
'  independent,' — that  is,  outside  the  Zamindari  estate  of 
anyone, — and  were  called  '  huziiri '  or  'kharija':  (huzuri, 
i.  e.  paying  to  the  huziir  or  headquarter  treasury  ;  '  kharij  ' 
means  outside)2.  But  many  of  the  smaller  taluqs  were 
either  holdings  which  were  not  strong  enough  to  prevent 
their  being  absorbed  into  Zamindaris,  or  else  had  been  tenures 
granted  on  favourable  terms  to  conciliate  influential  per- 
sons,— or  merely  to  save  trouble,  by  the  Zamindar  himself 
or  some  State  official.  These  were  called  'mazkuri,'  or 
'  dependent '  taluqs.  They  paid  their  fixed  revenue  through 
the  Zamindar,  and  were  not  liable  to  many  of  the  inter- 
ferences which  mere  tenants  were  subjected  to.  It  was 
a  question  of  the  facts  and  merits  of  each  case  at  Settle- 
ment, what  taluqs  were  of  one  class  or  the  other.  If  in- 
dependent, they  were  allowed  to  hold  a  separate  Settlement 
and  were  full  proprietors ;  if  dependent,  they  became 
'  tenures  '  under  the  landlord,  however  privileged  in  regard 
to  fixity  of  holding  or  rent.  I  have  already  alluded  to  the 
rules  in  Regulation  VIII  of  1793  (page  411-13)  for  settling 
the  question  whether  the  taluq  was  a  proprietorship  or  an 
under-tenure.  Independent  holdings  were  not  always  large 

1  E.g  in  the  24-Pergunnahs  I  find  the  '  nawara '  estate  in  Jasiir  (Statis- 

it  noticed  that  the  estates  had  been  tical  Account,  vol.  ii.  p.  263  \  This 

much  broken  up  and  portions  sepa-  consisted  of  some  1 1 76  holdings  of 

rated  or  sold,  or  gifted.  When  the  land  (scattered  over  the  district") 

decennial  Settlement  came  on,  all  treated  as  a  sort  of  jagir  in  the 

estates  that  paid  R.  5,000  revenue  Mughal  days,  their  revenue  being 

and  more  were  called  'Zamindaris,'  set  apart  for  the  maintenance  of  a 

and  those  paying  less  were  called  river  fleet.  They  were  not  of  course 

'taluqs.'  (Statistical  Account  of  Bengal,  included  in  any  Zamindari;  the 

vol.  i.  p.  262.)  holders  fell  into  arrears  and  were 

8  A  good  instance  of  the  way  in  sold  up,  and  the  purchasers  became 

which  estates  might  become  'inde-  'independent  taluqdars,'  or  petty 

pendent '  is  afforded  by  the  case  of  proprietors  holding  the  Settlement. 


526  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

ones.  Mr.  Harington  quotes  a  case  in  Bhagalpur  where 
the  headmen  of  villages — '  muqaddams,'  as  they  were  called 
— had  succeeded  in  working  themselves  into  the  position  of 
proprietorship,  and  the  Courts  decided  in  their  favour, 
separating  them  from  the  Zamindaris.  They  were  called 
'  malik-muqaddam '  (proprietary-headman)  and  treated  as 
'  actual  proprietors '  entitled  to  Settlement  under  Sections 
4  and  5  of  Regulation  VIII  of  1793.  Here  the  muqad- 
dams put  forward  '  bills  of  sale '  to  account  for  their  rights, 
while  the  other  side  was  a  Zamindar  who  had  risen  to  this 
rank  from  being  the  '  chaudhari '  of  the  parganas 1. 

It  was  not  always  necessary  that  an  estate  which  hap- 
pened to  be  called  '  taluq  '  in  the  Revenue-language  of  the 
day,  should  be  held  under  a  distinct  grant.  In  the  Fifth 
Report 2  a  curious  account  of  the  Monghyr  district  is  given, 
which  well  illustrates  how  taluqs  might  come  into  exist- 
ence. Tradition  asserted  that  on  the  Emperor  Humayun 
appearing  at  Monghyr  (at  the  time  of  the  Mughal  conquest) 
two  Rajputs,  Hira  Ram  and  Ram  Rai,  obtained  the  appoint- 
ment of  chaudhari  ;  and  they  ultimately  became  Zamindars. 
But  the  possession  was  regarded  as  a  family  right,  and  was 
divided  up,  exactly  on  the  principles  that  any  single  ances- 
tral village  would  be.  '  Ha  veil  Munger,'  as  the  district  was 
then  called,  was  divided  into  eleven  '  tarf '  or  divisions,  for 
five  sons  of  Hira  Ram,  and  six  of  Ram  Rai.  Of  the  latter, 
two  had  passed  out  of  the  family.  Each  of  the  '  tarfs '  was 
further  divided  among  the  descendants  of  each  branch,  and 
the  holdings  formed  so  many  taluq  estates.  Some  of  them 
gradually  passed  into  the  hands  of  other  families.  A 


1  It  is  probable  that  these  '  mu-  '  chaudharis '   or   State    officers,  as 

qaddams '  were  really  minor  chiefs  having  ridden  on  horseback  clad  in 

or  scions  of  families  who  had  once  armour  or  clothed  in  rich  dresses, 

either  ruled  or  had  obtained  '  birts'  till  the  tyranny  of  Sultan 'Ala-ud-din 

or  grants  from  the  Kaja,  and  then,  (fourteenth  century)  reduced  them 

dividing  up  the  estate,  had  come  to  to  being  mere  raiyats.' 
hold  each  one  or  two  or  more  vil-          2  Vol.  i.  pp.  211-14.     The  account 

lages  of  which  they  long  regarded  is   full   of  misprints,   but    is    very 

themselves  as  the  landlords.     The  curious  ;  it  is  followed  by  an  ac- 

judgment  of  the  Court  quotes  Fe-  count   of  the  assessment  and   the 

rishta's   history,  which   alludes  to  various  allowances  to  be  made, 
these  '  muqaddams '  as  well  as  the 


CHAP,  m.]  THE   LAND-TENUEES.  527 

number  of  these  taluqs,  proprietary,  were  formed  into 
separate  estates  as  small  '  Zamindaris.' 

Under  the  head  of  taluq  estates  I  may  also  mention  the 
'  invalid  jagirs '  found  in  this  same  Bhagulpur  district  (see 
Regulation  I  of  1804).  They  were  grants — now  perma- 
nently-settled estates — made  out  of  waste  land  to  pensioned 
or  invalided  soldiers  of  the  Company's  army.  It  is  in- 
teresting to  note  that  at  the  time  the  'Zamfndars'  protested. 
Whether  or  not  these  lands  (in  the  Kalgaon  or  Colgong 
pargana)  were  really  included  in  the  known  limits  of  any 
Zaminddjri  I  cannot  ascertain  ;  but,  on  the  supposition  that 
the  Zamindar  was  a  mere  revenue  collector,  his  protest 
against  the  grant  of  certain  lands  and  their  revenue  (and  of 
course  the  revenue  would  be  deducted  from  any  demand 
made  against  the  Zamindar)  would  be  preposterous. 

In  Chittagong,  as  in  Sylhet  also,  the  nature  of  the 
country  was  unfavourable  to  the  formation  of  large  estates 
which  absorbed  all  the  essentials  of  proprietorship ;  and 
there  we  find  that  the  heads  of  parties  of  settlers  were 
regarded  as  '  actual  proprietors '  though  the  estates  were 
'taluqs.'  But  I  shall  best  describe  the  land  system  of 
Chittagong  in  a  separate  section. 

The  above  are  the  estates — all  known  as  taluqs — such  as 
were  allowed  to  be  proprietary.,  and  therefore  mentioned 
here.  Taluqs  that  were  'dependent,'  and  only  formed 
'tenures'  will  be  dealt  with  further  on:  and  it  will  be 
found  (in  their  case)  the  taluq  is  only  one  of  quite  a 
number  of  local  names. 

This  will  serve  as  a  caution,  and  prevent  confusion  in 
the  mind  of  the  reader. 


SECTION  IV. — LAKHIRAJ  OR  REVENUE-FREE  HOLDINGS. 

We  have  already  noticed,  from  the  Settlement-point  of 
view,  how  the  Collectors  had  to  deal  with  tenures  claimed 
by  persons  who  were,  or  professed  to  be,  grantees  of  land 
free  of  revenue  ;  and  we  found  that  many  of  such  grants 
were  irregular  or  were  wholly  invalid.  We  have  now  to 


528  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  11. 

examine  them  from  the  land-tenure  point  of  view.  In 
early  times  the  grants  could  only  be  made  by  the  Emperor. 
or  by  recommendation  of  a  few  of  the  most  important  local 
authorities ;  in  after-days  all  sorts  of  authorities  used  to 
make  them.  In  speaking  of  the  Settlement,  we  have  already 
seen  how  the  Regulations  dealt  with  these  cases ;  and  that 
rules  were  laid  down  for  testing  the  validity  of  the  royal 
(badshahi)  and  subordinate  authorities  (non-badshahi  or 
hukami)  grants.  Whether  valid  and  left  revenue-free,  or 
invalid  and  therefore  assessed  to  revenue,  the  holders  were 
regarded  as  the  proprietors  of  the  land,  if  that  were  the 
intention  of  the  grant,  as  determined,  in  the  case  of  dispute, 
by  the  Civil  Court.  Whether  it  was  so,  depended  on  the 
circumstances.  For  example,  the  grant  may  have  remitted 
the  revenue  on  a  man's  own  holding,  or  on  land  (unoc- 
cupied) granted  to  the  holder ;  in  that  case,  the  grant  was 
originally  called  'milk'  (ownership  grant),  or  later  'mu'afi,' 
and  constituted  a  clear  form  of  property,  because  the 
Government  had  then  no  concern  with  the  land,  either 
with  the  soil  or  the  revenue  on  it.  But  in  many  cases,  as 
with  jagirs,  it  often  happened  that  the  grant  was  merely 
of  the  revenues  realisable  from  lands  already  held  by  other 
persons  ;  but  even  in  such  cases,  in  the  course  of  time,  the 
grantee  might  have  so  developed  his  position  as  to  become 
virtually  landlord.  A  great  portion  of  the  estate  may  have 
been  waste,  and  by  his  exertions  brought  under  the  plough  ; 
he  may  have  bought  lands,  or  ousted  the  original  holders 
for  default,  and  so  forth. 

As  a  matter  of  fact,  I  believe  I  am  right  in  saying,  that 
in  Bengal  the  '  freehold '  estates  were,  or  had  come  to  be,  all 
or  mostly,  proprietary,  whatever  they  might  once  have 
been.  The  grantee  would  become  landlord  by  the  same 
influences  as  caused  the  growth  of  the  Zamindar. 

§  i.    Jdgirddrs. 

The  institution  of  the  jagir  (jai-gir= place-holder)  was 
essentially  a  Muhammadan  one,  but  was  not  dissimilar  to 


CHAP,  m.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  529 

the  position  occupied  by  Hindu  chiefs  in  frontier  territory. 
In  effect,  when  a  tract  of  country  was  distant  from  head- 
quarters and  troublesome  to  manage,  the  State  would 
appoint  a  jagirdar,  who  would  collect  and  appropriate  the 
revenues,  and  in  return  keep  the  country  in  order  and 
maintain  a  body  of  troops  for  local  or  other  service.  From 
the  Ayin-i-Akbari  we  learn  that  it  was  a  regular  part  of 
the  Mughal  system  to  make  life-grants  of  this  kind  to 
nobles  and  courtiers  for  the  maintenance  of  their  state, 
with  a  more  or  less  nominal  claim  to  service  in  return. 

In  Bengal,  however,  jagirs  were  rare.  Mr.  Grant,  in  1797, 
said  he  only  knew  of  three  or  four.  But  the  old  proprietary 
Hindu  chieftains  were  stronger  in  Bihar,  and  many  jagirs 
were  there  granted,  besides  other  revenue-free  gifts. 

The  jagir  was  originally  only  a  life-grant l.  Hereditary 
nobles  did  not  exist  under  the  Mughal  Empire  ;  the  Em- 
peror made  and  unmade  dignities  at  will.  When  he  wished 
to  confer  a  dignity,  he  appointed  the  person  as  mansabddr 
of  a  certain  rank,  which  was  estimated  according  to  the 
number  of  horsemen  he  commanded ;  the  jagir  was  an 
appanage  to  the  grant  of  a  mansab,  and  the  revenue  was 
appropriated  both  for  the  support  of  the  grantee  and  the 
maintenance  of  his  troops,  which  might  be  from  ten  to  ten 
thousand.  At  first  the  official  forms  of  appointment  were 
minute  and  carefully  followed  out.  Mr.  Shore  gives  a  very 
detailed  account  of  how  the  jagirs  were  granted2.  This 
will  be  found  in  extenso  in  Harington  (chapter  on  Rights  of 
Landholders).  I  have  said  that  at  first  jagirs  were  granted 
only  by  the  Emperor  or  on  recommendation  of  the  governors 
of  the  most  important  of  the  distant  provinces,  as  Kabul, 
Bengal,  and  the  Dakhan.  In  the  times  of  the  decline, 
however,  all  sorts  of  local  governors  granted  them 3. 
Clearly,  under  such  grants,  the  jagirdar  was  not  in  any 

1  Harington,    vol.    iii.    361,   413.  classified,  in  the  State  accounts,  as 
Baillie's  Land-Tax,  xxiv,  xxv.  (i)  available  for  grant  (paibaki),  or 

2  Minute  on  Eights  and  Privileges  of  (2]  charged  with  the  king's  revenues 
Jdffirddrs  (April  and,  1788,  the  same  (khalsa  muqarrari). 

date  as  the  minute  so  often  referred  ;<  Jagirs  were  often  granted  in 
to).  In  the  best  days  of  the  Mughal  mere  notes  addressed  to  the  local 
rule,  the  whole  of  the  districts  were  officials  called  '  tankhwa.' 

VOL.  I.  Mm 


530  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  H. 

sense  proprietor  of  the  land.  Indeed,  he  was  not  allowed 
to  collect  more  from  it  than  the  actual  amount  assigned 
according  to  his  grade  and  the  terms  of  the  sanad  ;  and 
had  to  account  for  all  the  surplus  or  '  tauf  ir.'  In  course  of 
time,  however,  the  precautions  and  rules  fell  into  abeyance, 
and  the  jagirdar  was  allowed  to  do  much  as  he  pleased ; 
and  then  too  it  happened  that  the  grant  was  not  resumed 
on  the  death  of  the  holder,  as  it  ought  to  have  been,  and 
soon  became  hereditary.  In  short,  the  grantee  in  time 
came  to  be  looked  on  as  proprietor,  unless  there  was  any 
holder  on  the  land  strong  enough  to  maintain  his  own  posi- 
tion. The  Regulations  accordingly  declared  that  the  terms 
of  the  grant  should  be  looked  to,  and  that  a  jagir  was  not 
to  be  assumed  to  be  a  life-grant  if  the  intention  appeared 
that  it  should  be  hereditary1, 

§  2.    Other  Grants. — Altamghd;  aimd;  Madad-ma'dsh. 

Besides  the  jagir  grants,  which  were  eventually  connected 
with  military  or  State  service  of  some  kind,  there  were 
several  other  grants  which  involved  the  remission  of  the 
revenue,  and  in  time  came  to  constitute  actual  estates  in 
land.  One  such  revenue-free  grant,  or  rather  an  assignment 
of  the  revenue  of  cultivated  land,  was  called  altamgha — 
grant  by  the  royal  seal  or  stamp  (tamgha).  The  term  was 
applied  to  any  grant  which  was  permanent  and  not  re- 
vocable (except  in  case  of  misconduct 2),  and  therefore 
hereditary.  The  grant  of  the  '  Diwani  '  to  the  East  India 
Company  was  called  an  '  altamgha ' ; 3  where  granted  (as  in 
Bihar)  on  estates  already  in  the  hands  of  a  landholder,  the 
grantee  ousted  the  existing  landlord,  but  felt  obliged  to  pay 
him  '  malikana.'  This  illustrates  what  I  just  now  remarked 
about  the  growth  of  grantees. 

Another  was  the  '  madad-ma'ash ' — which  was  a  '  milk ' 
grant  (i.e.  included  the  soil  ownership).  As  its  name  im- 
plies (help  to  livelihood),  it  was  a  subsistence  grant,  perhaps 

1  See,    for    example,    Section    2,          2  Colebrooke's  Supplement,  p.  238. 
Regulation  XIX,  1793.  3  Phillips,  p.  199. 


CHAP.  III.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  531 

on  condition  of  some  service,  but  ordinarily  to  pious  and 
religious  persons  ;  and  it  was  hereditary.  Mr.  Phillips,  on 
the  authorities  quoted  in  his  note J,  says  the  grant  was  in 
practice  revocable  at  the  will  of  the  sovereign. 

It  was  always  a  proper  thing  to  make  grants  to  Sayyids 
and  holy  or  learned  men  of  family ;  and  the  class  of  grant 
made  for  this  purpose  was,  in  the  official  language  of  the 
Empire,  called  '  suyur-ghal.'  These  grants  were  assign- 
ments of  revenue  only,  not  conditional  on  service,  and 
were  originally  for  life 2.  They  were  made  by  order  or 
'tankhwa,'  and  very  naturally  became  hereditary,  as  the 
son  was  likely  to  follow  the  condition  and  vocation  of  his 
father.  To  the  same  class  belonged  another  kind  of  grant 
known  as  '  aima.'  But  it  seems  that  there  were  '  aima ' 
grants  which  included  the  land  also,  and  then  there  were 
'  milk,'  not  '  suyiir-ghal '  grants.  We  hear  also  of  '  aima ' 
grants  given  with  a  view  to  encourage  the  cultivation  of 
the  waste,  and  these  were  proprietary  grants.  They  were 
sometimes  merely  holdings  at  a  low  or  privileged  rate  of 
revenue  payment,  and  were  then  called  '  malguzari  aima  3.' 

§  3.    Minor  Service  Tenures. 

I  may  include  in  this  section  some  mention  of  a  numerous 
class  of  tenures  which  here  (as  in  other  provinces)  were  either 
wholly  free  from  revenue  charge,  or  else  assessed  at  a  quit- 
rent.  I  allude  to  the  '  chakaran '  lands,  by  which  village 
servants,  the  watchmen,  the  Zamindar's  guards,  and  others, 
were  remunerated.  A  number  of  these  were  petty  grants, 
and  became  subordinate  tenures  under  the  landlord,  but  it 
will  be  well  to  notice  them  here.  They  are  all  conditional 
on  performing  service.  The  nankdr  or  '  bread-lands '  of  the 
Zamindars  were  originally  of  this  kind.  Mr.  Phillips  says 
that  there  were  150,000  petty  officers  of  all  kinds — kanun- 
gos,  headmen,  patwaris,  guards  and  watchmen,  &c.,  remu- 
nerated in  this  way 4.  In  some  cases  the  lands,  though 

1  P.  197.  3  Harington,  ii.  65. 

a  Baillie,  Land-Tax,  xlviii.  *  See  Phillips,  p.  208. 

M  m  2 


532  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

hereditary,  were  not  allowed  to  be  divided;    so  that  the 
person  who  actually  did  the  duty,  enjoyed  the  holding. 

Ghdtwdl  lands  were  holdings  of  this  kind — an  institution 
which  originated  probably  in  the  earliest  times  and  was 
adopted  by  all  classes  of  rulers.  They  were  in  fact  a  kind 
of  jagir  created  in  frontier  territories,  so  that  the  holders 
might  be  '  wardens  of  the  marches.'  In  such  territories 
there  often  were  hill-passes  (hence  the  name  ghdt-wdl),  and 
incursions  were  to  be  feared  from  wild  tribes  inhabiting 
the  hill  country  beyond,  or  from  robbers  who  would  make 
the  inaccessible  jungles  their  haunt.  The  State  granted 
lands  to  be  held  free  on  condition  of  guarding  the  passes. 
In  Bengal  these  holdings  appear  to  have  originated  in 
Birbhum.  They  occur  also  in  Bankura,  Manbhiim,  &C.1, 
and  we  shall  make  a  more  detailed  study  of  them  here- 
after. 


SECTION  V. — PROPRIETARY  TENURES  OF  MODERN  ORIGIN. 

§  i.    Waste  Land  Estates. 

I  have  already  given  the  chief  results  of  the  '  Waste  Land 
Rules,'  and  therefore  here,  in  an  enumeration  of  tenures,  I 
have  only  need  to  recall  the  fact  that  out-and-out  grants, 
whether  with  the  revenue  redeemed  or  not,  may  constitute 
a  class  of  modern  proprietary  tenures.  Many  rights  under 
Waste  Land  Rules,  especially  those  designed  for  petty  cul- 
tivators, as  opposed  to  capitalists,  are  not  proprietary  but 
cultivating  or  lessees'  rights  under  Government. 

§  a.    Proprietary  Tenures  with  reference  to  the  Settlement. 

Connecting  the  various  forms  of  proprietary  rights  in 
land  with  the  different  Settlement  laws,  I  may  briefly 


1  And  Regulation  XXIX  of  1814      ferable  and  heritable,  and  fixing  the 
relates  to   the  Birbhum  '  Ghatwal      rent  in  perpetuity. 
Mahals/  declaring  the  estates  trans- 


CHAP,  m.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  533 

observe  that  any  proprietary  estate  may  be,  according  to 
circumstances — 

(1)  Permanently  settled ; 

(2)  Temporarily  settled,  as    in    Orissa ;    or    in   Bengal, 

wherever  the  original  estate  permanently-settled 
did  not  include  the  land  in  question,  as  in  the 
case  of  excess  waste. 

(3)  Not  settled,  by  reason  of  the  proprietor's  refusal  to 

accept  the  terms  of  Settlement :  here  the  property 
is  not  lost,  but  the  management  is,  for  a  term. 


SECTION  VI.^-'  TENURES.' 
§  i.    How  they  arose. 

I  have  already  explained  that  the  long-continued  rule  of 
the  Muhammadan  power  tended  gradually  to  overlay  and 
ultimately  to  obliterate  the  original  tenures,  with  the 
result  that,  in  process  of  time,  the  chief  proprietary  tenures 
came  to  be  those  of  the  Zamindar,  the  larger  taluqdars, 
jagirdars,  and  grantees,  who,  under  the  terms  of  the  Per- 
manent Settlement  Law,  retained  sufficient  importance  to 
be  called  and  treated  as,  separate  '  actual  proprietors.'  It 
follows  almost  necessarily,  that  there  were  a  number  of 
smaller  tenures, — those  of  headmen  who  had  obtained 
favourable  tenures  of  lands,  of  ancient  holders  of  land,  of 
grantees  who  failed  to  resist  the  absorbing  influence  of  the 
greater  landholders,  but  who  managed  to  retain  a  certain 
degree  of  recognition  as  '  dependent  ta]uqdars,'  or  other- 
wise,— all  of  whom  became  tenure-holders  or  subordinate 
holders  under  the  recognized  landlord.  I  have  also  quoted 
authoritative  opinion  to  show  (what  might  be  expected) 
that  when  once  those  subordinate  holders  descend  to  the 
position  of  tenure-holders,  it  is  impossible  to  draw  any 
hard-and-fast  line  between  them  and  the  persons  who  have 
no  pretension  at  all  to  proprietary  right,  and  are  therefore 
simply  '  tenants.' 

But  every  case  stands  on  its  own  history  and  merits,  and 


534  LAJtt)   SYSTEMS   OF  BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  rr. 

therefore  there  are  special  provisions  of  law  by  which 
persons  having  certain  facts  found  in  their  favour,  are 
1  tenure-holders,'  not  tenants. 

§  2.    Classification  of  ' Tenures' 

A  very  large  class  of  land  interests  in  Bengal  is  repre- 
sented by  the  '  tenures '  of  this  secondary  order.  For  the 
purposes  of  treatment  I  can  best  classify  them  as  (A)  taluqs 
and  other  tenures  of  a  heritable  and  transferable  character, 
with  or  without  absolute  fixity  of  rent ;  these  being  of 
small  area,  or  otherwise  by  their  nature,  were  not  recog- 
nized as  separate,  but  remained  <  dependent '  or  subordinate 
to  some  larger  proprietor.  It  is  impossible  to  separate 
these  accurately,  as  to  origin.  Some  of  them  may  have 
been  distinctly  created  by  the  Zamindar  since  Settlement ; 
others  existed  from  before  that  date.  If  so,  they  are  often 
relics  of  former  proprietary  right.  Even  when  traceable 
to  a  grant  of  some  preceding  Zamindar,  they  yet  may  be 
really  due  to  an  ancient  proprietorship,  which  the  strong 
fetters  of  custom  had  induced  the  Zamindar  to  recognize 
(not  eo  nomine  but)  by  granting  a  '  taluq.' 

(B)  In  a  second  group  I  place  tenures  which  arise  from 
the  desire  of  the  Zamindar  to  improve  his  estate  by  extend- 
ing his  income— the  large  margin  between  the  taxed  revenue 
and  the  possible  rental,— and  at  the  same  time  to  divest 
himself  of  the  trouble  and  responsibility  of  direct  manage- 
ment. But  such  farming-tenures  are  not  only  due  to  the 
desire  to  save  trouble,  they  are  often  advantageous  when 
the  landlord  has  no  taste  or  capacity  for  estate  manage- 
ment, and  the  employment  of  an  energetic  lessee  will 
develop  the  capabilities  of  the  estate. 

When  the  farming-lessee  manages  well,  he  secures  ex- 
tended cultivation,  founds  new  villages,  and  otherwise 
increases  the  rental  (very  harshly,  it  is  feared,  in  some 
cases) ;  and  that  being  so,  the  margin  between  his  contract 
sum  with  the  Zamindar  and  the  collections  becomes  so  large, 
that  he  can  afford,  as  time  goes  on,  to  retire  and  to  be  con- 


CHAP,  m.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  535 

tent  with  a  portion ;  he  therefore,  in  his  turn,  gives  up  the 
trouble  of  management,  and  subleases  to  another  contractor. 
More  frequently,  however,  when  there  is  much  waste,  the 
lessee  is  unable  to  bring  the  whole  under  cultivation,  and 
so  he  sub-farms  a  portion  with  a  view  to  more  rapid  ex- 
tension of  cultivation.  In  any  case  it  often  happens  that 
the  sub-lessee  shares  his  liability  with  another,  and  yet 
another  '  sub-sub-lessee.'  This  is  what  is  meant  by  the 
'  sub-infeudation '  spoken  of  in  revenue  reports. 

(C)  A  third  and  important  class  of  tenures  has  arisen — 
especially  in  Eastern  Bengal  and  in  the  districts  containing 
'  Sundarban  '  tracts — out  of  grants  and  contracts  (sometimes 
antecedent  to  the  year  1793),  for  clearing  and  reclaiming 
the  waste.     In  the  native  mind,  first  clearing  of  the  waste 
gives  one  of  the  strongest  titles  to  permanent  right  in  the 
cultivation,  and  it  is  not  surprising  that  this  sentiment 
should  have  given  rise  to  many  tenures,  with  (as  usual) 
tenures  under  them  created  by  '  sub-infeudation.' 

(D)  Lastly,  as  we  find  '  lakhiraj  '  (revenue-free]  rights 
giving  rise  to  estates  of  the  first  or  proprietary  order,  so 
in  the  same  way  less  important  rent-free  holdings,  though 
remaining  included  within  proprietary  estates,  have  become 
'  tenures '  of  essentially  the  same  origin.     Village  service 
grants,  and   especially   grants   in   aid    of  temple-worship 
and  for  the  support  of  holy  men,  represent  this  familiar 
class. 


§  3.  Absence  of  the  Sub-proprietor  or  '  Proprietor  of  the 
holding'  found  in  other  Provinces. 

It  will  be  noticed  that  in  Bengal  we  have  nothing  of  the 
'  (sub-  or)  under-proprietor,'  the  man  who  is  complete  owner 
as  far  as  his  personal  holding  is  concerned,  but 'has  no 
interest  in  the  general  profits  of  the  estate.  There  is 
nothing  like  the  '  malik-maqbuza '  of  Upper  or  Central 
India,  in  theory ;  though  where  a  tenure-holder  has  a  fixed 
rent,  his  position  is,  qua  his  holding,  about  as  good  as  a 
separate  proprietorship  ;  especially  when,  by  registration  or 


536  LAND  SYSTEMS    OF  BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

otherwise,  his  tenure  is  protected  from  being  annulled  on 
the  sale  of  the  superior  estate  for  revenue  arrears. 

§  4.  Difficulty  of  separating  '  Tenures.' 

The  terms  adopted  are  '  tenure-holder '  (or  sometimes 
in  books)  under-tenure-holder.'  It  will  be  interesting 
to  the  student  here  to  turn  to  the  Acts  and  compare 
the  definition  of  '  tenure '  in  the  Recovery  of  Arrears 
Act  (B.  VII  of  1868),  and  in  Section  5,  clause  I,  of  the 
Tenancy  Act,  1885.  But  here  I  must  add  a  word  of 
apology.  In  dividing  rights  into  tenures  and  raiyafs 
tenancies,  it  is  hardly  possible  to  escape  the  criticism 
that  some  rights  which  I  have  treated  as  tenures, 
ought  to  be  regarded  rather  as  occupancy-tenancies.  I 
believe  that  absolute  accuracy  in  drawing  a  line  between 
the  two  is  unattainable.  The  framers  of  the  Act  have  not 
pretended  that  their  definition  is  exhaustive.  The  Com- 
mission said  that  it  was  impossible  '  to  discover  any  prin- 
ciple of  distinction  between  raiyats  and  tenure-holders  or 
under-tenure-holders,  which  will  hold  good  universally  or 
even  in  a  large  majority  of  cases1.'  Actual  cultivation  is 
not  a  test,  for  a  tenure-holder  (like  a  small  proprietor)  may 
cultivate  the  fields  himself,  while  a  '  tenant'  may  have  sub- 
let the  whole  holding.  The  same  would  apply  to  the  act  of 
'  receiving  rents ' — the  tenure-holder  may  be  receiving  rent 
from  a  sub-lessee  in  actual  occupation.  So  some  tenant 
rights  are  heritable,  as  much  as  in  a  tenure.  Some  tenant 
rights  are  also  transferable,  and  saleable  in  execution  of  a 
decree  for  arrears.  It  is  equally  impossible  to  refer  to  the 
amount  of  rent  payable,  for  some  tenures  are  extremely 
petty,  and  some  raiyat  holdings  pay  considerable  sums. 
Act  vin  The  Act,  however,  has  given  some  assistance  by  enacting  that 
sec  5ci  l°cal  custom  and  the  purpose  for  which  the  right  was  origin - 
4?  5-  ally  acquired,  have  to  be  looked  to,  and  that  where  the 

holding  exceeds  100  bighas  (Bengal  standard),  the  legal  pre- 
sumption is  that  it  is  a  tenure  till  the  contrary  is  shown. 

1  The  whole  passage  may  be  read  at  page  23  of  R.  and  F.  Tenancy  Act. 


CHAP.  III.] 


THE    LAND-TENTJBES. 


537 


In  these  pages  I  shall  follow  the  Act  in  treating  all 
persons  under  the  proprietor  as  equally  '  tenants '  in  class. 
But,  to  avoid  confusion,  we  describe  separately  the  '  tenure- 
holders  '  and  the  raiyats  1.  The  distinction  is  of  some  im- 
portance, because  tenure-holders  are  only  liable  to  enhance- 
ment of  their  rent  under  very  limited  circumstances,  which 
will  be  noticed  hereafter.  The  tenure  may  be  also  per- 
manent by  law  or  by  contract  (as  the  case  may  be),  and  if 
permanent  it  is  transferable  and  can  be  bequeathed  like  any 
other  immoveable  property,  subject  to  certain  provisions  of 
the  law. 

§  5.  Remarks  on  the  variety  of  local  names  for  Tenures 
of  the  same  kind. 

One  other  difficulty  remains  to  be  noted,  and  that  is  the 
tendency  to  give  different  names  to  tenures  and  forms  of 
lease,  although  there  is  really  nothing  essentially  different. 
In  so  far  as  the  variety  is  due  to  locality  and  change  of 
dialect,  it  is  of  course  not  to  be  wondered  at.  What  is 
called  ' jot '  in  Kangpur  may  be  called  '  ganthi '  in  Jessore, 
and  so  forth.  But  it  will  often  be  observed  that  in  an 
elementary  stage  of  civilization,  languages  are  as  rich  in 
terms  distinguishing  things  that  need  no  such  discrimina- 
tion, as  they  are  poor  in  terms  for  things  and  for  con- 
ceptions that  really  do  differ.  In  English,  for  example,  we 
are  contented  with  one  word  '  bracelet '  for  all  ornaments 
of  that  class ;  or  one  word  '  earring '  for  any  ornament  for 
the  ear.  Not  so  in  the  vernacular  dialects  ;  there  are  dozens 
of  words  for  each  kind  and  shape  of  bracelet  or  earring ; — 
the  pattern  of  ornamentation,  or  the  number  of  stones  set, 
often  sufficing  to  alter  the  name  of  the  article.  And  so  it 


1  In  a  case  reported  in  Calcutta 
Law  Reports,  IX.  449,  the  Court  said : 
'  The  only  test  of  a  raiyat's  interest 
is  to  see  in  what  condition  the  land 
was  when  the  tenancy  was  created. 
If  raiyats  were  already  in  possession 
of  the  land,  and  the  interest  created 
was  a  right,  not  to  the  actual  phy- 
sical possession  of  the  land,  but  to 
collect  the  rents  from  the  raiyats, 


the  interest  is  not  raiyati  (in  other 
words  it  is  a  'tenure').  It  is  un- 
fortunate that  the  use  of  the  words 
'  tenure,'  '  a  tenure/  &c.,  is  not  uni- 
form or  precise  in  judgments  and 
references.  There  is  no  remedy  : 
all  we  can  do  here  is  to  adopt  the 
language  of  the  Act  and  adhere 
to  it. 


538  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

is  with  tenures:  a  slight  difference  in  the  conditions  of 
holding,  in  the  rate  or  method  of  rent-payment,  or  in  the 
fact  that  the  area  is  measured  or  not,  will  give  rise  to  a  new 
name,  as  if  the  tenure  itself  were  different.  This  gives  at 
first  sight  an  air  of  mystery  and  complexity  to  Bengal 
'  tenures '  which  they  do  not  really  possess l. 

(A)  TENURES  DERIVED  FROM  ANCIENT  RIGHTS. 

§  6.  Dependent  Taluqs. 

As  all  the  estates  separated  at  the  Permanent  Settlement 
from  Zamindaris  and  originally  called  taluqs  (huzuri  or 
kharija2)  are  now  landlord  estates,  the  term  'taluq'  at  the 
present  day  is  a  restricted  term,  very  vague,  but  always 
implying  a  subordinate  tenure.  In  popular  language,  such 
a  '  taluqdar '  is  said  to  be  '  shiknii '  (shikm,  the  belly — one 
within  the  other). 

The  tenure  may  be  under  a  private  proprietor,  or,  as  in 
the  taluqs  of  Eastern  Bengal,  may  be  under  Government 
itself  as  proprietor. 

Those  dependant  taluqs  which  have  been  in  existence 
from  the  time  of  the  Permanent  Settlement,  are  not  liable  to 
be  cancelled  if  the  estate  to  which  they  are  subordinate  is 
sold  for  the  recovery  of  arrears  of  revenue.  They  are  herit- 
able and  transferable.  The  rent  at  which  they  are  held 
cannot  be  enhanced  except  upon  proof3  (i)  of  a  special 
right  by  custom  to  enhance,  or  (2)  of  a  right  appearing 
from  the  conditions  of  the  grant,  or  (3)  that  the  taluqdar, 
by  accepting  abatements,  has  (impliedly)  subjected  himself 
to  increase  ; — if  the  lands  are  capable  of  affording  it.  If  the 
rent  has  never  been  changed  since  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment, it  cannot  now  be  enhanced  ;  and  in  order  to  relieve 

1  For  example,  in  Tipperah  I  find  '  muqarrari,'  '  qaimi,'  &c. — all  these 
about   sixty  names  for  tenures  or  words  signifying,  not  any  real  differ- 
under- tenures  in  proprietary  estates;  ence  of  kind,  but  some  incidental 
one  of  these  kinds — the  taluq — is  condition   or  feature   attaching   to 
distinguished  as 'mushakhsi'  (lump-  the  terms  of  the  tenure, 
rent  for  the  whole),  Hakhsisi '  (par-  a  See  pp.  411-13. 
ticularizing     rents),     '  chauhaddi,'  s  See  Tenancy  Act,  1885,  chapter  iii. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  539 

the  tenure-holder  to  some  extent  from  the  difficulty  of 
giving  proof  extending  over  a  period  of  so  many  years,  the 
law  provides  that  if  it  be  proved  that  the  rent  has  not  been 
changed  for  tiventy  years,  it  shall  be  presumed,  until  the 
contrary  be  shown,  that  the  tenure  has  been  held  at  the 
same  rent  since  the  Permanent  Settlement. 

§  7.  Guzdslita  holdings. 

Among  taluqs  which  represent  a  vestige  of  old  proprietary 
right,  I  mentioned  as  a  characteristic  example,  those  known 
as  'guzashta  jot'  in  the  Shahabad  district.  It  is  not  neces- 
sary now  to  allude  to  the  difference  of  opinion  that  once 
existed,  for  there  can  hardly  be  a  reasonable  doubt  that 
the  term  'guzashta,'  which  (in  Persian)  indicates  something 
'  lost '  or  '  passed  away,'  refers  to  a  proprietary  right  once 
held.  Most  of  Bihar,  as  already  stated,  was  held  by  small 
proprietors,  who  were  descendants  of  military  retainers  and 
minor  chiefs  under  the  old  Hindu  kings  ;  in  many  cases 
one  of  the  family  (or  perhaps  more  than  one  jointly)  suc- 
ceeded in  getting  recognized  at  the  Permanent  Settlement ; 
or  else  were  found  to  have  lost  all  their  rights,  except  the 
malikana  payment l.  In  Shahabad,  landlords  of  this  class 
were  found  too  strong  to  be  put  aside  with  a  mere  malikana 
allowance,  and  yet  (from  causes  which  we  cannot  now 
ascertain)  were  not  considered  entitled  to  an  independent 
Settlement.  They  were  placed  under  the  great  Zamindar 
of  Dumraon,  but  so  as  to  become  tenure-holders  at  fixed 
rates ;  and  this  is  now  their  true  position :  they  are  not 
mere  occupancy  raiyats 2.  It  is  quite  clear  that  their 
position  has  nothing  to  do  with  any  artificial  rule  under 
Act  X  of  1859,  or  any  other  law  creating  occupancy 
rights. 

1  In  this  fact  the  reader  will  re-  the  ancient  title,  and  he  pays  mdli- 
cognize  another  proof  of  the  strength  kdna  accordingly, 
of  those  old  claims  by  virtue  of  con-  2  Cotton's  Memorandum  on  Tenures, 
quest,  which  the  descendants  of  the  and   Board's  Letter  to  Government   of 
chiefs    call    '  birthright.'      Though  Bengal,  No.  1024  A,  dated  22nd  Do- 
overridden,  the  incoming  landlord  cember,  1883. 
is  obliged  to  give  some  recognition  to 


540  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

§  8.  Fixed-rent  Tenures. 

Under  this  class  I  may  consider  the  '  istimrari,'  the  '  mu- 
qarrari,'  and  '  mauriisi '  tenures  existing  from  before  the 
Permanent  Settlement.  These  Persian  names  have  been 
noticed  before :  they  give  no  clue  to  origin,  and  only 
describe  certain  incidental  features  ;  but  it  may  be  reason- 
ably supposed  that  they  originated  in  some  closer  and 
hereditary  connection  with  the  land,  either  independent  of 
any  contract  with  the  Zamindar,  or  such  as  to  have  won 
recognition  in  the  shape  of  a  special  lease  or  tenure  from 
the  local  authorities. 

Properly  speaking,  '  istimrari '  refers  to  the  stable  or  per- 
petual nature  of  the  tenure,  which  is  not  voidable  when  the 
estate  is  sold  for  arrears.  '  Muqarrari '  refers  to  the  rent 
being  'fixed';  and  a  tenure  might  be  either  istimrdri  or 
muqarrari,  or,  more  commonly,  both.  '  Maurusi '  merely 
means  that  the  tenure  is  hereditary,  and  implies  nothing 
about  the  fixity  of  rent.  '  Miras  l '  leases  (miras  is  only 
another  grammatical  form  from  the  same  root  as  maur&si) 
are  also  found  in  Dacca  and  Eastern  Bengal. 

When  such  tenures  are  of  modern  creation,  they  are 
sometimes  found  to  have  been  created  in  favour  of  relatives 
of  the  landlord's  family,  or  to  settle  old  claims  by  way  of 
compromise 2. 

In  Rangpur  and  the  adjacent  Kiich  Bihar  territory,  a 
tenure  of  this  class  called  '  upanchaki '  is  found ;  it  is  a 
perpetual  holding  for  religious  services  at  a  small  rent. 

The  '  upanchaki '  tenure  of  Rangpur  is  said  to  be  the 
creation  of  the  Zamindar,  and  is  the  collective  name  for 
lands  granted  for  the  worship  of  deities,  the  keeping  of 
lamps  at  shrines,  &c.,  &c.,  under  the  well-known  names  of 
debottar,  pirpal,  chiraghi,  shibottar  (see  p.  542).  They  pay 

1  We  shall  again  notice  the  term  istimrari    tenures   to   ghatwals  (p. 
*  miras '  in  Sylhet,  and  in  other  parts  532)  under  him,  in  order  to  settle 
of  Bengal.  a  dispute  ;  and  he  revoked  the  con- 

2  Mr.  Cotton  mentions  that  Eaja  dition  of  service,  which  of  course 
Silanand      Singh,     of     Bhagalpur,  attached  to   the  ghdtwcU  tenure   as 
granted  a   number   of   muqarrari-  such. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  541 

a  nominal  quit-rent  [perhaps  connected  with  the  '  fifth ' 
(panchak)  of  the  produce],  are  hereditary  and  transferable. 
If  liable  (rarely)  to  enhancement  of  rent,  they  are  distin- 
guished as  'niajkuri1.' 

In  the  Bhagalpur  division  I  find  references  to  a  tenure 
called  '  ghorabandi  V 

In  not  a  few  districts  I  find  mention  of  a  great  variety  of 
'  taluqs '  and  '  mirasi '  (hereditary)  tenures,  distinguished  by 
various  names,  which,  however,  mean  nothing  more  than 
that  there  is  some  condition  attached  to  their  recognition 
by  the  landlord,  or  some  special  feature  in  their  origin  or 
terms. 

In  Tipperah,  for  instance,  there  is  the  'zimma-miras,' which 
means  a  tenure  held  originally  by  one  person  but  made 
over  in  charge  (zimma)  to  another ;  the  '  az-musbakhsi 
mirds'  or  '  specific,'  is  a  tenure  recognized  after  measurement 
and  assessment.  There  are  also  many  tenures  compounded 
with  the  now  familiar  term  taluq ;  e.  g.  there  is  the 
'  takhsisi,'  which  means  that  the  landlord  has  reserved  the 
right  to  test  and  measure  the  area  and  reassess  it  at  some 
future  time.  '  Tashkhisi,'  again,  means  a  taluq  recognized 
after  measurement.  '  Bandobasti '  taluq,  is  one  granted 
after  measurement  and  making  out  an  account  of  expenses, 
allowance  for '  malikana/  &c.,  and  determining  the  resulting 
payment  as  rent. 

All  these  details  sound  very  complicated,  but  in  reality 
indicate  nothing  that  affects  the  nature  of  the  tenure.  To 
recur  to  the  illustration  already  used  (p.  537)  of  the 
variety  of  native  terms  for  ornaments  of  different  forms, 
these  separately-named  tenures  are  on  the  same  footing. 
They  are  really  no  more  difficult  to  understand,  than  would 
be  the  case  if  our  language  used  a  separate  name  for  a  lease 
with  repairs  and  for  a  lease  without  repairs,  or  a  lease  ter- 
minable with  notice,  and  a  lease  for  a  fixed  period. 

1  Statistical  Account  of  Bengal,  vol.  a  definite  area,  whether  cultivated 

vii.  p.  278.  or  not  ;  but  it  is  not  enumerated  in 

4  It  is  stated  that  this  means  a  the  Statistical  Account  of  Bengal  (vol. 

tenure  where  the  rent  is  payable  for  xiv)  as  a  '  tenure.' 


542  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

§  9.  Rent-free  Tenures. 

Just  as  Government  has  created  certain  revenue-free 
estates,  so  the  landlords  have  in  turn  allowed  certain  rent- 
free  tenures,  known  as  '  brahmottar,'  '  shibottar,'  '  debottar,' 
'  piruttar,'  and  '  hazratdargah,'  &c.,  i.  e.  lands  devoted  to  the 
worship  of  the  deities,  or  to  that  of  a  saint  (pir).  They  call 
for  no  special  remark.  In  the  same  way  some  service 
tenures  (chakdran)  may  exist  under  the  Zamindars.  Espe- 
cially these  will  be  noticed  in  the  Santal  Pergunnah, 
Chutiya  Nagpur,  the  Bardwan  division,  and  in  the  Rang- 
pur  district J. 


(B)  TENUEES  DUE  TO  THE  DESIEE  OF  BEING 
BELIEVED  OF  DIRECT  MANAGEMENT. 

§  10.   Origin  of  the  Class. 

These  tenures  are  due  partly  to  the  desire  of  improving 
the  estates  by  handing  them  over  to  the  more  energetic 
management  which  a  lessee  would  give,  and  partly  to  the 
effect  of  prosperity  and  the  desire  to  be  saved  trouble.  In 
either  case  a  time  came  when  the  landlords  began  to  create 
permanent  subordinate-tenures  ;  by  this  means  they  escaped 
not  only  the  labour  and  risks  attendant  upon  direct  manage- 
ment, but  were  successful  in  bringing  large  tracts  of  waste 
land  under  cultivation.  Many  a  Zamindar,  who  had  no 
taste  for  estate  management,  or  had  more  land  than  he 
could  manage,  would  by  a  well-considered  farm,  or  sub- 
lease, greatly  improve  his  income.  Considerable  portions 
of  estates  have  been  thus  conveyed,  in  perpetuity,  by 
Zamindars  in  consideration  of  a  bonus  paid  down  and  of 
a  fixed  annual  rent.  This  rent  is  calculated  so  as  to 
leave  to  the  lessee  a  margin  of  profit  over  and  above  the 
sum  payable  to  the  Zamindar  and  the  revenue  payable  to 

1  The  Deputy-Collector  mentions      grants  of  this  class   (see   Statistical 
that  most   of  the.    Zamindars    re-      Account,  vol.  vii.  p.  283). 
munerate  village  servants  by  small 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENTJEES.  543 

Government — a  margin  which  it  depends  on  the  lessee's 
skill  and  ability  to  make  more  and  more  considerable 1. 


§  ii.  The  Paint2. 

The  commonest  tenure  of  this  kind  is  now  the  '  pattani,' 
or  patni-taluq,  as  it  is  usually  written.  At  first  under  the 
Regulations, — for  fear  of  endangering  the  power  of  paying 
the  land-revenue, — the  Zamindars  had  been  prohibited 
from  giving  any  lease  for  longer  than  ten  years.  This 
provision  was  rescinded  in  1812;  and  gradually  the  prac- 
tice of  granting  long  (or  perpetual)  managing  leases  or 
farms,  called  patni,  became  so  common,  that  it  was  not 
only  legalized  by  Regulation  VIII  of  1819,  but  special  pro- 
visions were  made  regarding  it.  The  patni  itself  can  be 
protected  by  registration  (as  will  presently  be  explained) 
from  being  dissolved,  should  the  Zamindar  fall  into  arrears 
to  Government. 

A  patni-taluq  is  heritable  and  transferable,  and  all  the 
rights  of  the  Zamindar  are  transferred  by  the  grant.  It  is 
held  at  a  rent  fixed  in  perpetuity.  The  holder  is  required 
to  furnish  collateral  security  for  payment,  and  for  his  conduct 
generally,  though  he  may  be  excused  from  this  obligation  at 
the  Zamindar's  discretion.  But  even  if  the  original  holder  is 
excused,  the  Zamindar  may  require  this  security  from  any 

1  Sometimes  the  creation  of  such  disabled  himself  from  paying  the 
farms  has  been  the  greatest  benefit  revenue.  Fifty-two  of  these  taluqs 
to  the  estate  :  sometimes  it  is  the  are  now  recognized  as  valid. — (Sta- 
resource  of  mere  laziness,  and  of  a  tistical  Account,  vol.  vi.  p.  401.) 
device  to  procure  money  at  almost  2  Whence  the  patni  derives  its 
any  sacrifice.  Thus,  for  example,  name  is  uncertain.  Wilson  inclines 
Government  became  the  purchaser  to  connect  it  with  '  patta,'  a  lease, 
(for  arrears)  of  fractional  shares  in  Had  the  land  been  usually  waste,  it 
the  Bardhakat  estate  of  Tipperah  would  have  been  natural  to  suggest 
district  (first,  the  '8-anna  share'  the  Bengali  word  patten — colonizing 
was  sold,  and  then  a  '  2-anna,-i3  or  founding.  Harington  (vol.  iii. 
ganda,-i  kara,-i  kranti' share).  The  519)  says  it  means  'established  or 
details  of  the  former  management  settled,'  but  gives  no  word  in  the 
soon  came  out.  The  default  had  in  vernacular  ;  and  Wilson  remarks 
fact  resulted  from  the  fact  that  the  that  the  term  originated  in  the 
Zamindar,  to  raise  ready  money,  had  estate  of  the  Zamindar  of  Bard- 
sold  so  many  taluqs  or  under-farms  wan,  and  soon  became  common  in 
for  '  salami '  or  fees  paid  down  other  districts.  The  meaning  is 
(which  he  squandered),  that  he  had  questionable. 


544  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

new  holder  introduced  by  private  transfer  (by  sub-infeuda- 
tion  as  it  is  called),  or  by  purchase  at  a  sale  of  the  patni 
for  arrears  due  under  it.  A  patni-taluq  is  liable  to  sum- 
mary sale,  upon  application  to  the  Collector,  if  the  rent  is 
not  paid ;  and  this  is  allowed  to  be  due  twice  in  the  year. 
The  effect  of  sale  is  similar  to  that  of  a  revenue-paying 
estate ;  inasmuch  as  all  leases  granted  and  incumbrances 
created  by  the  defaulting  patniddr  are  voidable  by  the 
purchaser,  who  is  entitled  to  take  the  estate  in  the  condition 
in  which  it  was  at  the  original  creation  of  the  patni. 
Persons  whose  interests  might  suffer  in  this  way  by  a  sale, 
are  authorized  to  protect  themselves  by  paying  up  the  rent 
due  by  the  defaulting  patniddr,  and  on  doing  so  can  claim 
to  be  put  in  possession  of  the  patni  tenure  in  order  to 
recoup  themselves.  If  they  do  not  take  this  course,  and 
the  patni  tenure  is  sold,  they  can  only  claim  to  be  com- 
pensated out  of  any  surplus  which  remains  from  the  sale- 
proceeds  after  satisfying  the  rent  due  to  the  Zamindar.  If 
they  are  unable  to  obtain  compensation  in  this  way,  they 
may  bring  an  action  for  damages 1. 


§  12.  Sub-letting,  or  '  Subinfeudation.' 

The  margin  left  to  the  patnidar  is  often  so  considerable 
— that  is  to  say,  the  capability  of  the  estates  for  improve- 
ment is  such — that  the  patnidar  can  again  divest  himself 
of  the  management,  and  content  himself  with  a  fixed  sum, 
sub-letting  the  actual  rental  to  persons  who  are  called 
'  darpatniddr  '  or  '  darpatni-taluqdar.'  This  is,  however, 
often  done,  not  to  save  trouble,  but  simply  because  if  there 
is  much  waste,  the  charge  may  be  more  than  the  original 
farm-holder  can  manage  :  and  he  at  once  sees  the  advantage 
of  giving  out  waste  portions,  or  outlying  blocks,  to  a  sub- 
lessee. 

And  another  special  feature  in  this  tenure  has  to  be  noticed. 
It  is  not  only  the  whole  or  some  specific  lands  forming  part 

1  For  this  account  of  the  patni  I  am  indebted  to  Mr.  J.  S.  Cotton,  C.S. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENUKES.  545 

of  the  estate  that  are  thus  sub-let ;  often  a  fractional  share 
of  the  whole  estate  (or  of  the  first  tenure)  regarded  as  an 
undivided  unit,  is  thus  granted. 
Mr.  Cotton  writes  : — 

'These  [dar-patnls  or  sub-farms]  again  are  sometimes  similarly 
under-let  to  se-patnidars ;  and  the  sub-letting  in  some  instances 
has  continued  several  degrees  lower.  In  some  places  there 
are  now  as  many  as  a  dozen  gradations  between  the  Zamindar  at 
the  top  and  the  cultivator  of  the  soil  at  the  bottom.  In  these 
alienations,  the  proprietors,  as  a  rule,  have  made  excellent 
terms  for  themselves.  It  rarely  happens  that  a  patni  is  sub-let 
otherwise  than  on  payment  of  a  bonus  which  discounts  the 
contingency  of  many  years'  increased  rents.  The  descendants 
of  the  grantor  suffer  by  this  arrangement ;  because  it  is  clear 
that,  if  the  bonus  were  not  exacted,  a  higher  rental  could  be 
permanently  obtained  from  the  land.  This  circumstance  has 
not,  however,  had  much  practical  weight  with  landholders. 
And  if  the  wide  diffusion  of  the  profits  from  land  is  in  itself 
a  desirable  thing  in  the  interests  of  the  community,  the  selfish- 
ness of  the  landholding  class  is  not,  in  this  instance  of  it, 
a  subject  for  regret.  In  one  respect,  however,  the  cultivators  of 
the  soil  undeniably  are  placed  at  a  disadvantage  by  the  practice 
of  sub-letting ;  for  it  is  a  peculiarity  of  the  system  that, 
although  these  tenures  and  sub-tenures  often  comprise  defined 
tracts  of  land,  a  common  custom  is  to  sub-let  certain  aliquot 
$hares  of  the  whole  superior  tenure,  and  in  consequence  the 
tenants  in  any  particular  village  of  an  estate  are  often  required 
to  pay  their  rents  to  two  or  more  than  two,  and  often  to  many 
different  landlords  [tenure-holders].  The  desirability  of  cor- 
recting this  state  of  things,  so  productive  of  confusion  and  of 
hardship  to  the  rent-payers,  is  admitted,  but  it  is  not  easy  to 
find  a  remedy.  The  extent  to  which  sub-infeudation  has  been 
carried  in  some  parts  of  the  country,  the  minute  subdivision  of 
shares1  which  exists  in  other  parts,  the  claims  of  individual 
shareholders  on  the  raiyats  for  personal  service  and  consider- 
ation, and,  most  of  all,  the  too  common  feuds  and  jealousies 
of  copartners,  while  they  are  the  main  causes  of  the  difficulty, 

1  In  the  estate  of  Katalipara,  in  whom  is  in  possession  of  an  in- 
the  district  of  Faridpur,  there  are  finitesimal  interest  in  the  property. 
no  less  than  500  sharers,  each  of 

VOL.  I.  N  n 


546  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BBITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

are  at  the  same  time  insurmountable  obstacles  to  the  introduc- 
tion of  any  scheme  having  for  its  object  to  induce  or  compel 
joint-proprietors  [tenure-holders]  to  act  in  concert. 

'  The  enormous  number  of  permanent  holdings  now  existing 
in  Bengal  is  due  to  the  practice  of  sub-letting.  The  total 
number  of  perpetual  leases  registered  in  the  offices  of  the 
Registration  Department  during  the  past  fifteen  years,  is 
1,221,417.  More  than  half  of  this  almost  incredible  number 
is  furnished  by  the  three  districts  of  Jessore  (273,892),  Backer- 
gunge  (192,514),  and  Chittagong  (230,795).  The  gradual 
accession  to  the  wealth  and  influence  of  small  proprietors, 
almost  all  of  whom  are  themselves  cultivators,  induced  by  this 
wide  dissemination  of  a  permanent  interest  in  landed  property, 
is  evidenced  by  the  comparative  material  prosperity  of  these 
districts.' 

§  13.    Temporary  Leases. 

I  do  not  propose  to  regard  as  tenures  mere  temporary 
agreements  for  a  five  years'  lease  or  more.  In  the  Bihar 
districts,  where  there  are  small  landowners,  there  is  no 
general  creation  of  patnis  or  permanent  sub-tenures,  but 
a  host  of  temporary  farms,  contracts,  and  leases,  called 
'  ijara,'  or  '  thika,'  or  '  mustajiri.'  A  farm  of  a  farm  is  called 
'  katkina.'  A  '  zar-i-peshgi '  ('  money  in  advance ')  lease  is 
common  in  parts  :  it  is  a  grant  of  the  rent- collections,  either 
against  an  advance  made  at  the  time,  or  by  way  of  repay- 
ing a  debt  already  incurred1.  The  analogy  of  such  con- 
tracts to  tenures  is  obvious,  but  they  are  not  tenures  in  the 
legal  sense. 

1  Mr.    Cotton    notices    a   curious  or  rent  farmer).     These  lessees  had 

case  of  an  estate  (in  the  Kishnganj  divided  their  circles  into  sections 

Subdivision  of  Parniya)  which  came  or   '  qismat,'  and  let  them  out  to 

under  the  management  of  the  Court  sub-lessees  called  '  malguzar.'     The 

of  Wards  in  1874.    The  owners  had  qismat  might   again  be  subdivided 

let  the  whole  estate  out  in  circles,  into  parts  less  than  a  whole  village, 

which  they  called  taluqas,  on  five  and  called  '  gach,'  held  by  a  '  gach- 

years'  leases.     Each  circle  or  taluqa  dar '  or  abadkar.     This  last  would 

contained  several  villages,  and  the  usually  cultivate  himself  or  by  hired 

lessee  was   called   '  mustajir '    (the  labour,  but  even  he  will  sometimes 

common  Persian  term  for  a  revenue  once  more  sub-let  to  a  '  kulait.' 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  547 


(C)   WASTE-CLEARING  OR  JANGALBURI  TENURES, 

We  have  seen  already  that  from  the  days  of  Maim,  the 
Hindu  custom  has  always  respected  the  title  of  him  who 
'  first  cleared  the  jungle.'  Instances  of  this  will  continually 
occur  in  the  land-tenures  of  almost  every  province.  On  the 
one  hand,  the  rulers  were  naturally  inclined  to  encourage 
such  work,  as  it  enlarged  their  revenue,  and  accordingly 
they — even  the  worst — afforded  protection  and  favourable 
rates  of  rent  or  revenue  payment  to  the  '  abadkar  '  (settler) 
on  the  waste ;  on  the  other,  the  sentiment  of  the  people 
conceded  to  him  a  right  in  the  holding  of  a  permanent 
character1.  A  number  of  the-taluq  or  tenure  rights  which 
we  have  been  examining  may  very  possibly  have  had  their 
origin  in  rights  connected  with  village-founding  and  clear- 
ance, though  it  is  not  so  expressed,  and  they  may  have  been 
wrongly  classified  in  my  account :  if  so,  it  will  not  really 
make  much  difference.  But  in  this  section  we  are  con- 
cerned with  those  tenures  which  are  professedly  created  on 
this  basis  only.  They  are  all  distinguished  by  locally 
different  names,  and  there  are,  as  usual,  separate  terms 
which  indicate  differences  in  the  rate  of  rent,  or  the  con- 
ditions of  holding,  which,  while  making  these  tenures 
apparently  complicated  and  multifarious,  do  not  really 
show  any  fundamental  or  structural  distinctions. 

The  commonest  terms  indicating  this  kind  of  tenure  are 
'  jot 2 '  in  East  Jessore,  Rangpur,  Jalpaiguri  W.  and  the 
Dwars  ;  '  ganthi '  in  Jessore  and  the  24-Pergunnahs ; 
'  hawala '  (often  written  and  pronounced  hawala  or  hawla) 

1  'In   all   tenures  based   on  the  case  may  be,  on   the   person  who 

right    of    reclamation,    it    will    be  reclaims  jungle   and  causes  waste 

found   that   claims   exist    and    are  land   to    be    brought    under   culti- 

asserted,  with  more  or  less  tenacity,  vation.' — (Mr.  J.  S.  Cotton.) 

not  onlyfor  the  permanent  character  2  I  need  hardly  remind  the  reader 

of  the  holding,  but  also  very  often  that  when  the  vernacular  name  of 

for  fixity  of  rates  .  .  .    and  accord-  the  tenure  is  given,  the  holder  of  it 

ingly  it  is  a  principle  always  claimed  (as  a  person)  is  indicated  by  adding 

in  these  provinces,  though  it  is  not  'dar'  (P)  =  holder.   Thus  the  holder 

always  conceded,  that  a  taluq   or  of  a  'jot'  or  ganthi  tenure  is  the 

sub-proprietary  right   is  vested   or  jot-dar,    ganthi-dar ;    just    as    the 

transferred,   or    conferred,    as    the  holder  of  a  taluq  is  taluq-dar. 

N  n  2 


548 


LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 


in  Jessore,  Backergunge.  and  Noakhali.  In  other  places  we 
have  the  '  taluq  '  of  Chittagong,  and  the  '  chak  '  in  the  Sun- 
darban  tracts.  In  Midnapore  we  shall  find  that  the  revenue- 
free  grant  already  mentioned  as  '  aima,'  was  there  applied 
in  favour  of  clearers  of  the  jungle,  and  the  '  aimadars '  of 
that  district  are  tenure-holders. 

Some  remarkable  features  are  presented  by  the  Khulna 
district,  which,  in  1882,  was  separated  from  Jessore.  It 
might  be  supposed  that  the  customary  tenures,  based  on 
jungle-clearing,  would  be  the  same  both  in  the  northern 
and  southern  halves  of  the  old  collectorate.  It  is  not  so. 
In  the  Khulna  parganas  Baghirhat  and  Naldi,  the  terms 
'ganthi'  and  'jot'  of  North  Jessore  are  not  recognised. 


§  14.    Features  of  the  tenures  in  Jessore,  &c. 

We  may  commence  our  study  with  these  districts — 
remarking  that  Khulna  includes  a  good  portion  of  the  delta 
tract  we  have  already  spoken  of  in  connection  with  the 
waste-land  rules — the  Sundarbans. 

The  following  extract  from  Mr.  Westland's  1  Monograph 
on  Jessore  will  give  a  good  idea  of  these  tenures ;  and  Mr. 
Cotton  remarks  that  this  also  describes  the  state  of  things 
in  the  Sundarbans  generally. 

'Patni  tenures  and  farms  are  almost  unknown,  as  the  Za- 
mindar  does  not  ordinarily  transfer  all  his  rights  to  others, 
constituting  himself  a  mere  rent-charger ;  but,  on  the  other 
hand,  he  manages  his  lands  himself.  In  the  south  of  the 
district  (i.  e.  in  the  present  Khulna  district),  in  fact,  it  is  the 
raiyats  and  not  the  Zamindars  who  take  to  creating  tenures. 
The  highest  tenure  is  called  a  taluk,  the  talukdar  holding  and 
paying  rent  for  a  village  or  half  a  village ;  sometimes  cul- 
tivating himself,  sometimes  not.  The  talukdar  corresponds 
with  the  ganthidar  of  the  older  tracts  (where  the  word  taluk- 
dar2 has  a  totally  diiferent  application,  and  refers,  not  to  the 


1  Westland's  Monograph  on  the  Dis- 
trict of  Jessore  (pp.  198,  1991. 

2  See  p.  525  and  note.    It  applied 


to   the   holdings   in  the 
estate. 


'  nawara  ' 


CHAP.  III.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  549 

raiyat  series,  but  to  the  landholder  series  of  tenures).  The 
talukdar's  rent  is  looked  upon  as  a  fixed  rent.  Under  him 
comes  the  hawaladar,  who  corresponds  with  the  jama'-holder 
farther  north,  and  whose  rent  is  also  regarded  as  fixed.  The 
hawala  tenure  may  be  created  by  the  Zamindar  if  he  has  not 
already  created  a  talukdar,  and  in  this  case  a  talukdar  sub- 
sequently created,  will  take  position  between  the  hawaladar 
and  the  Zamindar.  The  right  of  a  talukdar,  however,  includes 
that  of  creating  hawdlas  within  his  own  tenure  ;  and  the 
hawaladar,  again,  may  create  a  subordinate  tenure  called  '  nim- 
hawala,'  and  may  subsequently  create  an  '  ausat-hawala, ' 
intermediate  between  himself  and  the  'nim-hawaladar.'  In 
these  subordinate  tenures  the  holders  are  almost  always  of  the 
pure  peasant  class,  and  engage  personally  in  agriculture.  They 
are  always  regarded  as  having  rights  of  occupancy ;  but  if  they 
again  let  their  lands,  those  who  cultivate  under  them,  who  are 
called  cliardia  raiyats,  have  no  such  rights,  and  regard  them- 
selves as  only  holding  the  land  for  the  time. 

'  These  tenures  have  their  origin,  I  have  no  doubt,  in  rights 
founded  upon  original  reclamation.  A  raiyat  who  gets  a  small 
piece  of  land  to  clear  always  regards  himself  as  having  a  sort 
of  property  in  it — an  l  abadkari  swatya '  or  reclamation  right. 
As  reclamations  extend,  he  begins  to  sub-let  to  other  raiyats, 
and  we  have  a  hawaladar,  with  his  subordinate  nim-hawaladars 
in  a  few  years. 

4  The  talukdars  above  described  are  those  who,  in  the  per- 
gunna  lands,  come  between  the  Zamindar  and  the  raiyat 
proper,  or  hawaladar. 

1  In  Sundarban  grants 1,  the  word  has  another  meaning,  for 
the  Sundarban  grants  are  themselves  called  taluks,  and  their 
possessors  are  talukdars.  Among  these  talukdars  we  find 
several  persons  holding  considerable  estates  (zamindaris)  in 
Jessore,  Backergunge,  or  the  24-Pergunmhs ;  but  a  great 
number  of  them  appear  to  belong  to  the  comfortably-circum- 
stanced class  of  people  residing  immediately  north  of  the 
Sundarbans.  Many  people  there,  who  derive  a  competence 


1  The  grants  here  referred  to  are  by  these  grants  are  tracts  of  Sunder- 

those  which   have   been   made   by  ban  waste  which  are  not  included 

Government   under   rules   promul-  within  Zamindaris  under  the  Per- 

gated  from   time   to   time  for  the  manent     Settlement.  —  (H.    J.    S. 

encouragement   of  reclamation    in  Cotton.) 
the  Sunderbans.   The  lands  covered 


550  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

either  from  a  tenure  in  land  or  from  commerce,  have  also  some 
taluk  in  the  Sundarbans,  and  they  form,  for  the  most  part, 
successful  reclaimers.  They  have  just  enough  money  to  enable 
them  to  carry  on  Sundarban  reclamation  with  success  ;  and 
they  are  not  rich  enough  to  leave  everything  in  the  hands  of 
agents,  and,  by  forgetting  their  direct  interest,  relax  the  enter- 
prise. Many  of  them  also  have  raiyats  of  their  own  in  their 
older-settled  lands,  and  can  use  them  for  their  newer  lands. 
It  is  to  the  class  to  which  these  men  belong  that  the  greater 
part  of  the  agricultural  improvements  and  extension  since  the 
Permanent  Settlement,  is  owing,  and  the  advantage  of  having 
men  of  this  class  as  Sundarban  talukdars  was  strikingly  shown 
in  1869.  The  raiyats  lost  very  much  indeed  by  the  cyclones  of 
that  year  ;  and  the  loss  would  have  been  sufficient  to  paralyze 
the  whole  reclamation  scheme,  but  that  these  talukdars, 
immediately  connected  as  they  are  with  the  grants,  at  once 
came  forward  to  give  their  raiyats  the  necessary  assistance, 
drawing  only  upon  the  little  surplus  of  money  they  had  at 
their  homes.  Larger  Zamindars  require  to  have  these  matters 
brought  home  to  them,  and  even  then,  expect  their  raiyats  to 
settle  matters  themselves  ;  these  smaller  men  at  once  appre- 
ciate the  whole  case,  and  step  into  the  gap.' 

While  the  old-established  'jot'  and  'ganthi'  of  Jessore 
are  founded  on  the  clearing  right,  modern  ganthis  are  now 
much  connected  with  the  Zamindars'  arrangements  for  rent- 
collection  ;  still  the  ganthidars  have  much  to  do  in  the  way 
of  promoting  cultivation  and  settling  the  villages.  Mr. 
Westland  says  that  these  'tenures  are,  whatever  the  law 
may  say,  understood  by  the  people  to  be  fixed.'  Their 
right  is  so  firmly  established,  that,  according  to  Mr.  Finu- 
cane,  the  Zamindars  do  not  think  of  contesting  it 1. 

§  15.    The  hawdla. 

The  '  hawala  '  of  the  Sundarban  tracts  of  Khulna,  Bakir- 
ganj,  and  Noakhali  is  so  named  from  the  Arabic  word 
signifying  something  placed  '  in  charge  of '  or  '  consigned 

1  There  is  a  report  on  the  jot  and       Correspondence   on    the    Preparation    qf 
ganthi  of  Jessore  by  Mr.  Finucane       Tables  of  Rent-rates. 
in  the  printed  selections  from  the 


CHAP.  III.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  551 

to '  a  person.  The  tenure  implies  the  grant  by  a  superior 
landlord,  of  a  certain  limited  area  of  waste  for  reclamation. 
The  hawaladar  settles  some  cultivators  on  the  land,  advances 
them  a  little  money  wherewith  to  erect  homesteads,  buys 
ploughs  and  cattle,  and  advances  seed  for  sowing ;  he  then 
realizes  rents  from  the  cultivators  and  pays  his  own  quit- 
rent  to  the  superior  landlord.  The  tenure  is  permanent, 
but  the  quit-rent  is  not  absolutely  fixed  (unless  there  is  a 
grant  in  set  terms).  Mr.  Cotton  says  : — 

'This  point  has  been  settled  by  the  Courts  and  is  admitted 
in  many  cases  by  the  hawaladars.  But  it  so  happens  that  the 
tenure  of  the  hawaladar  has  often,  either  intentionally  or 
through  carelessness,  been  perpetuated  .  .  .  and  that  the 
hawala  has  been  sold,  re-sold,  and  transmitted  by  descent.  .  .  . 
In  such  cases  the  hawaladars  naturally  claim  permanence  of 
terms  and  fixity  of  rate. ' 

In  the  Noakhali  district  there  are  some  considerable 
Government  estates,  and  consequently  the  exact  position  of 
the  hawaladar  has  come  up  for  determination.  Under  the 
Settlement  law  of  Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1879,  they  were 
treated  as  'occupancy  raiyats.'  Their  rents  were  settled 
under  Sections  5  and  6  of  the  Act,  but  not  on  the  principle 
of  charging  them  with  the  total  of  all  the  sub-rents,  less 
a  specific  percentage  deduction.  Agreeably  to  this  conces- 
sion, they  were  to  pay  a  certain  lump  sum  to  Government 
as  determined  by  the  Settlement  officer,  and  are  free  to  make 
their  own  contract  arrangements  with  the  actual  cultivators. 
I  presume  that  now,  under  Act  VIII  of  1885,  the  hawaladar 
will  come  within  the  meaning  of  '  tenure -holder.' 

The  extract  from  Mr.  Westland's  Monograph,  given  in 
the  last  paragraph,  forcibly  reminds  us  how,  coming  under 
permanent  waste-clearing  tenures,  smaller  sub-tenures  also 
arise  :  the  tenure-holder  finds  he  has  more  land  than  he 
can  manage,  and  he  sub-lets  a  portion  of  the  surplus ; 
his  sub-lessee,  for  the  same  reason,  again  sub-lets.  The 
hawaladar  creates  an  '  ausat-'  (corruptly  ashat)  hawala,  also 
called  '  mm-'  (or  half)  hawala.  The  sub-lease  of  this  is  the 


552  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BE1TISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

'  nim-ausat-hawala ' ;    and   then   again   a  '  nim-ausat-nim- 
hawala  '  (fortunately  shortened  into  '  tim-hawala ') l. 

§  1 6.    Taluqddrs  of  Chittagong. 

Under  the  head  of  tenures  I  ought  to  mention  the  taluq- 
dars of  Chittagong.  On  the  Permanent  Settlement  being 
made  with  the  heads  of  groups  or  tarfdars,  the  individual 
settlers  or  taluqdars  became  tenure-holders  under  them. 
The  position  also  of  the  '  nauabad  '  taluqdars  or  new  settlers 
who  came  in  after  the  Settlement,  has  also  to  be  considered ; 
but  as  it  would  be  inconvenient  to  break  up  the  account  of 
Chittagong  into  parts,  I  have  put  everything  relating  to 
that  district  under  one  section  which  follows. 

§  17.    Jalpdiguri  J6ts. 

The  cultivated  land  of  this  district  is  held  by  'jotdars' 
who  are  described  as  descendants  from  original  settlers  who 
appeared  as  mere  squatters  on  the  waste  and  prepared  a 
portion  of  it  for  cultivation.  As  land  was  more  plentiful 
than  labour,  a  large  part  of  the  holdings  still  remained  under 
jungle  ;  and  now,  as  usual,  the  jotdar  sub-leases  to  tenants 
called  '  chukanidars  ' ;  and  as  these  cannot  manage  it  at  all, 
they  sub-lease  to  others  called  '  dar-chukanidars.' 

In  the  "Western  Dwars  Settlement,  the  jotdar  has  been 
recognized  as  a  tenure-holder  under  Government  as  proprie- 
tor 2  ;  but  as  originally  his  right  was  regarded  as  a  strong 
one — a  sort  of  quasi-proprietary  right — he  has  been  allowed 
an  unusually  large  margin  of  profit  by  the  Settlement. 

1  Original    hawalas    are    distin-  conditions    for    rent-enhancement, 

guished  by  added  names  indicating  All  these  terms,  therefore,  formid- 

any    little    peculiarity.     Thus,    in  able  as   they  look,  mean   little   or 

Tipperah    (Tipra),  I   find    that  an  nothing  from  the  tenure  point  of 

'  izhari   hawala '   means    a    tenure  view. — See  Statistical  Account,  vol.  vi. 

which  is  claimed  by  the  holder  but  p.  405. 

not    recognized    by  the   Zamind£r  2  The    tenure    is    heritable   and 

(who  takes  the  rent  all  the  same).  transferable,  but  the  power  of  sale 

'  Miras  hawdla '  will  be  one  acknow-  is  limited  ;  the  Bhutan  custom  was 

ledged  as  having  been  inherited  ;  that  a  sale  could  not  be  made  to 

'  qaimi  hawala '  will  be  one  with  the  prejudice  of  any  one  who  would 

fixed   rent ;    '  karari    hawala '   one  succeed  in  the  event  of  the  death 

with  certain   conditions  attached  ;  of  the  '  jotdar.' — Statistical  Account  of 

'  raiyati  hawali '  one  with  express  Bengal,  vol.  x.  p.  284. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE  LAND-TENURES.  553 

The  rights  of  the  sub-lessees  are  protected  by  a  record  of 
their  rents,  and  the  pattas  provide  that  the  rents  are*  to 
remain  fixed  during  the  term  of  Settlement,  unless  and 
until  the  jotdar  can  show  that  the  payments  to  him  have 
given  him  a  less  profit  than  50  per  cent,  on  the  revenue  he 
pays  to  Government,  or  the  chukanidar  can  show  that  he  is 
left  a  less  profit  than  30  per  cent,  on  the  rent  he  pays  to  the 
jotdar. 


554  LA^D    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  VII. — CHITTAGONQ  TENURES. 

§  i.    Origin  and  growth  of  Tenures. 

Mr.  H.  J.  S.  Cotton,  some  years  ago,  published  a  graphic 
memorandum  on  Chittagong  Revenue-history1,  and  I  cannot 
do  better  than  substitute,  for  any  abstract  of  my  own,  the 
paragraphs  Mr.  Cotton  has  himself  put  together  in  a  recent 
printed  memorandum  on  Tenures  in  Bengal. 

The  land-tenures,  it  will  be  observed,  are — 

(1)  the  proprietary  estates  of  the  petty  Zamindars   or 

tarfdars  who  were  the  connecting  links  between  the 
State  and  the  families  who  cultivated  ; 

(2)  the   subordinate   tenures   of   those   individuals   and 

families  whose  rights — as  usual  in  Bengal  — are 
described  as  taluq  holdings  : 

(3)  the  tenures   of  cultivators  who   came  in  after  the 

Permanent  Settlement,  and  whose  cultivation  was 
therefore  described  as  '  new '  (nau-dbdd),  and  whose 
holdings  are  nauabad-taluqs. 

Chittagong  is  certainly  an  instance  of  a  country  to 
which  the  ideals  of  the  Permanent  Settlement  Were  wholly 
unsuited.  Obviously  enough  now,  the  Settlement  should 
have  been  raiyatiudri  with  the  several  taluq-settlers :  not 
only  does  the  '  tarfdar '  proprietor  bear  more  than  usually 
strong  marks  of  being  a  purely  artificial  landlord  ;  but  as 
the  different  taluqs  under  him  are  scattered  one  here  and  one 
there,  his  estate  must  be  practically  unmanageable,  were  it 
not  for  the  strength  of  the  individual  taluqdar's  position, 
which  frees  them  from  any  direct  interference. 

'  The  origin,'  writes  Mr.  Cotton,  '  of  the  peculiar  system  of 
land-tenure  in  the  Chittagong  distinct  has,  in  my  opinion,  been 

1  Memorandum  on  the  Revenue  History      Collector  and  Magistrate  of  Chitta- 
of  Chittagong,  1880  ;  Calcutta,  Secre-       gong, 
tariat   Press.     By  H.  J.  S.  Cotton, 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  555 

correctly  stated  by  the  Commissioner,  Mr.  Lowis,  in  a  recent 
report  submitted  to  the  Board ],  as  follows  : — 

'"During  the  turbulent  times  preceding  the  final  Maho- 
medan  occupation  of  the  district,  small  settlements  of  '  khush- 
bash '  cultivators  appear  to  have  been  formed  in  different 
directions.  As  soon  as  the  Mahomedans  finally  established 
themselves  in  the  country,  the  first  step  was  to  collect  rents 
from  these  men,  who,  to  save  themselves  from  the  annoyance 
and  trouble  of  visits  from  the  revenue  underlings,  attached 
themselves  to  some  person  having  influence  at  the  Nawab's 
court,  and  paid  their  revenue  through  him  ;  hence  these  self- 
elected  agents  came  to  be  called  tarafdars,  from  the  Urdu 
word  taraf— on  the  part  of — a  partizan2.  Hence  it  is  that  each 
taraf  is  a  mere  aggregate  of  taluks,  as  these  '  khushbash '  hold- 
ings came  to  be  called,  the  component  parts  of  each  being 
scattered  in  different  villages  and  different  thanas.  Such  a 
thing  as  a  compact  estate  is  unknown  in  Chittagong. 

'"The  taluqdars  must  have  chosen  their  own  taraf dar, 
otherwise  we  would  not  find  every  estate,  whether  large  or 
small,  scattered  piece-meal  over  the  district.  Had  the  tarafdars 
obtained  the  land  and  settled  taluqdars,  or  had  Government 
farmed  out  the  collections  to  tarafdars,  it  is  quite  clear  that  such 
a  fragmentary  division  would  have  been  avoided — opposed  as 
it  is  to  all  facility  for  collection.  Looking  to  the  facts  as  they 
stand,  it  seems  to  me  perfectly  clear  that  the  popular  belief  is 
the  correct  one,  viz.  that  the  taluks  were  the  original  clearances, 
and  that  for  their  own  convenience  these  taluqdars  elected  to 
pay  revenue  through  the  agency  of  certain  individuals  known 
as  tarafdars,  an  aggregate  of  such  scattered  holdings  forming 
a  taraf." 

'  In  this  manner  the  large  tracts  of  jungle  existing  in  Chitta- 
gong were  taken  up  in  the  first  instance  by  taluqdars  or 
jangalburi  [jungle-clearing]  settlers,  while  the  work  of  sub- 
sequent reclamation  went  on  by  the  agency  of  the  same  class. 
I  agree  with  Mr.  Lowis  that  it  was  the  intention  of  the  Govern- 

1  No.  72  C.T.,  dated  8th  December,  it  maybe  remarked,  also  means  a 
1882,  paragraph  13.  section  or  '  side/  as  when  a  village 

2  The  term'  khushbash '  (P.,  being  is   divided   into   'tarafs'  or  major 
at  ease)  is  used  all  over  India  to  sections  in  Northern  India ;  so  that 
indicate  a  tenant  or  settler  invited  '  tarafdar '  may  also  imply  the  head- 
to    take   up   his  abode   at   a  place  ship  of  a  group  or  section,  i.e.  of  the 
under   promise   of  protection   and  cultivating  settlers  or  taluqdars. 
favourable  terms.     The  word  taraf, 


556 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 


ment  of  Lord  Cornwallis  to  fix  the  demand  against  these 
taluqdars  at  the  time  of  the  Permanent  Settlement.  In  the 
correspondence1  of  the  time,  reference  is  made  to  the  "fixed 
jamabandi  raiyats,"  and  the  necessity  of  seeing  that  the 
Zamindars  do  not  exact  from  them  sums  in  excess  of  their 
engagements,  is  insisted  on.  In  these  allusions  to  fixed  jama- 
bandi raiyats  there  is  no  doubt  that  reference  is  made  to  the 
jangalburi-taluqdars,  and  it  is  evident  that,  in  fixing  the 
demand  due  from  the  Zamindars  or  tarafdars,  it  was  intended 
that  the  amount  payable  by  the  taluqdars  should  be  fixed  also, 
and  that  all  of  that  class  should  continue  to  enjoy  the  same 
privileges  which  we  find  enjoyed  by  them  at  the  time  of  the 
Permanent  Settlement.' 


§  2.    Change  in  the  position  of  the  Taluqddr. 

'For  some  time  subsequent  to  the  Permanent  Settlement, 
the  rights  and  privileges  of  the  taluqdars  appear  to  have  been 
respected  ;  but  the  tendency  of  late  years  has  unfortunately 
been  in  an  opposite  direction.  Even  at  the  present  day,  how- 
ever, though  bereft  of  some  of  the  privileges  which  used  to 
attach  to  it,  the  taluq  is  still  a  valuable  holding,  and  its  posses- 
sion carries  with  it  something  of  a  proprietary  title.  It  is 
always  considered  to  be  permanent,  and  is,  in  consequence, 
called  qdimi,  although  the  taluqdars  are  frequently  persuaded 
into  consenting  to  some  small  increase  of  rent,  which  under 
our  laws  militates  against  the  claim  of  fixity  of  rate.  A  taluq 
is  transferable  and  heritable,  and  a  taluqdar  can  grant  per- 
manent leases  without  question.  Eoughly  speaking,  the  entire 
district  is  divided  amongst  these  taluqdars,  most  of  whom 
cultivate  personally.' 

randum  on  the  Revenue  History  of  the 
Chittagong  District.  The  statement 
there  given  shows  the  nature  of 
the  assessment :  first,  the  assul- 
jumma,  with  its  component  parts  ; 
then  the  abwfib,  mahtot,  and  other 
demands  added  to  the  assul,  until 
the  Government  demand  on  a  droon 
of  land  amounted  to  Arcot  R.  15, 
annas  5,  gundas  19,  and  3  cowries. 
This  amount  is  equivalent  to  R.  15, 
annas  13,  gundas  16,  in  Sicca  ru- 
pees ;  and  for  convenience  of  cal- 
culation has  always  been  reckoned 
as  R.  16  of  the  Company's  coinage. 


1  An  extract  from  Mr.  Collector 
Bird's  letter,  reporting  on  the  pro- 
posals for  the  decennial  Settlement, 
dated  i4th  January,  1788,  is  as 
follows :  '  The  rates  and  rules  of 
assessment  do  not  vary  in  any  part 
of  this  province,  and  the  raiyats 
are  immediately  redressed  wherever 
it  is  found  that  the  zemindars  exact 
anything  beyond  the  established 
jamabandi,  with  their  different  ab- 
wabs  which  are  specified  in  the 
accounts  annexed.'  The  whole  of 
this  letter,  with  the  accounts,  will 
be  found  at  pp.  55-61  of  the  Memo- 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  557 


&  q.    Etmdmddrs. 

J    *v 

'Where,  however,  the  holding  is  of  any  size,  or  where  a 
person  owns  more  than  one,  a  portion  only  is  reserved  as 
"  nij-jot "  (home-farm),  and  the  rest  is  leased  to  cultivators 
locally  called  etmamdar  (the  term  is  a  corruption  of  ihtimam — 
a  trust).  An  etmam  is  like  the  taluq,  qdimi,  and  the  rent  is 
not  theoretically  subject  to  increase  ;  but  in  practice,  if  the 
taluqdar  is  persuaded  by  a  new  auction- purchaser  or  otherwise 
to  consent  to  some  small  increase,  he  generally  manages  to  get 
some  corresponding  rise  in  the  rent  payable  by  his  etmamdar. 
The  etmamdar  is  also  generally  a  cultivator,  but  he  enjoys  the 
same  power  as  the  taluqdar  of  granting  permanent  leases  to 
under-raiyats.  Hence  the  creation  of  "dar-etmams"  and  "qaimi 
raiyati"  leases/ 


§  4.    The  Naudbdd  holdings  (subsequent  to  the  Permanent 
Settlement). 

[All  land  that  was  not  held  by  taluqddrs  paying 
revenue  though  '  tarfdars '  who  became  the  landlords,  at  the 
Permanent  Settlement,  was  outside  the  scope  of  the  Settle- 
ment, and  remained  the  property  of  the  State.  But  as  time 
went  on,  squatters  occupied  it  informally,  and  then  naturally 
questions  arose  about  their  position.  They  called  themselves 
taluqddrs  like  the  older  cultivators.  This  large  area  of 
land,  shown  in  a  separate  colour  on  the  maps,  was  collec- 
tively called  the  mahdl  or  estate  of  Government,  and 
distinguished  by  the  term  nau-dbdd — newly  cultivated. 
The  following  is  what  Mr.  Cotton  writes  about  it.] 

'  The  taluqdars  of  the  Government  nauabad  mahal  base  their 
claims  on  exactly  the  same  grounds  as  do  the  other  taluqdars, — 
viz.  on  original  reclamation  of  the  soil.  When  Chittagong 
passed  into  the  hands  of  the  English,  the  policy  of  encouraging 
the  reclamation  of  waste  land  and  of  granting  rights  to  the 
holders  or  taluqdars,  such  as  existed  under  the  Mogul  adminis- 
tration, was  carefully  adhered  to.  Accordingly  in  May,  1761, 


558 


LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


a  proclamation l  was  issued,  inviting  people  to  take  up  waste 
and  bring  it  under  cultivation.  The  reclaimer  was  only  required 
to  record  the  amount  of  his  reclamation  and  was  to  be  assessed 
at  the  established  rate.  The  immediate  result  of  this  pro- 
clamation was  a  considerable  extension  of  cultivation  which 
was  claimed  by  one  Joy  Narayan  Ghosal  as  having  been 
brought  about  by  his  efforts  ;  and  in  the  measurement  of  the 
district  in  1765  the  new  nauabad  taluqs  were  grouped  and 
recorded  under  pattas  granted  by  him,  as  "  taraf- Joy  Narayan 
Ghosal."  Subsequent  measurements  made  from  time  to  time 
recorded  the  increased  area  of  land  brought  under  cultivation. 
In  1796,  the  grant  under  which  Joy  Narayan  Ghosal  claimed 
to  be  "tarafdar"  of  all  new  lands  brought  under  cultivation, 
was  declared  to  be  a  forgery,  and  his  rights  were  confiscated  by 
the  State.  But  the  rights  and  privileges  of  the  nauabad  taluq- 
dars  were  obviously  unaffected  by  this  action,  and,  as  a  matter 


1  An  extract  from  the  proceedings 
of  the  Chittagong  Council,  dated 
isth  May,  1761,  is  to  the,  following 
effect :  '  Taking  into  consideration 
the  vast  quantity  of  lands  that  have 
been  laid  waste  for  many  years  past 
from  the  dissensions  between  the 
people  of  this  province  and  those 
of  Arracan,  and  as  an  encourage- 
ment to  every  one  who  will  under- 
take the  clearing  and  inhabiting 
these  lands  again,  agreed  that  a 
proclamation  be  put  up  and  publicly 
declared  throughout  all  parts  of 
the  province,  that  whatever  persons 
will  undertake  the  clearance  of 
such  lands  shall  for  the  first  five 
years  be  excused  all  rents  and  taxes 
whatever ;  that  at  the  expiration 
of  that  time  their  rents  are  to  com- 
mence at  the  usual  rate  of  lands  in 
every  other  part  of  this  country ; 
and  that  a  guard  shall  constantly 
be  kept  there  to  protect  them 
from  any  insults  of  the  Muggs  or 
other  foreigners :  and  to  prevent 
hereafter  disputes  regarding  the 
property  of  the  land  when  cleared, 
every  person  who  shall  engage  in 
the  inhabiting  and  clearing  of  them 
shall  first  register  his  name  in  this 
office,  and  every  month  send  an 
account  of  what  quantity  he  has 
cleared,  for  which  pottahs  shall  be 
immediately  granted  him.' 


The  effect  of  these  orders  is  to 
create  precisely  a  junglebooree  taluq 
as  defined  in  sec.  8,  Regulation  VIII 
of  1793,  as  follows:  '  Taluqdars 
also,  whose  tenure  is  denominated 
jutigalburi,  and  is  of  the  following 
description,  are  not  considered  en- 
titled to  separation  from  the  pro- 
prietors of  whom  they  hold.  The 
pattd  granted  to  these  taluqddrs  in 
consideration  of  the  grantee  clearing 
away  the  jungle  and  bringing  the 
land  into  a  productive  state  gave  to 
him  and  his  heirs  in  perpetuity 
the  right  of  disposing  of  it  either 
by  sale  or  gift ;  exempting  him 
from  payment  of  revenue  for  a 
certain  term,  and  at  the  expiration 
of  it,  subjecting  him  to  a  specific 
'asl-jama,  with  all  increases,  abwdb, 
and  mahtaut  imposed  on  the  per- 
gunnah  generally,  but  this  for  such 
part  of  the  land  only  as  the  grantee 
brings  into  a  state  of  cultivation. 
And  the  grantee  is  further  subject 
to  the  payment  of  a  certain  specified 
portion  of  all  complimentary  pre- 
sents and  fees  which  he  may  receive 
from  his  under-tenants  exclusive  of 
the  fixed  revenue.  The  pattd  speci- 
fies the  boundaries  of  the  land 
granted,  but  not  the  quantity  of 
it  until  it  is  brought  into  culti- 
vation.' 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  559 

of  fact,  they  were  clearly  recognized  by  the  Collector  at  the  time 
of  the  confiscation. 

'  It  is  impossible  in  this  memorandum  to  describe  the  subse- 
quent history  of  the  nauabad  taluqdars.  It  has  become  the 
subject  of  an  elaborate  and  intricate  correspondence,  extending 
over  a  period  of  ninety  years,  and  a  variety  of  conflicting  orders 
have  been  passed  from  time  to  time  by  the  highest  authorities ; 
the  rights  of  the  taluqdars  have  again  and  again  been  empha- 
tically asserted  and  they  have  been  as  emphatically  denied  V 

'The  Ee-settlement  of  nauabad  lands  was  ordered  in  1872. 
It  was  then  decided  that  the  position  of  a  nauabad  taluqdar 
was  that  of  a  tenure-holder  in  an  estate  the  property  of  Govern- 
ment. Under  orders  then  passed,  the  Settlement  has  been 
based  on  the  rents  actually  paid  by  the  cultivators :  no  inter- 
mediate tenures  have  been  recognized 2,  the  proprietary  title  has 
been  held  to  belong  solely  to  Government :  and  the  taluqdar 
himself  been  treated  as  a  sort  of  rent  collector  with  little  more 
interest  in  his  holding  than  that  possessed  by  a  farmer.'  .  .  . 

'  The  Commissioner  has  now  challenged  the  propriety  of  the 
conclusions  at  which  the  Government  arrived,  and  on  which  it 
founded  the  orders  on  which  the  Settlement  has  been  made.' 

It  has  been  decided  (see  section  on  Settlement,  p.  492) 
that  the  holdings  are  liable  to  re-settlement,  but  it  has  been 
conceded  that  a  number  of  these  shall  not  be  re- settled  at 
present,  which  puts  them  on  the  same  basis  as  other  holdings 
to  which  a  fifty  years'  settlement  was  conceded  in  1 848. 


§  5.    The  Island  of  Kutubdla. 

'  The  title  of  the  taluqdars  of  the  island  of  Kutubdia  rests 
upon  the  same  origin  as  that  of  the  taluqdars  of  the  mainland. 
They  were  declared  by  the  Settlement  officer  in  1834  ;! — 

1  The  subject  is  discussed  by  me  ment,  paragraph  7,  No.  993,  dated 
at  length,  with  full  extracts  from  10th   April,   1878,  it   was   directed 
correspondence,  in  a  note  recorded  that  certain  intermediate  holdings 
in  the  Board's  office,  dated  7th  Feb-  should    be    recognised;    but    these 
ruary,  1883.     A   copy  of  this  note  instructions     were     not     properly 
was  submitted  to  Government  with  carried  out. 

the  Board's  letter  No.  693  A,  dated  3  Mr.  Plowden's  Keport,  No.  34, 

i8th  August,  1883.  dated  agth  September,   1834,  para- 

2  Under  orders  passed  by  Govern-      graph   14.     But   of  course   if   the 


560  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF  BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 

'  "to  hold  a  jangalburi  tenure  differing  in  no  respect  from  the 
description  of  that  denomination  of  tenure  as  laid  down  in 
Section  8,  Eesolution  VIII  of  1793.  These  dependent  pro- 
prietors, under  the  above  section,  enjoy  a  permanent,  hereditary, 
and  transferable  right  of  occupancy,  privileges  to  which  they 
have  always  considered  themselves  entitled  ;  for  whilst  in  some 
cases  the  original  jangalburi  taluqdars  are  still  in  possession, 
others  have  become  proprietors  in  right  of  succession  as  heirs 
of  the  original  clearers  of  the  land,  whilst  a  third  class  rest 
their  claim  on  the  deeds  of  purchase  or  gift  executed  either  by 
the  original  grantees  or  their  heirs." 

'  In  the  recent  Settlement  of  the  island,  the  title  of  taluqdar 
has  been  retained,  but  practically  the  taluqdars  have  been 
treated  as  occupancy  raiyats,  and  the  Settlement  records  do 
not  contain  any  entries  of  the  holding  or  rental  of  the  actual 
cultivators.  The  claim  to  hold  at  fixed  rates  was  strenuously 
asserted,  but  it  has  not  been  admitted.  In  one  case  only  a 
taluqdar  contested  the  principles  of  the  Settlement  in  the  civil 
court,  but  unsuccessfully,  and  the  others  appear  to  have  accepted 
the  situation.' 

clearing  had  not  been  made  in  1793      proprietary  or  permanently  settled 
it  did  not  follow  that  the  settler    .  estate  under  the  Regulation, 
would   be   entitled   to    any  quasi- 


CHAP,  in.]      .  THE    LAND-TENURES.  561 


SECTION  VIII — THE  LAND-TENURES  OF  ORISSA. 

§  i.    Early  History. 

Only  a  part  of  what  is  now  the  Midnapore  district  con- 
stituted the  '  Orissa '  comprehended  in  the  grant  of  the 
Diwani  in  1765.  For  the  purposes  of  this  section,  however, 
I  include  both  the  old  and  the  modern  Orissa:  in  other 
words,  I  go  beyond  the  Subarnrekha  river  which  now 
forms  (roughly  speaking)  the  provincial  boundary,  as  far  as 
the  Rupnarain  river  further  to 'the  north-east. 

First,  taking  the  modern  Orissa  only,  as  to  its  general 
features ;  I  have  before  noticed  that  it  consists 

(1)  of  certain  Tributary  States  furthest  inland  ; 

(2)  of  certain  Permanently  Settled  Estates  next  beyond 

them  towards  the  coast ; 

(3)  of  the  flat,  rice-growing  country  called  the  Mughal- 

bandi,  which  was  the  chief  seat  of  Temporary  Settle- 
ment operations  ;  and 

(4)  a  swampy  coast-line. 

The  '  Tributary  States  '  are  not  properly  part  of  British 
territory:  they  are  the  home  of  various  relics  of  primaeval 
tribes,  the  Kandhs  (sometimes  written  Khonds),  Savars  or 
Sauras,  and  others ;  they  present  great  attractions  to  the 
ethnologist.  The  Uriya  people  or  Uraons  (Dravidians  from 
the  south  by  origin)  seem,  at  a  remote  period,  to  have 
conquered  the  whole  country. 

The  primaeval  tribes  were  not  altogether  displaced  by  the 
Uraons,  but  the  two  races  apparently  co-existed.  The 
Uraons  in  some  parts  left  the  aborigines  alone  in  such  fast- 
nesses as  the  Bod  State  (where  the  Kandhs  now  are),  or  the 
hills  to  the  south,  where  the  Savars  are  (or  in  Keunjhar, 
where  the  curious  Bhumiyas.  who  claim  to  be  autochthones, 
and  the  leaf-wearing  Jawangs  are  found).  In  other  parts 
they  took  the  ruler's  place,  seizing,  of  course,  the  best 
lands  for  their  chiefs.  Sir  W.  W.  Hunter  has  extracted  for 

VOL.  i.  oo 


562  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.        [BOOK  n. 

us,  out  of  the  old  official  records  of  Orissa,  a  most  interest- 
ing account  of  the  Kandhs l.  That  I  must  pass  over, 
merely  remarking  that  the  Kandhs  exhibit  the  same  peculi- 
arity as  other  Kolarian  tribes.  They  had  no  organization 
above  that  of  tribal  families  in  villages,  these  again  being 
loosely  grouped  into  circles  under  petty  chiefs. 

The  Kandhs  (as  is  the  case  with  other  tribes  similarly 
situated)  have  hardly  settled  down  from  the  nomadic 
stage,  in  which  cultivation  is  practised  by  firing  the 
forest  and  raising  a  crop  or  two  by  the  aid  of  the  ash- 
manure.  Where  they  are  more  confined  as  to  space,  there 
the  tribe  has  finally  settled,  and  lays  claim  to  the  whole 
area  occupied,  while  the  families  have  their  allotments 
which  remain  undivided  until  the  death  of  the  family- 
head2.  It  is  this  head  of  the  family  who  is  everything. 
There  is,  of  course,  the  necessity  for  protection  from 
enemies  and  wild  beasts,  which  causes  a  number  of  families 
to  group  together;  they  arrange  their  residence  like  the 
people  of  Kanara 3,  where  the  '  village '  site  is  in  fact  a 
single  street  with  houses  on  either  side,  and  at  the  end 
the  huts  of  the  menial  caste  and  artisans,  who  supply  the 
needs  of  the  residents.  The  villages  are  often  divided  by 
rugged  peaks  and  dense  forests,  but  the  only  organization 
is  that  as  each  village  is  under  a  headman,  so  a  group  of 
villages — probably  the  'sept'  or  section  of  a  tribe — forms 
a  '  muttha ' 4 ;  and  the  chief  of  the  sept  is  over  the  muttha. 
This  exactly  resembles  the  village  union  called  parhd,  and 
the  chief  (mdnki)  which  we  shall  notice  in  Chutiya  Nagpur. 

The  Uraons  had  a  much  stronger  government ;  and, 
indeed,  like  those  southern  (Dravidian)  states  about  which 

1  Orissa,  vol.  ii.  p.  69.  for   pasturage    among    the   village 

2  In  their  native  settlements  they       hamlets.' — Orissa,  ii.  77. 

change  their  villages  once  in  about  3  Cf.  p.  106,  ante.  In  such  a  village 
fourteen  years  ''Priority  of  occu-  a  headman  is  a  necessity,  and  be- 
pation  forms  the'  -sole  origin  of  comes  still  more  so  when  the  tribe 
right.  No  complicated  tenures  is  brought  into  contact  with  a  con- 
exist,  every  man  tilling  his  own  quering  Raja  or  some  one  mightier, 
field  and  acknowledging  no  land-  He  is,  however,  elected  and  only 
lord.  Where  the  population  begins  partly  hereditary,  and  has  no  par- 
to  press  heavily  on  the  territory  of  ticular  emoluments  or  authority, 
the  tribe,  they  parcel  out  the  waste  *  Onssa,  ii.  70. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE   LAND-TENUKES.  563 

we  shall  hear  so  much  in  the  Madras  Presidency,  they  had 
an  organization  which  it  is  very  hard  to  distinguish  from 
the  Aryan  or  Rajput.  We  find  the  same  gradations  of 
rank ;  first,  a  great  chief  over  the  whole  nation,  with  his 
central  demesne ;  minor  chiefs  on  the  frontiers,  and  a  system 
of  militia  to  guard  the  marches,  and  to  keep  the  peace 
within. 

At  a  remote  period,  however,  Orissa  became  the  scene  of 
Rajput  conquest  ;  and  the  Jagannath  records,  though  Brah- 
manical,  and  naturally  inclined  to  ignore  everything  non- 
Aryan,  leave  no  doubt  that  the  Rajput  or  Aryan  settle- 
ment must  have  taken  place  long  ago  and  assimilated 
the  institutions  of  the  villages  and  states  of  the  non- 
Aryan  tribes :  so  that  the  present  state  of  things  is  due — 
(i)  to  the  Dravidian  organization;  (2)  to  its  modification 
by  the  Rajput  system  which  supervened,  and  later  by  the 
Mughal  conquest  which  tended  to  convert  the  Rajput  fiscal, 
police  and  military  officers  into  landlords ;  (3)  the  action  of 
the  brief  and  ill-established  Maratha  rule,  in  arresting  the 
growth  of  the  landlords,  and  pushing  forward  the  heads 
and  managers  of  villages  and  smaller  estates. 

It  has  been  suggested  that  the  Aryans  really  copied  and 
adopted  the  earlier  system 1.  I  must  be  content  with 
merely  noting  the  fact,  adding  that  in  Chutiya  Nagpur  we 
clearly  see  how  the  Dravidians  strengthened  the  Kolarian 
village  system,  linking  it  on  to  their  own  State  organiza- 
tion of  chiefs  and  courtiers,  by  adding  to  the  village  an 
accountant,  or  fiscal  headman — the  '  bhuin '  of  Orissa,  the 
'  mahto '  of  Chutiya  Nagpur. 

§  2.   The  organization  of  the  Orissa-Rdjjmt  Kingdom. 

As  to  the  Rajput  organization  of  Orissa,  we  find  that 
the  Raja  occupied  the  level  and  fertile  plain  as  his  de- 
mesne, or,  as  it  would  be  called  in  Rajputana,  his  '  khalsa.' 
All  round  were  the  hilly  frontier  tracts  which  were  held  by 
chiefs  called  'khandaits.'  This  term,  derived  from  the 

1  See  Chapter  IV.  p.  119,  and  Orissa,  ii.  207. 
O  O  2 


564  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH  INDIA.        [BOOK  11. 

Uriya  '  khanda,'  a  sword,  was  applied  not  only  to  the  great 
frontier  chiefs  who  kept  the  marches,  but  also  to  the  mili- 
tary chiefs  of  all  grades  who  were  located  within  the  king's 
demesne.  The  hill  states  were  protected  by  the  '  forts '  at 
which  the  chiefs  resided,  and  hence  the  territories  came  to 
be  known  collectively  in  Muhammadan  times  as  '  Garhjat.' 
The  estate-owners  were  called  'Qila'dars1.' 

We  may  dismiss  the  Garhjat  chiefs  from  further  notice  ; 
the  Mughals  and  Marathas  never  interfered  with  them 
beyond  exacting  a  tribute  and  nominal  allegiance :  they 
have  now  become  the  {  Tributary  States '  or  '  Mahals '  of 
the  Regulations,  and  are  under  political  control  only  2. 

The  '  demesne '  itself  was  also  portioned  out  into  many 
estates ;  for  there  was  a  large  military  force  to  be  main- 
tained, and  estates  also  called  '  Qila' '  were  also  formed  on 
the  margin,  which  estates  became  the  '  Zarnindaris '  and 
were  admitted  to  a  Permanent  Settlement  as  noticed  in 
the  chapter  on  Settlements.  The  ordinary  districts  were 
divided  for  fiscal  purposes  into  '  Bisi '  or  '  Khand ' — terri- 
torial tracts  under  a  Desmukh,  Bissai,  or  Khand-adhipati, 
aided  by  some  military  chief  or  '  Khandait,'  whose  '  paiks ' 
or  military  retainers  were  supported  by  small  rent-free 
holdings.  The  district  officer,  who  was  to  the  district 
what  the  headman  was  to  the  village,  had  a  district 
accountant  (Bhui-mul)  to  aid  him,  and  a  village  accountant 
also  was  subordinate  to  him  in  each  village.  Every  one  of 
them  had  lands  held  in  virtue  of  office  (a  Dravidian 
institution),  which  laid  the  foundation  of  those  estates  or 
tenures  dealt  with  in  our  own  Settlements  at  the  beginning 
of  the  century. 

But  besides  supporting  the  military  chiefs,  the  king 
made  grants  within  his  demesne  for  the  support  of  the 
priesthood3,  for  his  family,  and  for  his  ministers  and 
courtiers.  Some  curious  survivals  of  these  grants  are 

I  '  Qila' '  means  a  fort  in  Arabic,  3  The    existence    of    the    sacred 
as  '  garh  '  does  in  Hindi.  temple  at  Piiri  ensured  many  lands 

II  This  was  judicially  decided.  See  being  granted  revenue- free  for  the 
Indian  Law  Reports,  viii.   985  (Cal-  worship  of  Jagannath. 

cutta  Series). 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  565 

mentioned  in  the  reports.  They  were  called  by  fanciful 
names,  perhaps  representing  the  titles  given  to  the  holders ; 
thus  we  have  the  grant  of  '  The  Lion's  Cub '  (Chhual 
Singh),  that  of  Hari  Chandan,  of  Sudhakar  (the  receptacle 
of  nectar),  Utsal  Kanajit  (grant  of  the  exalted  conqueror). 
'  Beg '  (grant  to  some  Afghan  adventurer),  and  many  others. 

§  3.  Effect  of  the  Mughal  Conquest. 

When  the  Mughal  rule  supervened,  the  district  organiza- 
tion was  scarcely  changed,  except  by  the  substitution  of 
Persian  names :  the  '  khand '  or  district  became  the  par- 
gana.  The  military  and  civil  heads  remained  on  their  own 
lands,  but  were  called  '  chaudhari,'  and  probably  with  ill- 
defined  functions ;  the  accountant  became  the  kamingo ; 
and  the  village  the  '  mauza,'  with  its  head  or  accountant 
variously  named  according  to  locality  and  the  tribal  origin 
of  the  village  itself. 

'Two  centuries,'  writes  Sir  W.  Hunter,  'of  conflicting 
usage  followed  (1567-1751).  During  that  period  of  con- 
fusion and  chronic  rebellion,  the  Muhammadan  governors 
were  only  too  glad  to  secure  the  revenue  for  each  current 
year  without  any  nice  scrutiny  of  the  machinery  by  which 
they  collected  it  ...  What  they  wanted  was  a  body  of 
powerful  native  middlemen  who  should  take  the  trouble  of 
dealing  with  the  people  off  their  hands,  and  who  should 
have  both  the  power  and  local  knowledge  enough,  to 
enforce  the  revenue  demands  against  the  individual 
villages  V 

The  body  of  hereditary  Hindu  officials  thrust  into  this 
position,  soon  came  to  act  like  landlords ;  if  it  had  not 
been  for  the  intervention  of  the  Maratha  period,  they 
would  probably  have  become  absolute  landlords  under  the 
British  system. 

1  Orissa,  ii.  221. 


566  LAND   SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


§  4.    Illustration  of  the  growth  of  Land-officers 
into  Landlords. 

Before  noticing  what  relics  of  the  '  estates '  of  the 
kanungos,  chaudharis,  and  others  survive,  I  would  call 
attention  to  the  very  instructive  account  which  Sir  W. 
Hunter  gives  of  their  means  of  gro^uth•,  because  this, 
though  written  of  the  Orissa  districts,  really  explains  the 
growth  of  '  Zamindars '  and  others  everywhere  in  Bengal. 

First  of  all,  these  officers  were  all  appointed ;  but  as 
soon  as  the  Government  became  weak  and  relied  upon 
the  local  knowledge  and  power  of  those  who  were  its 
instruments,  it  followed  almost  necessarily,  that  the  son,  or 
other  competent  near  relative  of  the  last  man,  stepped  into 
his  shoes  ;  and  the  right  of  appointment  practically  became 
softened  into  the  right  of  confirming  or  issuing  a  '  sanad ' 
to  the  new  man,  and  perhaps  taking  a  fee  or  present  by 
the  governor.  In  the  end  the  '  sanad '  was  discontinued, 
and  there  was  then  nothing  but  a  tacit  recognition  of  the 
succession. 

The  opportunities1,  then,  of  these  fiscal  officers  were, 
first,  that  they  were  practically  hereditary ;  they  were 
responsible  for  the  revenue,  and  therefore  had  large  powers 
in  realizing  it ;  they  also  had  the  right  to  retain  a  nominal 
percentage  and  various  charges  or  heads  of  expense  in 
collecting:  really  they  kept  whatever  they  could  collect 
over  and  above  the  fixed  sum  they  had  to  pay  in  to  the 
treasury.  They  had  their  official  holdings  of  revenue-free 
land ;  they  had  the  profits  of  bringing  new  waste  and 
abandoned  lands  under  cultivation, — all  the  newly-settled 
cultivators  of  course  looking  to  them  as  their  direct  head 
or  'landlord.'  They  had  various  dues  and  cesses,  rights 
over  fisheries,  pasture  lands,  thatching-grass,  bamboos, 
jungles,  forests,  transit  dues,  and  the  like.  What  wonder, 
then,  that  in  time  such  officers  should  become  landlords  ? 
And  be  it  observed,  all  this  process  of  growth  is  the  more 

1  See  Orissa,  ii.  230. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  567 

possible  because,  in  the  individual  villages,  there  is  no 
strong  proprietary  right.  The  actual  cultivators  who  are 
residents  (thani)  are  practically  proprietors  of  their  holdings, 
just  as  much  as  the  Kandh  families  were  of  their  lands ; 
but  the  long-continued  effect  of  the  Raja's  rule,  and  the 
encroachments  of  the  grantees  and  others  who  took  the 
royal  share  within  the  grant,  reduced  the  resident  cultivator 
to  being  nothing  more  than  a  permanent  occupant  with  a 
hereditary  right :  it  was  no  one's  interest,  as  long  as  govern- 
ment was  settled,  to  reduce  them  lower  than  that.  In 
North  India  we  have  seen  that  as  the  grantee's  family 
multiplies  and  divides,  it  produces  a  number  of  individuals 
or  families  holding  each  perhaps  a  single  village  as  the 
share  of  the  estate ;  and  then,  in  time,  they  appear  as  the 
actual  proprietary  body  owning  the  village  (which  then 
becomes  a  '  zamindari '  or  a  '  pattidari '  village  of  the  text- 
books). 

§  5.   Circumstances  limit  the  growth. 

In  Orissa  the  process  was  arrested  by  the  fact  that  there 
were  certain  greater  fiscal  chiefs  who  kept  the  Bissais 
(kamingos)  subordinate  to  themselves  ;  but  furthermore  it 
was  arrested  by  the  fact  that  when  the  Marathas  came, 
they  checked  the  growth  of  these  incipient  landlords. 
Wherever  we  come  across  a  tolerably  settled  form  of 
Maratha  government,  we  shall  again  and  again  notice  that 
the  Maratha  at  once  did  two  things:  he  imposed  a  quit- 
rent  on  revenue-free  holdings — thus  avoiding  the  odium  of 
wholly  resuming  them;  and  he  ignored  the  middleman 
system,  went  straight  to  the  villages,  and  made  use  of 
the  headman  as  the  distributor  of  rents,  holding  him 
primarily  responsible  for  their  collection.  It  was  only  in 
the  outlying  tracts  where  the  Maratha  rule  was  uncertain, 
that  the  governors  granted  large  farms  and  took  all  they 
could  grasp  before  the  day  of  destruction.  So  it  was  in 
Orissa ;  the  village  heads  were  resorted  to,  with  the  result 
of  greatly  increasing  their  power :  as  usual,  in  many  cases 


568  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

inefficient  headmen  were  turned  out  and  replaced  by 
'  sarbarakars '  or  managers ;  exactly  as  in  the  Central 
Provinces,  a  'patel'  who  did  not  give  satisfaction  was 
replaced  by  a  '  malguzar '  or  revenue-paying  manager. 


§  6.    First  British  policy. — Absence  of  great  Zaminddrs. 

When  our  rule  began  in  1803,  no  attempt  was  made  to 
introduce  the  Permanent  Settlement  or  its  laws.  I  have 
described  the  chief  features  of  the  Orissa  Settlement  before T  : 
I  have  here  only  to  speak  of  the  tenure  of  land.  It  is 
unfortunate  that  our  reports  so  often  speak  of  '  Zamindars,' 
as  if  Orissa  had  been  permanently  settled,  and  as  if  such 
an  institution  had  existed  generally.  There  are  in  fact 
hardly  any  '  Zamindars '  in  the  Bengal  sense  2.  There  were 
a  few  of  the  'Qila's'  or  chiefs'  estates  lying  on  the  edge  of 
the  royal  demesne  (which  it  will  be  remembered  was  the 
scene  of  our  detailed  Settlement),  and  a  few  of  the  greater 
fiscal  officers,  who  had  retained  such  a  hold  over  the  whole 
of  the  pargana,  that  our  first  administrators  thought  fit  to 
acknowledge  them  as  proprietors,  and  give  them  the  benefit 
of  a  permanent  revenue.  Then  there  were  a  certain  number 
of  kanungos'  estates,  and  those  of  other  chiefs  and  grantees 
(of  which  I  have  spoken).  Of  these  some  were  regarded 
as  subordinate  to  the  greater  estates,  and  others  were 
allowed  to  be  independent  and  were  treated  as  pro- 
prietary. 

The t larger  number  recognized  as  'landlords'  were  the 
headmen,  '  muqaddams '  or  '  sarbarakars '  of  villages  (in 
some  places  the  local  names,  'pradhan,'  &c.,  survived.) 

As  regards  the  class  of  large  '  landlord  estates/  the  latest 
return  I  have  shows  only  174  such  estates  (permanently 
assessed),  viz.  23  in  Katak,  3  in  Puri,  and  148  in  Balasor3, 

1  See  p.  473.  Zamindari    in    Regulation   XII    of 

2  The  proclamation  of  1803  issued  1805,     and    the    sanads    were    so 
on  annexation,  spoke  of  zamindars,  worded.     I  find,  for  instance,  one 
meaning    '  landholders '    generally.  of  the   Khandait    chiefs   (Sakinda 
See  Orissa,  ii.  257.  estate)   giving  his    '  qabuliyat '   or 

3  The   larger   estates    are    called  engagement  setting  forth  that  he 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENUKES.  569 

while  the  smaller  village  and  other  estates,  temporarily 
settled,  exceed  six  thousand. 


§  7.    Smaller  Landlord  Estates. 

Putting  aside  the  few  great  estates  called  '  Zamindarl,' 
the  bulk  of  estates  which  came  under  Settlement  were 
smaller  properties, — holdings  of  kaniingos,  chaudharis. 
courtiers,  grantees,  and  revenue-free  holders.  They  are 
described  as  '  taluq,'  and  are  called  after  their  origin  '  taluq 
chaudhari,'  the  estate  held  by  the  chaudhari,  and  so  forth. 
These  estates  should  not  be  described  as  'tenures,'  as  the 
term  has  a  special  or  technical  sense  in  Bengal.  I  may 
repeat  that  when  we  speak  of  '  holders  of  tenures '  in 
Bengal  we  now  mean  interests  of  the  second  class  existing 
under  a  recognized  landlord.  But  in  Orissa  the  larger 
number  of  the  landholders  we  are  speaking  of  became 
Settlement-holders  direct  with  Government. 

One  of  the  results  of  the  former  rule  had  been  a  system 
of  selling  estates  and  villages,  nominally,  but  not  always 
actually,  waste  ;  and  a  number  of  those  who  had  purchased 
such  estates  became  ( proprietors '  and  their  estates  were 
called  '  kharidadari,'  'patna,'  and  'kharija'  (i.e.  lands 
outside  any  other  recognized  estate). 


§  8.    Revenue-free  Holdings. 

There  were  also  many  revenue-free  estates  \     Some  of 
these,  of  course,  were  petty  rent-free  holdings  under  other 

had  been  '  appointed  to  the  service  claims  to  Idkhirdj  decided  by  Deputy 

of  Zamindar '  in  his  Qila'  by  the  Collectors     amounted    to     277,925 

Government,    and    that   he   would  (Memorandum  on  Temporary  Settlements, 

pay    the    revenue    and    keep    the  1880,  p.  580).     The  Marathas  im- 

raiyats  prosperous,  &c.  (see  Statistical  posed  a   'tankhi'  or  quit-rent  on 

Account  of  Bengal,  vol.  xviii.  p.  123).  many  such   tenures,   consisting   of 

In  Katak  the  old  records  showed  i  tankha  or  rupee  of  the  time  per 

that  of  1779  proprietary  or  quasi-  'bati'   of  20    'man.'      The   Orissa 

proprietary  estates,    16   only  were  '  man '  is  closely  equal  to  the  Eng- 

called    'Zamindari'   and    the    rest  lishacre.  A  number  of  these  tenures 

'  taluq.'  were  settled  at  half  rates  under  the 

1  Mr.   Stack   mentions    that   the  British  Settlement. 


57O  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITfSH   INDIA.        [BOOK  II. 

proprietors.  The  rule  was  that  such  holdings,  when  ad- 
mitted as  valid,  were  treated  as  proprietary  estates  if  they 
exceeded  75  acres,  and  as  subordinate  (tenure)  interests  if 
smaller. 

Among  the  smaller  rent-free  holdings  figure  many  be- 
longing to  the  '  paiks '  or  old  militia ;  and  some  were  called 
'  jagirs  '  or  '  dogra '  (literally  '  stick-holder ') l. 


§  9.    Village  Heads  become  Proprietors. 

In  many  cases  the  village  heads,  especially  those  who 
had  purchased  the  villages,  and  others  whose  actual 
position  demanded  the  step,  were  settled  with. 


§  10.   But  artificial  Landlord  rights  rarely  created. 

The  Orissa  officers,  as  is  amply  testified  by  the  valuable 
notes  they  have  left  on  the  land-tenures,  and  which  Sir 
\V.  Hunter  has  turned  to  such  good  purpose  in  his  Orissa, 
were  under  no  necessity  for  creating  landlords:  and,  as 
Sir  W.  Hunter  remarks,  '-putting  aside  very  quietly  the 
theories  of  distant  bureaucrats,  the  local  officers  proceeded 
laboriously  to  construct  a  system  in  accordance  with  the 
actual  facts.'  Hence  the  variety  of  estates  actually 
recognized.  But  while  a  number  of  larger  or  smaller 
proprietary  estates  were  recognized,  and  the  owners  held 
the  Settlement,  the  mistake  was  not  made  of  leaving  un- 
defined the  power  of  the  estate-holder,  or  letting  the 
question  of  the  rent-payments  of  subordinate  holders  be 
doubtful.  The  estate-holders'  interest  was  strictly  limited 
by  the  procedure  at  Settlement.  The  officers  went  direct 
to  the  villages  and  fixed  the  rents  of  the  than!  raiyats 
(who  really  were  the  original  individual  proprietors — only, 
as  I  have  explained,  they  ceased  to  claim  so  high  a 
position).  This  done,  there  was  a  fixed  total  rental,  of 

1  The  Statistical  Account  notes  that,  in  1875,  sixty-five  of  these  existed  in 
Katak  district,  covering  8339  acres. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE   LAND-TENURES.  57! 

which  part  went  to  Government  and  the  rest  to  the  '  pro- 
prietor.' 

§  ii.  Grades  of  interest — lioiv  provided  for. 

But  though  the  proprietor  was  one,  he  had  often  to  share 
the  profits  with  other  persons  interested — as,  e.  g.  first  the 
aarbardkdr  of  the  village,  second  a  dependent  taluqdar. 

In  oui'  Settlements,  whether  there  was  a  proprietor  over 
the  village  or  not,  the  headman,  niuqaddam,  sarbarakar, 
parsethi,  pradhan,  or  whatever  his  local  title,  was  allowed 
to  collect  the  rents  and  manage  the  village  and  receive  a 
percentage  for  his  trouble  ;  and  so  with  the  '  kharidadars,' — 
headmen  by  purchase  of  reclaimed  or  new  villages  \ 

Practically,  therefore,  the  difference  between  the  nominal 
landlord  and  the  inferior,  interests  is  represented  by  the 
larger  or  smaller  share  of  the  rental  fixed  at  Settlement. 

§  12.    Protection  of  Tenants. — The  Thdni  Raiyat. 

The  cultivators  are,  as  I  said,  protected  by  rents  fixed 
for  the  term  of  Settlement,  if  they  are  '  thani '  or  resident ; 
and  the  Rent  Law  of  1859,  still  in  force 2,  protects  the  paM 
tenants  who  have  fulfilled  its  terms. 

The  '  thdni '  cultivator  is  in  fact  a  '  sub-proprietor '  in 
everything  but  the  name.  'Rooted  to  the  soil,'  wrote 
Mr.  Sterling  in  1821,  'he  has  a  local  habitation  and  a 
name,  a  character  known  to  his  neighbours,  and  a  certain 

1  In    the   Statistical   Account   (vol.  centage   he  gets  under  the  Settle- 

xviii.  p.  307)  will  be  found  a  dis-  ment   represents   no   right   in   the 

cussion    as    to    the    origin    of   the  soil,  but  is  a  collection  allowance 

'  sarbarakar '  as   distinct  from  the  only.     But,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  the 

muqaddam  or  headman  (the  Mu-  village  total  payment  to  the  pro- 

hammadan    equivalent    of    barmv,  prietor  being  fixed,  the  sarbarakar 

pradhan,    or    other    local    names).  gets  the  benefit  of  an  increase  in 

As  to  the 'parsethi, 'the  explanation  the   rental  when   alluvial   land   is 

of  his  being  a  town  headman    (p.  formed  and  let  out,  or  when  waste 

134)  is  very  unlikely :   most  prob-  in   the  village    is    occupied.     The 

ably  he  is  the  headman  of  a  later  tenure   may   be    (if  so    proved   by 

colony,    i.  e.    a  village    of   modern  custom)  heritable  and  transferable, 

foundation  (see  p.  310).     The  sar-  but  the  holder  is  liable  to  be  re- 

barakar's  right  was  the  subject  of  moved  for  misconduct, 

judicial  decision  in  1 859.    The  per-  a  See  p.  452. 


572  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

degree  of  credit  thence  resulting,  which  enables  him  to 
borrow  from  the  mahajan  (money-lender)  and  secures  him 
a  settled  market  for  the  disposal  of  his  produce.'  He  is 
exempt  from  demand  of  'chandniya'  (a  payment — chan- 
dina — made  by  outsiders  for  the  use  of  a  site  in  the 
village) ;  he  is  allowed  a  bit  of  rent-free  '  khanabari '  or 
garden-ground  near  his  house1,  also  a  rent-free  patch  in 
his  holding  called  '  talmunda,'  or  a  nursery-ground  for  his 
rice-plants. 

'  A  preference,'  adds  Mr.  Sterling,  '  is  given  to  him  in 
cultivating  the  lands  of  village  lakhirajdars  (revenue-free, 
—the  aima,  debottar,  &c..  lands,  so  often  spoken  of)  when 
the  holders  do  not  themselves  handle  the  plough  ;  and  his 
sons  and  brethren,  and  even  he  himself,  may  cultivate 
untenanted  land  as  "  pahi "  raiyats  in  their  own  or  any 
other  villages.' 

§  13.    Midnapore. 

I  include  the  district  of  Midnapore  in  this  notice,  though 
the  greater  portion  of  the  district,  being  the  old  Orissa  of 
1 765  (all  in  fact  but  the  Pataspur  pargana),  came  under  the 
Permanent  Settlement.  The  tenures  now  found  in  the 
district  are  those  which  are  usually  found  described  in 
Persian  terms  of  the  Mughal  system  and  that  of  the  Regu- 
lations, and  again  and  again  repeated  in  the  Statistical 
Account.  There  is  the  usual  array  of  Zamindaris,  the 
resumed  '  lakhiraj  '  estates,  and  the  '  bahali  '  [i.  e.  those  not 
resumed,  but  that  remained  in  (ba)  their  own  state  (hal)]. 
Under  them  are  the  usual  '  taluqs '  or  tenures, — '  patnis/ 
'  ijaras/  and  the  like.  Of  these  no  special  mention  is  here 
required.  A  certain  number  of  special  jungle-clearing 
tenures  (but  sometimes  granted  out  of  favour)  exist  under 
the  name  of  kamdura.  They  are  heritable  and  trans- 

1  The  reader  will  also  note  the  the  differences  of  Brahman  villages 

same  custom  in  Assam.     There  is  are  noted.     As  the  Brahman  could 

an  exceedingly  good  account  of  the  not  plough,  the  whole  cultivation 

village  (exactly  resembling  the  vil-  was   done   by  the   aid  of  tenants, 

lages  all  over  Bombay  and  Madras)  which   resulted   in   some  peculiar- 

in  Orissa,  vol.  ii.  p.  241,  and  there  ities. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENUKES.  573 

ferable.  I  also  notice  favourable  tenures  called  'panchaki,' 
seemingly  identical  with  the  'upanchaki'  of  Rangpur1. 
It  is  also  worthy  of  notice  that  the  revenue-free  tenure  or 
'  aima '  seems  to  have  been  here  created,  not  for  the  support 
of  religious  persons,  but  as  a  favourable  tenure  for  cul- 
tivating the  waste.  As  it  is  not  entirely  free,  it  is  called 
'  nialguzari  aima.'  No  rent  is  paid  for  some  years,  and 
then  the  rent  progresses  to  the  rate  usually  paid  in  the 
pargana  for  similar  lands.  Some  of  these  tenures  in  par- 
gana  Balrampur  are  said  to  date  back  before  the  Permanent 
Settlement ;  others,  under  the  same  name,  are  more  recent. 
To  this  class  also  belong  what  are  known  as  '  mandali 
jot'  tenures  in  Midnapore,  which  are  nothing  more  than 
the  holdings  of  certain  men  who  were  set  to  reclaim  the 
waste  (abadkar),  undertaking  that  a  lump  sum  of  rent 
should  be  forthcoming.  From  time  to  time  the  terms  of 
the  bargain  were  readjusted.  Naturally  the  abadkars  became 
the  mandal  or  headmen  of  the  new  villages.  They  had 
a  higher  status  than  ordinary  resident  raiyats ;  and  they 
were  entitled  to  make  their  own  terms  with  their  culti- 
vators, thus  getting  a  considerable  profit  out  of  the  differ- 
ence between  the  lump  rent  they  paid  and  the  total  of 
the  collections  from  cultivators.  Their  tenure  became 
transferable  by  custom. 

1  See  pp.  540  and  586. 


574  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  IX.— CHUTIYA  NAGPUB  TENUBES. 

§  i.    Interest  attaching  to  the  Tenures. 

The  tenures  of  these  districts  have  a  peculiar  interest  for 
us,  because  here  (and  in  Santalia)  we  have  one  of  the 
centres  in  which  we  can  trace  pretty  clearly  one  of  the 
earliest  native  methods  of  landholding  in  relation  to 
the  State,  which  are  so  interesting.  Just  as  Oudh  and 
Rajputana,  and  to  some  extent  Orissa,  give  us  the  best 
information  regarding  the  Rajput  or  Aryan  organization 
which  has  so  profoundly  affected  the  constitution  of  village 
communities,  so  Chutiya  Nagpur  is  a  centre  which  enables 
us  to  reconstruct  the  organization  of  Kols  and  Dravidians, 
the  latter  being  great  colonizers  and  conquerors,  like  the 
Rajputs ;  and  this  organization  is  probably  identical  with 
what  once  existed  in  Gondwana  (now  the  Central  Pro- 
vinces and  Berar)  as  well  as  in  Southern  India1. 

§  a.    General  Description  of  the  Country. 

The  Chutiya  Nagpur  country  covers  an  area  of  about 
46,000  square  miles.  It  consists  of  a  series  of  table-lands 
rising  in  succession  from  800  to  3500  feet  above  the  sea- 
level. 

On  each  ten-ace  are  well-cultivated  plains,  and  the  borders 
of  each  are  scarped  and  forest-clad  hills.  The  plains  them- 
selves are  dotted  over  with  wooded  hills.  In  the  east  of 
the  division  are  the  tribes  known  as  Mundas,  Hos,  and 
Santals  (Kolarian) ;  in  the  west  are  Korwas  (Kolarian 

1  The   materials  for  this   sketch  1887,    vol.    iii.)  ;     an    interesting 

are   Mr.   J.   F.  Hewitt's  paper  on  '  Official  Paper '  in  the  Calcutta  Ga- 

Village    Communities    in    Journal,  zette,  i7th  December,  1880,  on  the 

Society  of  Arts,  vol.    xxxv.    p.   613  Lohardagga     District  ;     and     the 

(May    1887)  ;    '  Chota    Nagpur,    its  volumes  of  the  Statistical  Account  of 

People  and  Resources,'  by  the  same  Bengal,  relating  to  the  Division, 
author  (Asiatic  Quarterly  Review,  April 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  575 

also).  The  independent  States  along  the  frontier  of  the 
Central  Provinces  are  Gond  (Dravidian).  There  are  Bhuya 
tribesmen  in  the  States  of  Gangpur  and  Bonai,  and  in  the 
(British)  Singbhum  and  Manbhum  districts.  In  some  parts 
there  are  also  Uraons.  These  are  all  Dravidians. 

It  seems  that  the  Kolarian  tribes  are  the  earliest  inha- 
bitants, and  the  Uraons  and  Bhuyas  are  invaders ;  in  fact, 
part  of  that  great  wave  of  conquest  made  by  the  Naga 
(snake- worshipping)  people,  who  advanced  far  up  to  the 
Ganges  valley.  The  Santals  are  K61s ;  they  moved  from 
Orissa  to  Hazaribagh  to  escape  the  Marathas,  and  then,  in 
the  middle  of  the  last  century,  settled  in  the  hills  which 
are  now  known  as  the  '  Santa-1  Pergunnahs.' 


§  3.    Kol  and  Dravidian  Organization  of  Land. 

Of  these  tribes  some  appear  to  have  had  but  little  or- 
ganization, but  to  have  lived  by  shifting  or  temporary  'jum ' 
clearings  in  the  forests1.  But  in  the  plains  they  formed 
settled  villages  with  a  headman  over  each  (munda).  The 
Naga  races  in  their  advance,  where  they  did  not  drive  out 
the  weaker  tribes,  admitted  them,  as  it  were,  into  their  con- 
federacy, and  the  system  became  one — that  is  to  say,  the  Kol 
village  system  was  strengthened  by  the  Dravidian  military 
organization,  which  was  very  like  that  of  the  Aryans. 

There  were  senior  chiefs  or  Rajas  of  territories,  who  had 
a  central  domain,  while  all  around,  estates  were  allotted  to 
the  lesser  chiefs  and  to  the  servants  of  the  kingdom, — some, 
as  usual,  on  the  frontier,  being  charged  with  keeping  the 
passes.  The  villages,  as  usual  with  all  earlier  colonizing 
systems  in  India,  show  no  sign  of  a  joint  claim  to  a  defined 
area  of  soil.  Such  a  right  appears,  rather,  to  arise  at  a 
later  stage,  when  some  petty  chief  gets  a  hold  over  the 
village  by  grant  or  otherwise,  and  then  claims  to  be,  in 
that  little  circle,  what  the  Raja  was  in  his  larger  domain. 
His  claim  is  distinctly  territorial  and  is  focussed  on  a 

1  See  p.  116,  ante. 


576  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

small  area,  so  that  it  is  distinctly  felt  in  a  way  that  the 
Raja's  general  claim  over  a  large  area  cannot  be.  When, 
in  course  of  a  generation  or  two,  this  chief's  descendants 
form  a  considerable  body,  these  jointly  claim  the  entire 
area  as  a  body  of  'landlords';  or,  dividing  it  up  into  an- 
cestral shares  according  to  their  descent,  constitute  what 
the  books  call  '  pattidari '  communities. 

We  have  now  to  see  how  the  Kolarian  village  system 
was  modified  by  being  taken  into  the  Dravidian  system. 

The  K61  tribes  had  no  central  government.  The  tribal 
groups,  distinguished  by  a  flag1,  were  called  'parha,'  and 
over  which  was  a  chief  called  '  Manki '  or  '  Manjhi.'  These 
were  independent ;  they  might  meet  for  counsel  and  com- 
bine for  defence,  but  often  they  were  at  war  with  each 
other.  The  parha  territory  was  divided  into  villages,  each 
under  its  '  munda '  or  headman,  who  was  hereditary.  There 
was  a  '  pahan,'  or  priest ;  but  he  was  tribal,  not  local. 

The  Dravidians  did  not  alter  this  organization,  but  their 
chiefs  and  Rajas  took  the  rule  over  the  mdnkis,  who. 
having  no  special  estates,  dropped  into  a  secondary  or  in- 
ferior official  position.  What  distinguished  the  Dravidian 
plan,  was  that  in  every  village  the  Raja  or  the  chief  took 
a  certain  area  of  land,  the  whole  produce  of  which  went  to 
his  State  granary.  It  was  easy  to  carry  out  this  plan, 
because  the  whole  village  was  divided  into  lots,  according 
to  certain  principles.  The  lots  were  called  (originally) 
'  khunt ' — a  term  said  to  mean  stock  (Latin  stirps],  and 
imply  the  allotment  for  a  family  group  of  the  same  order. 
The  term  '  khunt-kati,'  or  the  clearer  of  the  holding,  is  still 
a  term  used  to  mark  the  right  which,  in  the  public  estimation, 
attaches  to  the  clearer  of  the  primeval  jungle.  The  'khunts' 
consisted  of  plots  of  different  qualities  of  land,  and  in  some 
places  were  periodically  re-distributed,  so  as  to  give  the 
person  who  enjoyed  each  a  certain  equality  of  advantage  2. 

1  These  are  still  displayed  at  cere-  India  :  where  the  level  land  was 

inonial  or  festive  gatherings.  cultivated  with  rice,  some  uplands, 

3  In  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  vil-  called  'tanr,'  to  supply  grass  and 

lages  we  find  an  institution  which  stuff  to  burn  for  manure,  were 

is  common  in  Southern  and  Western  allotted  with  each  holding. 


CHAP,  m.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  577 

When  the  Dravidians  conquered,  and  desired  to  find  a 
'lot'  in  the  village  for  the  Raja  (or  chief  in  an  estate  not 
held  by  the  Raja  himself),  it  was  easy  to  do  so  by  a  slight 
re-adjustment  of  the  '  khunt '  system. 

§  4.   Official  Allotments. — Royal  Lands. 

Originally  it  seems  that  a  lot  was  reserved  for  the  old 
tribal  manjhf — and  this  became  the  Raja's  royal  farm,  and 
was  called  majh-has.  The  '  bhuinhar,'  or  original  families 
(founders  l)  of  the  village,  had  their  allotments.  One  of 
these  was  for  the  headman,  munda,  whose  family  was  of 
course  '  bhuinhar.'  Another  was  for  the  priest  (laya),  which 
was  subdivided  into  a  lot  for  the  village  god  (gram  deota 
bhut-kheta),  and  the  district  god  (desauli  bhut-kheta) ;  the 
Dravidians  added  a  third,  the  earth-god,  or  deity  of  the 
whole  nation  (whose  secret  symbol  was  the  snake) — this 
was  called  'dalikatari  V  It  is  hardly  necessary  to  add  that 
petty  allotments  were  made  for  the  support  of  the  village 
menials — watchmen,  &c.,  and  the  artisans,  not  forgetting 
the  '  ojha,'  or  witch-finder. 

§  5.    Changes  effected  by  the  Rdjds. 

In  the  course  of  time,  but  very  early  in  the  history,  the 
Rajas  became  dissatisfied  with  merely  the  produce  of  the 
'majh-has,'  and  began  to  levy  a  grain-share  from  the  land 
generally,  but  always  excepting  the  official  and  religious 
allotments.  In  this  stage  all  the  land  that  paid  the  share 
was  called  '  Raj -has'  land.  Possibly  this  was  in  imitation 
of  the  Kols.  This  people  paid  no  regular  revenue,  but 
used  to  give  informal  offerings  of  grain  to  their  tribal 
chiefs,  which  may  have  suggested  to  the  Dravidian  Raja  to 
make  a  regular  or  formal  levy  of  grain.  Then  it  was  that 
the  Raja  grafted  on  to  the  old  village  staff,  a  steward  or 

1  Called  also  Khunt-kati  (clearers  port  of  the  priests'  assistants  who 

of  the  lot).  carried  water:  '  murghi-pakowti ' 

8  These  were  again  subdivided,  for  those  who  cooked  fowls  on  festi- 

as  e.  g.  into  '  pani-bhara '  for  sup-  val  and  ceremonial  occasions. 

VOL.  I.  P  p 


578  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

headman,  in  the  royal  interest,  and  called  '  Mahto.'  This 
official  was  provided  with  an  ex  officio  land-holding 
(called  'mahtoai),  like  the  earlier  village  authorities.  In 
order  better  to  provide  for  the  tillage  of  the  majh-has  lands, 
the  king  also  established  allotments  (called  bet-kheta)  for 
labourers  who  cultivated  the  royal  farm  ;  these  allotments 
were  held  revenue-free. 

When  these  changes  were  accomplished,  the  lands  in  each 
village  became  distinguished  as  (i)  majh-has,  (2)  the 
bhuinhari  and  other  privileged  lands,  (3)  the  other  lands 
paying  a  royal  share  and  called  raj -has  accordingly. 

§  6.   Later  condition  of  the  Village  Lands. 

When  the  Raja's  dominion  passed  away,  the  '  majh-has  ' 
land  became  the  special  holding  of  the  person,  whoever  he 
might  be,  that  retained  or  acquired  the  superior  or  quasi- 
landlord  right  over  the  village.  Meanwhile  the  idea  of 
lots  for  cultivation  was  carried  further  than  is  above  in- 
dicated ;  for,  after  these  original  allotments  were  provided 
for,  there  remained  all  the  rest  of  the  available  waste  and 
other  land.  At  the  present  day  we  find  it  held  by  a  variety 
of  what  we  may  call  tenants,  as  distinct  from  the  '  buin- 
hars.' 

In  some  villages,  a  lot  of  the  land  is  called  sajwat  or 
khundwat,  meaning  that  it  was  held  by  tenants  who  had 
cleared  the  jungle:  these  were  not  the  original  village 
founders,  but  people  called  in  at  a  later  period  to  extend 
the  cultivation  and,  as  '  first  clearers,'  were  to  some  extent 
privileged.  Then  there  would  be  a  large  area  of  'jiban/ 
held  by  people  who  got  the  right  to  cultivate  a  certain 
area  (defined  by  local  measures,  with  reference  to  amount 
of  seed  required),  and  here  the  holdings  were  not 
fixed,  but  were  distributed  from  year  to  year  by 
exchange.  Then  another  part  of  the  available  area  would 
be  held  by  ordinary  tenant-labourers,  called  '  utkar.'  This 
distribution  of  area  varied  according  to  locality  and  circum- 
stances. In  some  places,  settlers  of  other  tribes  admitted, 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  579 

were  called  '  khorkar,'  holding  rent-free  for  three  years,  and 
then  paying  half  rates.  I  find  also  tenancies  called  '  bai- 
bala,'  'ariat,'  and  many  others.  One  called  '  jalsazan,' or 
water- providing,  meant  a  permanent  tenure,  where  the 
holder  got  the  angle  of  a  ravine,  dammed  it  up,  and  so 
formed  a  small  tank  ;  then  he  carefully  terraced  some  rice- 
fields  below,  which  he  watered  from  the  tank. 

§  7.  Later  history  of  the  Rdjds. 

The  Muhammadan  conquest  brought  no  real  change  to 
the  local  chiefships ;  the  holders  were  accepted  as  Zamin- 
dars,  and  some  of  them  got  sunads  on  submitting  to  pay 
a  '  peshkash '  or  tribute. 

But  among  themselves,  the  usual  course  of  events  over- 
took both  chiefs  and  Rajas  :  quarrels,  feuds,  and  the 
usurpations  of  the  more  energetic  members  of  families  who 
threw  off  their  allegiance,  occurred.  Some  families  rose, 
others  fell.  At  first  the  seat  of  the  chief  authority  was  at 
Patkum  (Manbhum  district) ;  but,  in  time,  '  the  chiefs,  who 
had  previously  governed  outlying  provinces  under  the 
control  of  the  descendants  of  their  first  leader,  proceeded, 
like  the  Maratha  chiefs  who  separated  themselves  from  the 
authority  of  the  Government  at  Satara,  to  set  up  inde- 
pendent kingdoms  for  themselves  ;  while  the  Patkum  chiefs 
sank  from  being  lords  paramount  to  being  merely  subor- 
dinate barons.'  These  changes  appear  to  have  come  about 
gradually,  and  without  such  violent  disturbance  as  would 
have  left  traces  in  the  traditions  of  the  country l. 

The  next  change  was  one  that  also  happened  in  Assam. 
Brahmans  and  others  began  to  penetrate  the  country, 
and  in  time  the  chiefs  were  '  Hinduized.'  As  usual,  they 
became  '  Nagbansi'  Rajputs,  and  adopted  caste.  The  result 
was  that  the  outsiders  began  to  get  lands  and  influence,  and 
to  override  the  rights  of  the  original  inhabitants,  causing 
much  discontent. 


Asiatic  Quarterly  Review,  vol.  iii.  p.  410. 
P  p  2 


580  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

When  British  rule  began,  some  of  the  surviving  Rajas 
chiefs,  and  grantees,  were  recognized  as  '  Zamindars,' 
with  a  Permanent  Settlement;  and  then,  as  landlords, 
they  began  to  grant  '  taluqs '  and  '  ijaras 1,'  or  farms  of 
their  villages,  to  eject  tenants  and  enhance  rents,  on 
the  (raj-has  or)  revenue -paying  lands.  A  few  peculiar 
land-tenures  are  the  result  of  the  chiefs  becoming  Zamin- 
dars. They  made  grants  for  their  brothers,  called  '  Haki- 
mali,'  '  Kunwarkar,'  &c.  (according  to  locality),  for  relations 
called  '  Khor-o-posh.'  A  number  of  these  obtained  recog- 
nition separately,  and  became  Permanently-Settled  estates. 
When  the  old  Rajas  (or  their  successors)  became  'Zamin- 
dar'  landlords,  the  majh-has  lands  became  their  home- 
farm  or  special  property,  unless  rights  had  arisen  in  them, 
owing  to  grants,  family  divisions,  &c.  as  might  be  the  case. 
The  'raj -has'  became  the  ordinary  'tenant-lands.'  The 
landlords  did  their  best  to  reduce  to  a  minimum  the  rights 
of  the  '  bhuinhars,'  in  their  free  allotments ;  and  this  led 
to  so  much  discontent  as  to  cause  rebellion  in  1831-32, 
and  again  in  1858.  The  districts  were  then  (by  Regulation 
XIII  of  1833)  separated  from  the  Regulation  Districts  and 
placed  under  the  '  South -West  Frontier  Agency,'  the 
political  control  being  guided  by  simple  administrative 
rules.  At  the  present  time  the  districts  are  '  Scheduled 
Districts'  under  Act  XIV  of  1874.  The  Revenue-sale  law 
has  never  been  enforced. 


§  8.   Modern  attempts  to  adjust  rights. 

In  1869  it  was  determined  to  put  an  end  to  the  un- 
certainty and  discontent  which  arose  from  the  encroach- 
ments of  the  landlords,  who  had  ignored  the  old  tenures, 
and  infringed  the  bhuinhari  rights.  Bengal  Act  II  of  1869 
provided  for  the  appointment  of  a  Special  Commissioner, 
whose  duty  was  to  define  and  record  all  classes  of  rights. 

1  Thus,  forinstance,  in  Manbhum,  gana  on  an  ijara  or  managing  lease 
the  Zamindar  of  the  Barabhum  for  21  years  to  an  English  firm  of 
estate  had  granted  the  entire  par-  indigo  planters. 


CHAP.  III.]  THE   LAND-TENURES.  581 

It  is  stated  (but  on  this  matter  I  am  not  competent  to  form 
an  opinion)  that  the  Act  does  not  correctly  represent  the  real 
state  of  affairs.  I  understand  that  it  does  not  apply  to  the 
'  raj -has  '  or  ordinary  proprietary  lands,  in  which  the  tenants 
of  all  classes  have  their  holdings.  Tenants  there  have  the 
protection  already  afforded  them  by  the  Rent  law,  presently 
to  be  mentioned.  The  Act  certainly  makes  no  mention  of  the 
'  raj -has  '  lands  and  their  tenants,  but  directs  that  a  record 
of  rights  shall  be  made,  giving  an  accurate  list  of  the  lands 
that  belong  to  the  majh-has  class J,  and  those  which  were 
'bhuinhari' — i.e.  set  apart  for  the  hereditary  headman, 
mahto,  priest,  and  privileged  families.  It  was  to  be  ascer- 
tained what  were  the  services  required  from,  and  the  rights 
enjoyed  by,  the  holders. 

Anciently  the  theory  was  that  no  '  bhiiinhar  (of  an  original 
founders'  family)  could  ever  lose  his  lands ;  so  that  after 
years  of  absence  he  might  return  and  claim  it  from  the 
present  holder.  This  was  so  far  recognized  by  the 
Act,  that  a  bhiiinhar  who  had  been  dispossessed,  could 
claim  to  be  restored  if  his  loss  occurred  within  the  twenty 
years  preceding  1869.  No  tenure  originating  within 
twenty  years  was  to  be  recognized  as  really  bhuinhari, 
unless  it  was  a  proved  case,  not  of  originating,  but  of  re- 
gaining, a  former  bhuinhari  status2.  The  bhuinhars  had 
been  so  long  made  to  pay  some  rent  to  the  '  Zamindar,'  that 
this  could  not  now  be  reversed ;  but  the  holder  could 
claim  to  commute  any  service  he  had  to  render,  for  a  money 
payment. 

1  Including  the   bet-kheta  hold-  villages  and  tribes  was  well  under- 

ings    of    the    special  tenants   who  stood  ;  but  in  time  the  Rajas  and 

work  the  majh-has  land.  others  encroached,  and  so  the  bhuin- 

*  I  have  mentioned  that  rice-land  hars,  though  always  allowed  certain 

holdings  were  accompanied  by  a  cer-  rights  of  user  in  the  waste  near  the 

tain    appendage    of    hilly  upland,  village,  were  not  given   an  actual 

which   supplied    grass,   wood,   and  right  over  the  waste  (tanr)  unless 

stuff  to  yield  ash-manure,  &c.,  for  they  could  prove  a  definite  occupa- 

the  rice.     No  doubt  originally  the  tion  and  possession, 
allotment  of  such  areas  among  the 


582  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

§  9.  The  Chutiyd-Ndgpur  Tenancy  Act. 

The  value  of  the  record  made  under  this  Act  is  to  a  great 
extent  secured  by  the  existence  of  another  special  Act — 
(B.)  I  of  1879 — which  regulates  the  relations  of  landlord 
and  tenant  in  Chutiya  Nagpur. 

This  Act  makes  no  attempt  to  draw  any  theoretical 
distinction  between  tenants  and  tenure-holders,  but  speaks 
of  taluq-holders  and  persons  having  a  permanent  and  trans- 
ferable interest  in  land,  as  well  as  of  raiyats.  A  twelve 
years'  holding  gives  a  right  of  occupancy  to  a  raiyat  in  all 
lands  except  in  the  majh-has  lands,  or  in  waste  reclaimed 
by  the  landlord  (the  khamdr  of  the  Permanent  Settlement), 
or  in  his  '  nij-jot'  or  home-farm,  or  in  lands  called  '  man  ' 
lands  (held  in  virtue  of  office1),  or  as  'saika,'  i.e.  lands 
held  by  contract  from  year  to  year,  or  under  a  contract 
containing  express  stipulations. 

The  usual  rule  was  made  about  holdings  which  have 
paid  the  same  rent  since  the  Permanent  Settlement  ;  they 
are  unenhanceable.  Moreover,  no  tenant  who  is  a  '  bhuin- 
har '  or  a  '  khunt-kati '  (the  reader  will  now  understand 
this  term)  can  be  enhanced,  except  on  proof  of  custom  or  a 
written  agreement ;  and  a  number  of  tenancies  specified  in 
Section  20  are  similarly  exempt.  All  occupancy  tenants,  as 
such,  are  liable  to  enhancement  only  on  certain  terms  stated 
in  Sections  22,  23,  24. 

§  10.    GMtwdli  Tenures  of  Mdnbhtim. 

A  special  notice  of  these  tenures,  which  exist  not  only  in 
Chutiya  Nagpur,  but  in  Monghyr  (Hunger),  the  Santal 
Pergunnahs,  Bankura,  and  other  districts,  will  throw  some 

1  The  reader  will  note  how  the  of  revenue — in  virtue  of  his  office,  a 

landlord  claim  had  grown.     The  old  privilege  one  would  have  supposed 

Raja  was  content  with  his  majh-has  to  be  already  provided  for  in  the 

and  his  grain-share  ;  but  the  Zamin-  majh-has.     The    exemption   of    the 

dar  took,  besides  waste  which  he  re-  special  holdings  of  the  landlord  from 

claimed,  private   lands  of  his  pur-  the   growth   of  tenant-right  is   on 

chase    or  original  possession ;  and  the    usual    principle    observed    in 

had  land  (man)  held — no  doubt  free  modern  Indian  Tenant  Acts. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  583 

light  on  the  Permanent  Settlement  and  its  effects,  as  well 
as  on  the  influence  of  revenue-free  grants,  in  originating 
tenures.  (See  Book  I.  Chap.  IV.  Sec.  iii.  §  9.) 

The  outlying  districts  of  a  conquered  country  were,  as 
I  have  before  stated,  usually  occupied  by  chiefs  who  were 
bound  to  maintain  a  force  to  keep  the  passes.  In  the  end 
it  often  happened  that  these  very  forces  proved  a  source  of 
trouble  ;  instead  of  defending,  they  attacked  ;  and  the  '  Poly- 
gar  wars '  of  Southern  India  originated  in  this  manner. 

When  the  Permanent  Settlement  arrangements  were 
made,  there  were  a  number  of  local  chiefs  all  round  the 
frontiers  of  Chutiya  Nagpur,  in  Kamgarh  (Hazaribagh), 
Singhbhum,  Manbhum,  &c.  Their  territories  adjoined  the 
more  settled  districts,  and  formed  what  were  called  'the 
jungle  mahals '  in  early  days.  Our  administrators  ac- 
cepted these  chiefs  as  '  Zamindars,'  imposed  a  small  and 
fixed  revenue,  and  left  them  very  much  to  themselves.  In 
Manbhum  this  was  the  case.  In  the  days  before  1793,  and 
even  at  the  Permanent  Settlement,  we  hear  nothing  about 
ghatwals,  under  that  name  at  least.  In  1793,  indeed,  there 
is  some  mention  of  '  paikan '  lands ;  but  they  were  virtually 
looked  upon  as  lands  for  the  support  of  rural  police  or 
paiks,  which  did  not  demand  any  special  notice. 

But  the  existence  of  ghatwali  lands  was  a  matter  of  real 
importance,  for  it  is  to  be  remembered  that  in  these  tenures 
not  only  is  the  chief  (the  Ghatwal  par  excellence)  entitled  to 
his  privileges,  but  every  head  of  a  troop  in  his  own  grade 
and  rank,  and  every  militia  man,  had  his  lesser  share  in 
the  privilege — a  certain  area  of  land  revenue-free,  which  he 
either  worked  himself,  or,  if  his  caste  and  rank  demanded 
it,  let  out  to  his  own  tenants.  When,  therefore,  the  chief  of 
the  locality  became  'Zamindar,'  and  the  collections  from 
the  raiyats  became  his  rents,  it  followed  that  every  acre  or 
bigha  that  could  be  claimed  as  held  by  a  subordinate  in 
ghatwali  tenure,  was  so  much  cut  out  of  his  profits :  he 
got  nothing  but  (at  most)  a  small  quit-rent  from  it.  The 
sort  of  militia  men  who  held  the  land,  were  taken  over,  so 
to  speak,  by  Government,  who  tried  to  organize  them  into 


584  LAND    SYSTEMS   OP   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

rural  police  and  make  them  render  service ;  and  there  were, 
from  time  to  time,  Regulations  passed  with  this  object.  Such 
subordinate  tenures  represented  a  very  large  area  of  land, 
and  they  were  held  by  a  series  of  holders  in  a  graded  order. 

In  1877-78  the  inefficiency  of  the  local  police  called  atten- 
tion to  the  system,  with  the  result  that,  under  the  Bengal 
Survey  Act  V  of  1875,  it  was  determined  to  have  a  survey 
and  record  of  all  the  gh&twali  lands,  and  of  the  rights  of  the 
Zaminddr  and  minor  ghatwals  respectively,  so  that  disputes 
might  be  at  an  end  and  proper  service  demanded  in  return 
for  the  holdings  allowed.  Mr.  Risley,  C.S.,  was  in  charge 
of  the  ghatwal  survey  of  Manbhiim,  and  submitted  to 
Government  an  elaborate  report.  The  report  is  somewhat 
difficult  for  the  uninitiated  to  understand,  but  it  is  full  of 
curious  information. 

It  appears  that  ghatwali  lands  were  found  in  25  out  of 
the  38  parganas  of  the  Manbhum  district ;  there  were  591 
holdings,  covering  an  area  of  785,192  standard  bighas,  or 
408  square  miles1.  These  were  distributed  among  1974 
persons,  who  formed  the  organized  body, — organized,  that 
is,  according  to  their  own  custom. 

The  chief  grantee  has  become  the  '  Zaminddr,'  and  under 
him  the  various  grades  are  as  follows : — 

At  the  head  of  a  group  of  villages,  now  called  a  taraf,  is 
the  '  sardar-ghatwal,'  or  leader,  of  whom  there  are  twelve  in 
all,  and  they,  of  course,  have  the  largest  holdings.  There 
is  also  a  body  of  '  digwars,'  and  nalb-  (or  deputy-digwars, 
whose  functions  formerly  were  to  'show  the  way,'  i.e. 
guide  or  protect  travellers  and  caravans  in  transit.  They 
are  now  subordinate  heads  of  small  companies  of '  taba'- 
dars.'  In  the  ghatwal  villages  there  were  headmen 
called  '  village  sardars,'  and  persons  called  '  sadial,' 
about  whose  origin  there  was  some  doubt.  It  was  first 
supposed  that  they  were  '  sarbarakar,'  or  managing 
collectors  of  rents2 ;  but  their  true  position  seems  to  be 

1  Report  (No.  6,  dated  aoth  Dec.,  digwar,  naib-digwar,  sadial,  village- 

1883)  to  Board  of  Revenue,  §  7.    These  sardar,  and  taba'dar,  as  will  appear 

tenures    represent    the    shares     of  presently, 

various     grades,  —  sardar-ghatwal,  2  In    the    special    note    on    the 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  585 

that  of  chiefs  of  the  '  parha" '  (the  old  Kolarian  union  or 
group  of  villages) ;  being  thus  a  relic  of  earlier  times  they 
were  respected,  but  in  subordination  to  the  '  taraf-sardar.' 
The  rank  and  file  are  the  '  taba'dar,'  who  have  their  petty 
holdings.  The  local  name  for  ghatwal  is  'chhuar1.' 

It  must  be  remembered  that  this  is  the  country  of  the 
Bhumij  Kols.  There  seems  reason  to  believe  that  the 
militia-organization  was  created  over  and  amalgamated 
with,  the  village  organization  on  the  Kol  system.  The 
village  lands  being  divided  into  lots  or  '  khunts '  held 
by  the  office-bearers  and  original  settlers,  the  taba'dars 
represent  the  body  of  ordinary  village  landholders:  the 
village  sardar  represents  the  munda,  and  the  sardar- 
ghatwal  and  sadial  take  the  place  of  the  '  mankf,'  or  chief 
of  the  '  parha '  or  union  of  villages. 

It  did  not  follow,  of  course,  that  the  whole  of  the  chiefs 
(now  become  Zamindar's)  lands  were  held  by  his  subordi- 
nates on  ghatwali  tenure :  some  were  so  held,  others  as 
ordinary  tenancies  :  and,  as  there  was  no  real  knowledge  of 
land-measures  in  old  days,  it  became  a  burning  question  at 
the  survey  what  lands  should  be  demarcated  as  ghatwali, 
i.e.  held  on  that  favourable  tenure,  and  what  as  '  mal/ 
i.e.  land  liable  to  pay  full  or  tenant-rent  to  the  '  Zamindar.' 

The  ghatwali  lands  were  described  in  various  ways,  e.g. 
as  'land  sowed  with  one  maund  of  seed'  (which  may  be 
taken  as  about  eight  bighas),  or  as  so  many  '  rekhs ' — a  rekh 
meaning  a  sixteenth  of  the  total  cultivated  area,  whatever 
that  might  be.  The  consequence  was,  as  might  be  ex- 
pected, that  the  minor  ghatwals  got  to  claim,  and  hold,  a 
good  deal  more  than  they  were  really  entitled  to  ;  and  that 
any  attempt  to  define  would,  under  the  large  licence  of 

Barabhum  pargana,  Mr.  Risley  dis-  and  grant  muqarrari  rights  in  com- 

cusses  the  'sadial'  at  length,  and  plete  disregard  of  the  nature  of  their 

thinks  he  was  a  real  part  of  the  own  title.    They  even  keep  so-called 

system — a  senior  chief.  '  diwans,'  disreputable  Hindus,  who 

1  The  ghatwals  are  not  good  cul-  do  whatever  writing  is   necessary 

tivators,  and  the  lands  are  poorly  and  absorb  whatever  profits  are  to 

managed.     Notwithstanding    their  be  made  out  of  the  lands.     Even 

poverty,  '  the  sardar-ghatwals  keep  the  sadials  and  village-sarclars  copy 

up  the  pretence  of  being  Zamindars.  this  system  on  a  small  scale.'     (Re- 

They  have  seals,  execute  'sanads,'  port,  §  43.) 


586  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

dispute  given  by  the  Survey  Act,  result  in  the  ghatwals 
claiming  more  on  one  side,  and  the  Zamindar  striving  to 
reduce  the  allotments  on  the  other.  In  one  case  it  hap- 
pened that  the  original  estate-holder — the  old  Bhiimij 
chief,  who  had  first  been  transformed  into  a  Hindu  '  Raja,' 
and  then  into  a  Permanent- Settlement  Zamindar— had 
granted  an  ijara  or  managing  lease  of  the  whole  pargana  to 
an  English  firm.  These  gentlemen  were,  of  course,  anxious 
to  watch  every  demarcation ;  it  was  the  Zamindar's  in- 
terest to  see  that  no  more  was  allowed  as  '  ghatwali '  land 
than  could  be  helped.  In  M^nbhum  there  was  fortunately 
a  kind  of  list  of  the  ghatwals,  with  their  rights  stated  in 
rekhs,  &c.,  drawn  up  in  1833,  and  spoken  of  as  the  'Ism- 
navisi  '  (or  '  nominal  roll '  of  ghatwals).  Mr.  Bisley  gives 
reasons  at  length  for  relying  on  this ;  and  in  the  pargana 
we  are  speaking  of,  it  was  made  the  basis  of  a  compromise 
by  which  certain  lands  were  demarcated  as  '  ghatwali,'  the 
rest  becoming  '  mal '  or  liable  to  rent  to  the  Zamindar.  In 
consideration,  however,  of  the  fact  that  many  of  the  rent- 
payers  were  probably  the  original  clearers  of  the  land,  even 
though  not  entitled  to  it  on  ghatwali  terms,  they  were  to  be 
allowed  a  rent- Settlement  at  fixed  rates,  something  in  this 
way :  the  holders  were  to  pay  fixed  rates  per  bigha  ;  the 
Zamindar  took  50  per  cent,  from  the  headmen  of  tarafs 
(sardar-ghatwals  and  sadials) ;  the  50  per  cent,  that  re- 
mained was  then  shared  according  to  fixed  percentages 
between  the  grades  of  ghatwal ;  25  per  cent,  to  the  village 
sardar,  and  so  on. 

The  ghatwali  tenure  does  not  carry  with  it  any  title  to 
a  share  in  the  village  upland  waste  or  '  tanr,'  but  certain 
rights  of  user  are  allowed. 

The  ghatwali  land  is  not  held  entirely  free.  It  pays  the 
landlord  a  'panchak'  or  quit-rent1.  But  extra  land  pays 
rent  and  the  '  mangan  '  or  cesses. 

1  The  use  of  this  term  throws  light  'one-fifth'  would  be  alight  share, 

on  the  '  panchaki '  and '  upanchaki '  as  a  full  rent  was  often  the  half 

tenures  :  (p.  573).      Calculating  on  or  very  commonly  the  '  panch-do  ' 

the  old  fashion  of  sharing  the  grain,  or  two-fifths. 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  587 

§  ii.    Similar  Jdgir  Tenures. 

Somewhat  analogous  to  the  frontier  police  tenures  were 
the  jagir  grants  found  in  Palamau  and  Lohardagga,  and 
called  baraik,  cheru,  and  bhogta.  They  were  grants  of  land 
held  on  condition  of  the  holder  being  ready  to  turn  out 
armed  at  any  moment  to  defend  his  Raja's  lands  and  make 
reprisals J. 

§  12.    Law  relating  to  Ghdtii'dls. 

I  shall  not  go  further  into  detail  regarding  the  law  of 
ghatwali  tenures,  as  this  can  be  found  at  p.  356  of  Finu- 
cane  and  Rampini's  Tenant  Act  (snd  ed.)  There  are  ghat- 
wal grants  created  under  the  Mughal  rule  (as  in  Birbhum, 
and  now  in  the  Santal  Pergunnahs)  which  have  become 
proprietary  tenures,  alienable  and  governed  by  Regulation 
XXIX  of  1814,  and  Bengal  Act  V  of  1859.  Others  (as 
those  of  Kharakpur  in  Hunger)  are  on  a  different  footing  ; 
they  are  not  alienable  (without  consent  of  the  superior), 
and  the  ghatwal  may  be  dismissed  by  the  Government,  or 
the  Zamindar,  as  the  case  may  be,  for  misconduct. 

Police  ghatwals,  like  those  of  Manbhum,  are  on  a  different 
footing;  if  the  ghatwal  is  dismissed  for  misconduct,  he 
forfeits  the  holding2. 

1  For  further  details,  see  Statistical  2  See  Indian  Law  Reports,  vol.  v, 
Account,  vol.  xvi.  p.  371,  &c.  Calcutta  Series,  p.  740. 


588  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  X. — THE  TENUEES  OF  THE  SANTAL 

§  i.    General  Account. 

The  district  was  made  up  (i)  by  the  withdrawal  from 
Murshidabad  of  some  of  the  Zamindari  tracts  ;  (2)  from 
Birbhtim  of  certain  parganas  belonging  to  the  Nagu  Raja's 
estate  ;  (3)  from  the  Bhagalpur  district,  of  certain  Zamin- 
dari tracts,  as  well  as  the  hilly  territory  known  as  the 
Rajmahal  Hills,  and  formerly  called  'Jungle  Terry'  (jangal 
tarai).  The  chief  feature  of  the  district,  indeed,  is  this 
hilly  tract,  forming  a  broad  strip  beginning  at  the  Ganges 
and  extending  downwards  to  the  south-east  corner,  which 
is  indicated  on  the  map  by  a  separate  colour  showing 
it  to  be  a  '  Government  estate.'  It  is  locally  known  as 
the  Daman-i-Koh,  and  here  no  formal  recognition  of  any 
proprietary  right  has  been  made,  though,  of  course,  the 
occupants  have  all  their  interests  practically  respected  and 
recorded. 

The  Santals  colonized  this  district  about  the  middle 
of  the  last  century.  In  consequence,  the  population  is  a 
mixed  one,  although  it  is  evident  that  the  Kol  village 
system  was  generally  prevalent. 

§  2.    The  Permanently-settled  portion. 

I.  In  that  part  of  the  district  taken  from  the  older 
collectorates  on  the  east,  west,  and  north-west,  all  the  earlier 
settled  tracts  are  under  the  Permanent  Settlement,  and 
their  tenures  exhibit  no  peculiarity,  except  that  they  have 
all  been  surveyed  and  rights  recorded  under  Regulation  III 
of  1872.  Here  (as  elsewhere  under  the  Regulation)  the 

1  For  this  section  I  am  mainly  on  the  Tenures,  by  Mr.  W.  Oldham, 
indebted  to  a  Report  on  the  Settlement,  kindly  prepared  expressly  for  my 
by  Mr.  C.  W.  Bolton,  and  to  a  Note  work. 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  589 

village  headman  is  employed  to  collect  the  rents  from  his 
villagers,  unless  there  is  any  special  reason  for  allowing 
the  Zamindar  directly  to  interfere  in  the  management. 
The  village  headman  will  be  a  '  manjhi  '  in  a  Santal  village, 
a  '  pradhan '  in  other  tribal  villages,  and  a  '  mustajir '  or  a 
'  mandal '  in  the  Bengali  villages.  The  office  and  its  appur- 
tenances cannot  be  transferred  by  sale.  For  every  raiyat 
actually  cultivating  at  the  time  of  Settlement,  and  whose 
name  was  entered  in  the  Settlement  proceedings,  after  due 
inquiry,  as  the  occupant,  it  has  been  recorded  that  he  cannot 
be  ejected  without  an  order  of  Court.  This  refers  to  tenants 
who  have  not  already  a  right  of  occupancy,  so  that  all 
tenants  have  virtually  rights  of  occupancy.  A  further 
effect  has  been  that  the  tenures  so  recorded,  no  matter  of 
how  short  standing,  are  bought  and  sold  and  sub-let : 
whether  such  transfers  will  hold  good  against  the  Zamin- 
dar (or  his  rent-farmers — patnidars,  muqarraridars,  &c.)  has 
yet  to  be  decided.  But  a  portion  of  this  Zamindari  and 
Permanently- Settled  tract  may  be  distinguished  by  the 
fact  that  the  great  mass  of  the  cultivators  are  Santal  immi- 
grants. This  consists  of  the  portion  nearer  the  hills,  and 
where  there  is  much  forest  to  clear.  Here  especially,  the 
rules  about  the  headmen  as  managers,  and  the  occupancy 
rights  above  stated,  are  applicable. 

§  3.    The  Ddwian-i-Koh. 

II.  The  Da'man-i-Koh  itself  is  entirely  distinct.  It  was 
originally  occupied  by  Paharia  or  '  hill '  tribes  under  local 
chiefs  who  got  spoken  of  (though  that,  of  course,  is  only  a 
Persian  office  nomenclature)  as  '  sardars '  and  '  naibs.'  As 
early  as  1780  this  tract  was  placed  on  a  special  footing; 
no  revenue  was  demanded  from  the  Paharias,  who  roamed 
the  tops  and  sides  of  the  hills,  living  by  shifting  culti- 
vation in  the  forest  (jum1).  Government  made  a  cash 
allowance  monthly  to  support  the  'sardars'  and  'naibs'; 
and  then  left  the  land  and  all  its  products  to  the 

1  Locally  called  '  Kurowabari.' 


590  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

people,  contenting  itself  with  declaring,  but  never  other- 
wise practically  asserting,  its  own  title.  The  valleys  lay 
uncultivated  till  the  Santals  immigrated  and  established 
villages  under  their  manjhis  or  headmen :  these  have  now 
been  settled  and  their  rights  recorded  under  the  Regula- 
tion. They  are  thus  tenants  on  a  Government  estate.  The 
mdnjhi  pays  direct  to  Government,  receiving  8  per  cent,  on 
the  collections  as  his  commission. 

This  immigration  has  confined  the  Paharias  to  the  hill- 
sides. '  In  the  hills,'  says  Mr.  Oldham,  '  left  to  themselves, 
tenures  innumerable  have  grown  up  among  them.  Every 
hill  is  claimed  as  private  property  and  the  hills  are  bought 
and  sold.'  .  .  .  '  None  of  their  claims  have  been  acknow- 
ledged by  Government,  and  are  all  at  variance  with  its 
declaration  that  the  Daman-i-Koh  is  its  own  and  the  in- 
habitants its  direct  raiyats.' 

§  4.    Law  of  the  District. 

The  whole  district  called  the  '  Son  thai  (Santal)  Pergun- 
nahs '  was  removed  formally  from  the  Regulation  law  within 
the  limits  stated  in  Act  XXVII  of  1855  (amended  by  Act  X 
of  1857).  But  the  managers  of  the  several  Zamindari 
estates,  and  especially  some  of  the  contract-farmers,  had 
been  in  the  habit  of  oppressing  the  people,  by  raising  their 
rents,  and  that  even  in  the  case  of  those  who  had  cleared 
the  jungle  and  therefore  ought  to  have  been  respected.  In 
1871  the  ill-feeling  culminated  in  a  very  general  agitation. 
In  Mr.  Bolton's  report  will  be  found  in  detail  the  various 
complaints  which  the  local  inquiry  elicited l. 

It  is  to  the  credit  of  one  of  the  Zamindars,  the  Maharaja 
Gopal  Singh  of  Maheshpur,  that  some  of  the  main  sugges- 

1  As  a  specimen  it  may  be  noted  a  profit  of  over  E.  31,000).     Four 

that  a  European  contractor  from  a  years  later  the  rental  was  run  up  to 

Raja  had  (in  1267,  Bengal  era)  taken  R  1,12,296.     Granted  that  some  of 

a  seven  years'  contract  for  R.  30,052,  this  was  due  to  extended  cultivation 

the  jamabandi   or  rent-roll   being  or  legitimate  increase,  a  rental  rise 

R.  41,566.     At  the  close  of  the  lease  of  270  per  cent.in  twelve  years,  could 

he  had  run  the  rents  up  to  R  81,637.  no*    have    been     effected    without 

He   then   got   a   lease  for  another  grievous  oppression, 
seven  years  at  R.  50,  ooo  (thus  making 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  59 1 

tions  on  which  the  Regulations  of  J  872  are  based,  came  from 
him.  They  were,  that  the  whole  body  of  the  '  Regulation  ' 
laws  should  not  be  enforced1 ;  that  the  cultivator  of  a  first 
clearing  should  not  be  ousted,  but  that  the  rent  should  be 
adjusted  by  a  public  officer ;  and  that  no  cesses  beyond  the 
rent  so  fixed  should  be  levied. 

Regulation  III  of  1873  declares  what  laws  are  in  force, 
and  limits  the  interest  that  may  be  levied  on  debts  to  24 
per  cent,  as  a  maximum,  any  agreement  to  the  contrary 
being  disallowed,  and  compound  interest  in  no  case  being 
permitted.  The  interest  is  also  never  to  exceed  the  prin- 
cipal debt,  and  if  the  interest  is  for  not  more  than  a  year, 
it  is  not  to  exceed  one-fourth  of  the  principal. 

The  rest  of  the  Regulation  is  taken  up  with  the  Settle- 
ment and  record  of  rights.  The  decisions  of  the  Settlement 
Courts  are  to  have  the  force  of  decrees.  Mr.  Bolton  thus 
describes  the  chief  provisions  of  the  special  Regulation  : — 

'  The  Settlement  Officers  were  to  inquire  into,  decide  and 
record  the  rights  of  Zamiiidars  and  other  proprietors,  the  rights 
of  tenants  or  ryots,  the  rights  of  manjhees  and  other  headmen 
as  against  both  proprietors  and  tenants,  and  also  any  other 
landed  rights  to  which,  by  the  law  or  custom  of  the  country 
or  of  any  tribe,  any  person  may  have  legal  or  equitable  claims. 
The  claimants  must,  however,  have  had  possession  personally, 
or  through  others,  since  the  ist  January,  1859,  a  limitation  of 
twelve  years  being  thus  fixed.  (Section  12.) 

;  The  record  of  rights  must  show  the  nature  and  incidents 
of  the  rights  and  interests  of  each  class  of  occupiers  or  owners, 
or,  if  need  be,  of  individuals.  Notice  must  be  given  to  the 
people  on  the  Settlement  Officer  proceeding  to  a  village  to 
record  the  rights.  (Sections  13  and  14.) 

'  The  boundaries  of  each  village  must  be  demarcated,  areas 
of  waste  or  forest  beyond  the  reasonable  requirements  of  the 
village  being  excluded,  unless  one-third  of  the  total  area  of  the 
village  is  already  cultivated  or  is  fallow  in  due  course  of  agri- 
cultural rotation,  and  such  waste  or  forest  has  been  hitherto 
enjoyed  by  the  village.  (Section  15.) 

1  It  would  seem  that,  in  spite  of  later  Acts,  and  notably  Act  X  of 
Act  XXVII  of  1855,  and  partly  1859,  which  worked  great  mischief, 
owing  to  an  erroneous  legal  opinion,  were  practically  put  in  force. 


5Q2  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BKIT1SH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

'  The  Settlement  Officers  were  empowered  to  review  and 
modify  any  previous  decision  of  the  ordinary  officers  of  the 
district,  regarding  the  rights  of  manjhees  and  other  village 
headmen,  which  was  found  erroneous.  (Section  16.) 

'  With  regard  to  the  manjhees  and  other  headmen,  it  was 
laid  down  that  any  manjhee  or  headman  who  had  lost  his 
village  since  the  3ist  December,  1858,  was  entitled  to  restora- 
tion if  he  had  a  fair  and  equitable  claim  ;  and  that  he  should 
not  be  excluded  because  he  had  been  described  as  a  mustajir 
or  farmer.  The  Settlement  Officers  might  abate  the  existing 
rents  of  manjhees  or  headmen  if  they  were  inequitable,  or 
enhance  them  if  they  were  low,  the  rates  being  determined 
according  to  the  prevailing  rates  of  the  neighbourhood,  the 
number  of  ploughs  in  the  village,  and  other  relevant  matters. 
If  necessary  the  lands  might  be  measured.  (Section  17.) 

'  The  following  principles  were  to  apply  in  the  case  of 
ryots  : — 

'  (a)  Twelve  years'  possession  conferred  occupancy  rights. 
'  (&)  Eyots  who  had  acquired  occupancy  rights  before  the 
3ist  December,  1858,  to  be  restored  to  possession, 
if  justly  entitled. 

'  (c)  Eyots  to  be  held  to  have  acquired  rights  of  occupancy 

in  fields  taken  in  exchange  for  other  fields  in  the 

same  village  in  the  same  manner  as  if  no  exchange 

had  taken  place. 

'  (d)  Any  custom  regulating  the  mode  of  paying  rents  to  the 

manjhee  or  headman  to  be  recorded. 

'  (e)  The  Settlement  Officer  to  record  the  rents  of  the  ryots, 
if  they  are  fair  and  equitable.  If  they  are  not,  he 
should  inquire  into  and  re-settle  the  rents  according 
to  the  number  of  ploughs  owned  by  each  ryot,  or  the 
area  of  cultivated  land  held  by  him,  or  in  any  other 
manner  which  might  be  customary  and  equitable. 
(Section  18.) 

'  After  adjustment  and  record,  the  rents  of  both  headmen 
and  ryots  shall  remain  unchanged  for  seven  years,  and  there- 
after until  a  fresh  Settlement  or  agreement  is  made.  (Section 

'9.) 

'  In  adjusting  rents,  the  Settlement  Officer  might  take  into 
consideration  the  agricultural  skill  and  habits  of  life  of  the 
rent-payers,  or  the  fact  that  the  headmen  or  ryots,  or  those 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  593 

through  whom  they  claim,  had  reclaimed  the  land  from  forest 
or  waste.     (Sections  20  and  21.) 

'  The  instalments  of  rent  and  dates  of  payment  by  ryots 
and  manjhees  or  headmen  respectively 1  were  to  be  fixed  by 
the  Settlement  Officer,  who  was  empowered  to  alter  existing 
instalments  and  dates  if  they  pressed  hardly  on  the  people 
of  any  village.  The  amount  and  dates  of  the  instalments  are 
to  remain  unaltered  until  otherwise  ordered  by  the  Lieutenant- 
Governor.  (Section  22.) 

'  A  record  of  local  customs  on  the  following  matters  was  to 
be  drawn  up  for  eveiy  village  : — 

'  (a)  The  existence  of  the  office  of  manjhee  or  other  village 
headship,   and  the  duties  and   emoluments  of   each 
headman,  and  the  customs  of  succession  to  the  head- 
ship by  inheritance,  election,  or  otherwise. 
'  (6)  The  removal  or  suspension  of  a  headman  for  misconduct, 
and  the  appointment  or  election  to  a  vacant  headship. 
'  (c)  The  devolution   of  the  lands   held   by  proprietors    or 
under-proprietors  or  headmen,  or  cultivated  by  ryots, 
any  custom  contrary  to  the  ordinary  Hindu  or  Ma- 
homedan  law  being  noted. 

'  (d)  The  tenure  of  houses  in  the  village,  and  the  payment 
of  ground-rents  and  dues  by  non-cultivating  resi- 
dents. 

'  (e)  The  duties  and  dues  of  village  watchmen  and  other 
village  servants,  and  their  succession  to,  and  removal 
from  office. 

'  (/)  The  management  and  usufruct  of  the  waste  land,  and 
other  matters  relating  to  the  internal  arrangement  of 
villages. 

'  The  record  of  rights  must  be  published  by  being  posted 
conspicuously  in  the  village  or  otherwise,  and  persons  in- 
terested may  bring  forward  objections  in  the  original  or 
appellate  Settlement  Courts.  (Section  24.) 

'  After  one  year  from  the  date  of  publication  the  record 
of  rights  becomes  conclusive  proof  of  the  rights  and  customs 
therein  recorded,  except  in  regard  to  those  still  under  objec- 


1  It  will  be  remembered  that  the       saving  the  raiyats  from  having  to 
headmen  are  constituted   the   sole       deal  with  the  landlord's  officials, 
rent-collectors  of  their  villages,  thus 

VOL.  I.  Q  q 


594  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

tion  before  the  Settlement  Court.  Such  record  having  become 
final,  shall  riot  be  reopened  or  modified  without  the  sanction 
of  the  Lieutenant-Governor,  save  as  provided  by  the  customs 
of  the  village  ;  but  the  Lieutenant-Governor  may  order  the 
revision  of  any  material  error.'  (Section  25.) 


§  5.    Special  Land  Tenures. 

The  special  tenures  that  deserve  notice  are  the  results  of 
the  Kol  organization.  As  before  stated,  in  the  permanently- 
settled  portions  of  the  district,  we  have  Zamindars  with 
patnidars  and  other  tenure-holders  leasing  their  estates  in 
the  usual  way.  These  need  no  remark. 

A  considerable  area  of  land  is  held  by  ghatwals  who 
employ  farmers,  '  mustajirs,'  to  collect  their  rents.  The 
ghatwals  (as  far  as  they  differ  from  those  described  in 
Manbhum)  will  be  described  presently. 

Throughout  the  Zamindari  and  ghatwali  villages,  there 
are  the  usual  rent-free  taluqs  for  religious  or  personal 
service ;  lands  allotted  to  members  of  the  family  (babiiana), 
and  in  the  Deogarh  ghatwalis  '  khor-o-posh '  grants  for  the 
same  object;  and  there  are  the  village-service  lands, 
especially  those  of  the  '  Gorait,'  or  village  watchman. 

Where  the  Santal  villages  are  the  predominant  element, 
we  find  that  the  village  has  its  headman  or  '  manjhi'  (the 
heads  of  other  villages  are  called  pradhan  or  mustajir).  A 
group  of  villages,  now  called  a  'chakla'  (borrowing  the 
Persian  term),  has  a  '  pramanik '  over  it  (also  called  '  chak- 
ladar ').  A  still  higher  chief,  called  a  '  des-manjhi,'  used  to 
preside  over  the  pramaniks ;  these  have  now  no  func- 
tions, but  are  still  remembered.  The  head  of  an  entire 
'pargana'  was  called  'parganait.'  In  the  '  Daman-i-Koh ' 
his  position  was  regularly  recognized ;  he  gets  a  commission 
of  2  per  cent,  on  all  rents  punctually  paid,  and  an  allow- 
ance from  each  village.  Elsewhere  he  is  not  so  generally 
recognized,  and  sometimes  does  not  exist.  These  officials 
have  all  more  or  less  retained  lands  held  in  virtue  of 
office,  rent-free  or  lightly  assessed.  The  holding  is 


CHAP,  in.]  THE    LAND-TENURES.  595 

called  'man';  thus,  'manjhiman'  is  the  headman's  hold- 
ing1. 

In  the  Daman-i-Koh,  I  may  notice,  only  levelled  and 
prepared  rice-land  is  called  '  zamin '  (or  in  the  dialectic 
form  '  jami ').  This  is  one  of  the  many  indications  how 
little  the  soil,  as  such,  is  regarded  as  the  subject  of  pro- 
perty ;  it  is  the  cleared,  prepared,  utilizable  surface,  or,  in 
other  words,  the  use  and  productivity  of  land,  that  is 
regarded  as  the  object  of  ownership.  The  Paharia,  wander- 
ing about  and  getting  a  crop  from  the  ashes  of  the  burnt 
forest,  is  not  regarded  as  owning  any  '  land.' 

§  6.    Ghdtwdli. 

I  have  already  described  the  tenures  of  this  class  in 
Manbhum :  but  the  ghatwals  of  Deogarh  and  other  parts 
are,  in  some  respects,  peculiar,  so  that  I  may  repro- 
duce in  extenso  the  account  kindly  sent  me  by  Mr. 
Oldham : — 

'  It  was  the  practice  throughout  the  district,  and  in  the 
portions  transferred  from  Birbhum,  Bhagalpur,  or  Murshida- 
bad,  for  the  great  Zamindars  to  assign  grants  of  land,  generally 
at  the  edges  of  their  estates,  in  selected  passes  (ghats)  or  other 
spots  suited  for  forts,  to  check  the  incursions  of  the  forest 
tribes,  as  the  remuneration  of  the  person  or  family  entrusted 
with  the  guardianship  of  the  pass,  and  of  the  specified  number 
of  armed  retainers  whom  he  was  bound  to  maintain. 

*  This  was  the  general  character  of  the  ghatwali  tenure.  '  The 
grants  were  rent-free.  The  grantees  held  while  they  performed 
the  conditions  of  their  grant.  The  establishments  of  retainers 
varied  much  in  size,  according  to  the  purpose  for  which  they 
were  wanted  ;  and  the  extent  of  the  lands  assigned  varied  in 
proportion.  Some  of  the  holders  were  wardens  of  extensive 
marches,  and  their  successors  at  this  day  occupy  the  position 
of  considerable  Zamindars.  Other  grants  were  merely  for  the 
purpose  of  checking  the  ravages  of  wild  beasts  ;  one  in  par- 
ticular was  given  for  the  destruction  of  elephants. 

1  Note  that  here  we  have  the  same  idea  as  involved  in  the  watan  of 
Central  India. 

Q  q  2 


596  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

'  In  the  Bhagalpur  district  the  grants  were  considered  "  police 
lands,"  and  when  the  need  for  the  grantee's  services  passed  away, 
they  were  resumed  by  Government  and  held  for  some  time  as 
Government  estates.  One  proprietor,  however,  appealed  against 
this  mode  of  dealing  with  them,  and  the  Privy  Council  decreed 
that  he,  and  not  the  Government,  had  the  right  of  resumption  ; 
and  most  of  those  resumed  have  been  restored  and  absorbed  in 
the  Zamindaris,  of  which  they  formed  a  part. 

'  In  the  part  of  the  district  which  once  belonged  to  Birbhum, 
no  resumption  or  restoration  has  taken  place.  The  grants, 
with  an  exception  to  be  noticed,  are  of  small  extent,  and  are 
still  held  as  rent-free  lands,  and  a  nominal  service  rendered 
for  them.  Many  of  them  have  changed  hands  by  sale  and  by 
encroachment,  though  such  alienations  are  not  recognized  or 
permitted  when  known  by  Government. 

'  An  exception  to  the  ghatwali,  as  thus  generally  described, 
is  the  subdivision  of  Deogarh,  which  consists  entirely  of 
ghatwali  tenures  of  a  distinct  kind.  This  country,  which 
consisted  of  a  forest  tract,  amid  which  rise  precipitous,  isolated 
hills,  was  held  by  a  number  of  Bhiiiya  chieftains  of  an  abori- 
ginal or  semi-aboriginal  race,  and  was  conquered  by  the 
Muhammadan  sovereign  of  Birbhum  about  A.D.  1600.  The 
conquerors,  however,  were  never  able  to  bring  the  tract  into 
complete  subjection,  and  at  last  effected  a  compromise  with 
the  Bhuiya  chiefs,  under  which  the  latter  were  to  hold  half  of 
their  respective  tenures  rent-free,  on  condition  of  their  main- 
taining retainers  and  performing  the  services  of  warden  of  the 
inarches  as  above  described.  Engagements  on  both  sides  were 
never  properly  fulfilled,  and  in  A.D.  1813  the  Government 
finally  intervened  and  concluded  an  arrangement  with  the 
ghatwals  by  which  their  quota  of  rent  was  paid  directly  to 
itself,  and  they  were  still  bound  to  render  what  the  Govern- 
ment of  the  day  styled  their  police  duties. 

'  Their  system  of  sub-tenures  coincides  with  that  existing  in 
the  precisely  similar  tenures  in  the  Chutiya  Nagpur  division, 
on  which  Deogarh  abuts.  They  held  watch  and  ward,  and 
maintained  militia  and  police,  and  farmed  out  each  village  to 
a  person  called  mustajir,  on  whom  fell  fiscal  responsibilities 
only.  These  farmerships  became  hereditary,  and  consequently 
at  Settlement,  the  holders  were  unwilling  to  accept  the  lower 
status  and  more  onerous  duties,  as  well  as  the  restrictions  as  to 
sale  and  transfer,  fixed  for  the  village  headman.  They  made 


CHAP,  ill.]  THE    LAND-TENUEES.  597 

an  application  to  the  Government,  which  conceded  in  return 
the  right  of  sale  to  mustajirs  of  certain  specified  villages.1' 

1  The  British  Government  made  of  the  district  the   (Persian)  term 

certain  Ghatwali  grants  to  pensioned  mustajir  has  been  naturalized  and 

or  invalided  soldiers  on  the  banks  turned  into  mustagir  (with  the  hard 

of  the  Ganges  ;  these  are  known  as  g  instead  of.?'). 
'  Inglis  (English)  Grants.'    In  parts 


CHAPTER   IV. 

THE    RELATION    OF   LANDLORD    AND   TENANT. 

SECTION  I. — THE  LOCAL  VAKIETIES  OF  TENANTS' 
HOLDINGS. 

THE  preceding  chapter  has  dealt  with  landlord  estates 
or  those  involving  proprietary  right,  and  also  with  '  tenures,' 
technically  so  called,  which  form  a  sort  of  secondary 
class,  intermediate  between  the  first  grade  of  interest  and 
the  lowest  which  is  that  of  the  raiyat.  Properly  speak- 
ing, no  fresh  start  is  necessary  before  proceeding  to" 
describe  raiyati  rights ;  an  account  of  the  varieties  of 
these,  as  they  are  found  in  different  districts,  is  as  much  a 
part  of  our  study  of  Bengal  land-tenures,  as  is  the  descrip- 
tion of  the  Zamindar  or  the  hawaladar.  It  is  only  the  mag- 
nitude of  the  subject  and  the  necessity  for  subdivision  into 
sections,  that  makes  me  begin  a  new  '  chapter '  for  tenants 
and  their  rights.  In  reality,  a  large  number  of  the  persons 
who  have  become  legally  tenants,  but  are  still  called  by 
the  old  name  of  raiyat,  were  the  original  soil-owners  of.  at 
any  rate,  their  individual  holdings.  Their  present  position 
is  due  partly  to  their  own  decay,  partly  to  the  gradual 
overlaying  of  their  rights  by  the  growth  of  the  '  Zamin- 
dars ' ;  it  is  therefore  necessary  to  bear  in  mind  that  in 
Bengal,  as  in  other  parts  of  India,  we  must  not  be  surprised 
to  find  '  tenants '  many  of  whom  owe  their  position  to  no 
kind  of  contract  with  any  landlord  whatsoever.  That  is 
a  main  point  to  be  borne  in  mind.  We  may  now  proceed 


CHAP,  iv.]  THE  KELATION  OF  LANDLOKD  AND  TENANT.  599 

to  notice  some  of  the  local  forms  of  raiyati  tenure,  and 
then  proceed  to  the  history  of  the  relations  of  landlord  and 
tenant,  and  to  the  provisions  of  law  actually  in  force. 
And  first  of  certain  very  common  terms  describing  tenants 
generally. 

§  i.    Main  Classes  of  Tenants. 

In  the  ordinary  revenue  language,  but  hardly  in  the 
common  speech  of  the  people,  tenants  in  the  Permanently 
Settled  districts  were  spoken  of  in  two  classes — '  khudkdsht ' 
and  '  pahi-kdsht.'  Khudkdsht  properly  means  a  man  who 
cultivates  his  own  land ;  and,  in  reality,  it  points  back  to 
a  time  before  the  Zamindars'  time,  when  the  village  cul- 
tivator was  either  a  member  of  a  body  which  had  cleared 
the  waste  and  established  the  village,  or  had  become,  by 
conquest  or  grant  at  some  remote  date,  the  virtual  owner 
of  it.  Where  such  persons  were  of  a  cultivating  caste  and 
worked  their  own  holdings  personally  or  with  the  aid  of 
their  servants,  they  were  said  to  be  '  khudkashfc,'  or  cul- 
tivating their  own.  But  there  were  always  others  in  the 
village  who,  though  not  on  the  same  footing,  were  never- 
theless resident  and  privileged  cultivators,  just  as  we  see  in 
Panjab  villages  at  the  present  day.  When  the  proprietary 
right  of  the  village  cultivators  became  lost  or  obscured  by 
the  turmoils  of  the  times  and  the  influence  of  overlords, 
both  the  original  village  owners  and  their  resident  help- 
mates became  practically  undistinguished,  and  were  called 
raiyats  under  the  Zamindar ;  but  as  both  were  by  custom 
privileged,  and  were  not  liable  to  eviction,  both  came  to  be 
equally  called  '  khudkasht ' — with  a  slight  change  of  mean- 
ing, for  the  word  now  implied  tenants  '  cultivating  in  their 
own  village.'  The  '  thani '  (or  sthani)  cultivator  is  only  a 
Hindi  name  for  exactly  the  same  thing ;  and  '  chappar- 
band,'  the  man  who  has  his  'roof  or  house  'fixed'  in  the 
village,  is  also  the  same.  Pahi-  or  pai-kasht  meant  a  man 
who  came  from  abroad  and  took  up  land  to  cultivate 
without  belonging  to  the  village  permanently.  He  retained 


6OO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP    BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

the  appellation  of  origin,  even  though  he  in  fact  continued 
to  till  the  land  year  after  year. 

As  the  modern  tenant-law  has  given  privileges,  after  a 
lapse  of  years,  to  the  '  pahi '  cultivators  as  well  as  to  the 
khudkasht,  the  distinction  found  in  the  Regulations  and  in 
the  older  reports  has  ceased  to  be  of  practical  import,  and 
has  given  place  to  the  legal  distinction  of  '  occupancy '  and 
'  non-occupancy '  raiyat. 

§  2.    Local  Names  for  Tenants. 

The  common  local  names  for  tenants  are  various.  '  Jot ' 
is  a  term  commonly  used  for  any  tenancy  *,  especially  in 
the  Bihar  districts,  where  it  has  not  the  special  meaning 
explained  (in  Chap.  III.  Sec.  VI.  §  C,  p.  546).  'Praja'  is 
a  common  word  for  tenant,  and  also  '  karsha '  (Sansk. 
krishan). 

As  regards  the  term  'jot,'  Mr.  Cotton  remarks  that  it  is 
used  with  the  most  elastic  application.  It  has  already 
been  stated  that  in  Jessore  it  means  a  class  of  persons  who 
are  in  fact  substantial  tenure-holders  with  an  acknow- 
ledged right  to  hold  at  fixed  rates;  and  so  it  is  explained 
in  the  district  of  Rangpur.  In  general  the  raiyat  who 
holds  direct  from  the  landlord  is  called  'jotdar,'  and  his 
holding  is  a  'jot,'  whatever  its  size,  and  which  may,  and 
does,  vary  from  one  paying  a  rent  of  one  rupee  to  one  of 
which  the  rent  is  half  a  lakh 2.  It  will  then  be  remem- 
bered that  'jot'  may  be  either  a  '  tenure '  or  a  raiyati 
(tenant)  holding  according  to  locality. 

§  3.    Hdl-hdsila. 

In  the  Bhagalpur  division  a  form  of  tenancy  is  spoken  of 
as  ' hal-hasila '  (which  means  'what  has  been  realized  for 

1  R.  and  F.  Ten.  Act,  p.  33.  house  and  garden  and  paddy-fields. 

2  The  term '  jot-jama' '  merely  im-  The  rent  is  '  be-miyadi,'  without  a 
plies  that  a  lump  rent  is  fixed  on  fixed  term,  or  'miyadi,'  for  a  term, 
the  whole  holding,  say,  of  five  to  or '  sarasar,' fixed  from  time  to  time, 
ten   bighas,   including  the   site   of  and  so  on. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.     6oi 

the  time  being,  or  actually ').  This  almost  explains  that 
the  tenant  is  only  bound  to  pay  according  to  the  crop 
which  actually  comes  to  maturity.  The  tenant  cultivates 
such  lands  in  the  holding  as  he  judges  best,  so  that  the 
fields  occupied  and  the  rent,  vary  from  year  to  year ;  but  it 
is  understood  that  the  tenure  is  a  continuing  one.  Certain 
rates  for  each  crop,  called  '  bera,'  are  known ;  and  at  the 
close  of  the  year,  the  account  is  made  out  by  taking  the 
area  of  crops  of  different  kinds  matured ,  and  working  out 
the  rent  by  aid  of  the  '  bera '  or  rates  *. 

So  much  of  the  holding  as  is  left  fallow  is  either  not 
paid  for  at  all  or  according  to  a  '  fallow '  rate,  as  may  be 
agreed  on  ;  but  it  will  be  observed  that,  whether  fallow  or 
not,  the  entire  area  is  at  the  disposal  of  the  tenant.  The 
landlord  has  no  power  to  hand  over  to  some  other  person 
such  fields  as  the  tenant  has  not  elected  to  plough  up.  It 
is  said  that  these  tenures  are  held  by  the  higher  castes, 
and  that,  in  some  cases,  they  are  regarded  as  transferable, 
having  been  sold  in  executing  decrees. 

A  modern  form  of  this,  only  on  a  yearly  agreement,  is 
found  on  the  banks  of  the  Ganges  and  Kiisi  rivers,  by 
non-resident  cultivators,  locally  called  '  dotwar  V 

§  4.    Otbandi  or  utbandi  3. 

This  is  a  new  form  of  temporary  contract  tenancy,  and 
only  resembles  '  the  hal-hasila,'  which  is  a  permanent 
tenancy,  in  this  one  particular,  that  the  rent  depends  on 
the  area  cultivated,  and  on  the  actual  crop  raised ;  nothing 
is  paid  for  the  fallow,  if,  as  in  some  cases,  the  utbandi 

1  There  is  a  more  extended  account       in  the  following  note). 

in  the  Statistical  Account  (Purneah\  3  Commonly    written   '  utbandi.' 

vol.  xv.  p.  324,  and  Malda  (vol.  vii.  Wilson  gives  it  .as  a  Marathi  word 

p.  81).     The  questions  there  raised  Aiit,  a  plough,  from  Sanscrit  ayudh, 

about  an  occupancy-right  accruing,  a  weapon.     But  Platt,  with  much 

are  all  set  at  rest  by  Act  VIII  of  more  probability,  spells  it 'ot,' which 

1885,  under  which  it  is  not  needed  means   a    '  scotch  '  (to  fix  a   thing 

that  the  very   same    plots   should  down)  ;  and  hence  a  fixed  rate  for 

have  been  continuously  held.  the   use   of  a  plough  and   pair   of 

2  Unless  the  name  is  (as  I  suspect)  bullocks. 
a  misprint  for  aotwar  or  otwar  ^as 


602  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

raiyat  holds  for  two  or  three  years  ;  for  it  is  a  local  feature 
that  the  land  (owing  to  its  infertility)  must  be  given  rest. 
This  form  of  tenancy  is  commonest  in  Nadiya,  but  is  found 
in  Jessore,  Murshidabad,  and  in  Pabna  under  the  name  of 
'  Uthitpatit '  or  '  charcha  jot.'  It  is  said  that  'jama'i' 
raiyats — i.e.  tenants  paying  a  lump  rental  for  their  hold- 
ing— pay  at  rates  about  half  as  high  as  those  which  are 
paid  by  utbandi  raiyats  on  their  actual  cultivation. 

§  5-    Grain-tenants. 

Before  closing  the  notice  of  varieties  of  tenant,  I  must 
mention  the  '  bhaoli '  or  grain-paying  system  of  Bihar. 
The  process  of  division  is  much  the  same  as  it  is  in  the 
Panjab,  or  any  other  place  where  it  survives,  or  had  sur- 
vived till  of  late  years.  As  usual,  the  grain  division  is 
effected  either  by  weighing  out  the  grain  at  the  threshing- 
floor  (agor-batai),  or  by  appraising  the  standing  crop  (dana- 
bandi),  in  which  case  the  tenant  makes  over  as  many 
maunds  of  the  grain  as  it  was  estimated  would  be  the 
share  in  the  field  as  it  stood.  It  is  surprising  how  accurate 
an  appraisement  of  this  sort  can  be  when  made  by  persons 
accustomed  to  the  work. 

In  Gaya,  it  is  said,  four-fifths  of  the  land  is  held  on 
grain-paying  tenures.  I  have  found  a  report  on  these 
tenures  written  by  Babu  Bhub-Sen  Singh,  of  Gay^i,  which 
graphically  describes  them1: — 

'  It  is  the  distinctive  feature  of  the  grain-rents  that  the 
payment  consists  not  in  any  fixed  quantity  but  in  a  fixed  pro- 
portion of  the  actual  out-turn  of  the  crops  grown.  The  rent, 
paid  or  payable  accordingly  varies  from  year  to  year.  The 
land  is  tilled  and  the  seed  sown  is  supplied  by  the  raiyat  or  at 

1  Report  on  the  Rent  Bill  in  1884.  whom  the  *  Zamindar  maintains,'  is 
The  account  is  also  curious  as  it  is  one  of  the  regular  servants  of  the 
written  from  a  strongly  landlord  village  community,  and  that  the 
point  of  view.  When  it  is  recol-  Zamindar  was  always  bound  to  keep 
lected  that  a  large  proportion  of  the  the  embankments,  the  author  cer- 
bhaoli  tenants  are  what  was  once,  tainly  does  not  underrate  the  land- 
in  byegone  days,  the  village  pro-  lord's  equitable  interest  in  the  cul- 
prietary  body,  and  that  the  '  gorait '  tivation. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.     603 

his  cost— the  cost  of  hoeing  and  transplanting,  of  weeding  and 
clearing,  being  also  borne  by  him.  But  the  water  is  supplied  by 
the  landlord  at  his  own  cost.  The  cost  of  gilandazi  (throwing 
up  of  earth),  division  of  lands  into  plots,  by  al  and  ail  (ridges) 
according  to  their  levels,  for  the  storage  of  the  necessary 
quantity  of  water,  and  of  erecting  embankments  on  the  banks 
of  rivers  for  the  protection  of  the  villages  from  being  over- 
flooded,  are  exclusively  paid  by  him.  In  dry  years,  when 
water  cannot  be  supplied  from  rivers  and  village  reservoirs 
and  artificial  water-courses,  he  pays  the  raiyat  the  cost  of 
sinking  wells.  It  is  not  only  that  the  landlord  supplies  water 
for  irrigation,  but  as  the  rise  or  fall  in  his  income  depends 
upon  the  increase  or  decrease  in  the  produce  of  the  lands,  he 
naturally  shows  as  much  anxiety  and  takes  as  much  care  in 
the  proper  and  timely  ploughing  thereof,  as  he  would  have 
done  had  he  been  a  cultivator  himself ;  and  his  servants  are 
always  found  to  be  busy  in  superintending  the  tilling  of  the 
soil,  the  sowing  of  the  seed,  the  transplanting  of  the  rice,  and 
so  forth,  according  as  the  case  may  be. 

'  If  the  raiyat' s  bullock  happens  to  die  in  the  ploughing 
season,  and  the  raiyat  is  unable  to  procure  one  in  its  stead, 
the  Zammdar  would  come  forward  and  help  him  with  one, 
even  at  the  risk  of  running  into  debt,  if  he  is  poor.  Seed  is 
also  supplied  by  him  in  the  same  way.  For  similar  reasons, 
the  landlord  is  interested  in  seeing  that  the  best  crops  are 
grown  upon  the  land  it  is  capable  of  producing.  No  raiyat  has 
the  right  to  sow  any  crop  inferior  to  what  the  land  is  capable 
of  producing,  nor  can  he  be  allowed,  without  the  express 
consent  of  his  landlord,  to  grow  crops  for  which,  by  the  custom 
of  the  country,  a  cash  rent  is  paid,  or  which  are  incapable  of 
being  appraised  or  stored  in  the  threshing-floor  or  barn  for 
division.  From  the  time  the  crops  are  sown  to  the  time  they 
are  appraised  and  stored,  the  landlord  watches  the  crops  with 
keen  interest  and  protects  them  from  being  wasted  or  other- 
wise injured  by  men  or  cattle.  For  this  purpose  he  has  to 
maintain  an  establishment  of  Barahils  and  Goraits,  the  former 
of  whom  receive  their  salary  from,  the  Zammdar,  .... 
while  the  latter  are  remunerated  by  the  Zammdar  with  rent- 
free  land '  [and  some  grain-payment  which  is  exacted  from  the 
tenants].  ;  This  kind  of  tenure,  it  may  be  remarked  en  passant, 
is  a  peculiar  one  and  has  not  its  like  anywhere  else  either  in 


604  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

Asia  or  Europe  :  and  it  would  be  a  mistake  to  compare  it  with 
the  European  metayer  system  and  to  condemn  it  as  having  all 
the  evils  of  that  system  without  any  of  its  advantages*.  .  .  . 

1  The  "  bhaoli  "  crops  are  by  custom  and  the  circumstances 
under  which  they  are  grown,  regarded  by  the  parties  concerned 
as  their  joint  property.'  [!]  .  .  .  'The  whole  of  the  straw 
and  the  chaff,  which  are  not  without  value,  goes  to  the  raiyats. 
It  is  only  out  of  the  grain-produce  that  the  Zamindar  gets  a 
share  which,  though  everywhere  more  than  half,  is  different  in 
different  parganas,  and  almost  in  different  villages,  and  which 
again  varies  with  the  different  classes  of  raiyats,  whether 
Ra'iyan  or  Shurfa 2,  the  former  delivering  a  higher  and  the 
latter  a  lower  share  :  and  we  shall  be  very  near  the  true  figure 
when  we  state  that  the  Zamindar's  share,  with  the  customary 
abwabs  or  cesses,  is  T9g-  of  the  grain-produce.  But,  if  the  value 
of  the  straw  and  the  chaff,  which  are,  in  these  days,  as  much 
valuable  commodities  as  grain,  be  taken  into  consideration,  the 
highest  share  which  the  Zamindar  gets  in  lieu  of  rent,  would 
be  much  less  than  even  half  of  the  total  gross  produce.  The 
value  of  the  straw  and  chaff  may  fairly  be  assumed  to  be  one- 
third  of  the  grain-produce. ' 

'  As  soon  as  the  crops  are  ripe  for  harvesting,  the  Zamfndar 
deputes  an  amin  (assessor)  and  a  sdlis  (arbitrator)  to  make  an 
estimate  of  the  grain-produce.  In  the  presence  of  these  officers, 
the  raiyats,  the  village  gomdsta,  the  patwari,  and  the  jeth  (head- 
man of  raiyats),  who  generally  knows  how  to  read  and  write, 
representing  and  watching  the  interests  of  the  raiyats ;  the 
village  chainman,  called  Jcathdddr  (holder  of  the  rod  or  bam- 
boo), measures  the  field  with  the  village  bamboo,  which  in  this 
district  is  nowhere  less  than  8  feet  3  inches  or  more  than  9 
feet  in  length.  The  sdlis  then  goes  round  the  field,  and  from 
his  experience  guesses  out  the  probable  quantity  of  the  grain 
in  the  fields,  holds  a  consultation  with  the  amin  and  the 
village  officers,  and  when  the  quantity  is  unanimously  agreed 
upon,  it  is  made  known  to  the  raiyat.  If  he  accepts  the 
estimate  so  arrived  at,  the  quantity  is  entered  by  the  patwari 

1  I  should  have  thought  that  the  2  Ra'iyan  are  ordinary  'subjects.' 

author's  own  description  fully  jus-  Shurfa  are  the  higher  castes  (from 

tified  the  condemnation  in  italics,  sharif=  noble),    very  often    ex-pro- 

which,  if  I  recollect  rightly,  is  Dr.  prietors. 
Field's ! 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     605 

in  the  Jchasra  or  field-book.  If  he  objects,  other  raiyats  are 
called  in  to  act  as  mediators,  and  if  they  fail  to  convince  either 
party,  a  partdl  or  test  takes  place.  On  behalf  of  the  landlord, 
a  portion  of  the  best  part  of  the  crops  is  reaped,  and  an  equal 
portion  of  the  worst  part  is  reaped  on  behalf  of  the  raiyat. 
The  two  portions  so  reaped  are  threshed  and  the  grain  weighed. 
On  the  quantity  thus  ascertained,  the  whole  produce  of  the 
field  is  calculated  and  entered  in  the  Jchasra.  From  the  time 
the  estimate  is  made,  the  Zammdar  withdraws  his  supervision 
from  the  crops,  which  are  then  left  in  the  exclusive  charge  and 
possession  of  the  tenant. '  .  .  .  '  After  the  appraisement  of  the 
field,  the  raiyat  is  allowed  the  full  liberty  of  reaping  the  crops 
and  taking  them  home  at  any  time  that  may  suit  his  con- 
venience. Out  of  the  estimated  quantity,  a  deduction  at  the 
rate  of  two  seers  per  maund  is  allowed  to  the  raiyat,  which  is 
called  chhuthi  (let  off).  I  have  not  been  able  to  ascertain  the 
exact  reason  for  which  this  allowance  is  made.  But,  as  in  the 
agorbatdi,  the  reapers  who  also  thresh  out  the  grain  are  paid 
from  the  joint  crop,  I  presume  this  is  allowed  to  the  raiyat  to 
meet  the  cost  of  reaping,  gathering,  and  threshing.  The  land- 
lord's share  is  then  calculated  on  the  quantity  left  after  the 
chhuthi  has  been  deducted,' 

The  writer,  however,  goes  on  to  describe  how  the  land- 
lord exacts  several  cesses  (here  called  '  hubub '),  which 
include  the  dah-haq,  which  is  an  extra  '  tenth '  (4  seers  in 
the  maund),  besides  pan-sera  (-J-  seer),  '  nocha,'  and  others. 
With  these  he  says  'the  Zamindar's  total  shark  would 
come  to,  in  some  cases,  a  little  less,  and  in  others  a  little 
more,  than  TnF. 

§  6.    Sub-tenants. 

When  the  tenant's  holding  is  of  considerable  size  and 
importance,  it  is  not  surprising  that  sub-letting  should  be 
usual.  The  commonest  name  for  a  tenant's  tenant,  or 
under-raiyat,  is,  perhaps,  '  kurpha '  (often  written  '  koorfa,' 
&c.) l.  A  sub-tenant  paying  grain  is  called  bargait  or 

1  As  the  term  is  supposed  to  be  of  in  these  languages,  must  be  wrong  ; 
Hindi  or  Bengali  origin,  of  course  but  I  believe  it  is  not  settled  what 
the  letter  '  f,'  which  does  not  occur  the  real  derivation  of  the  term  is. 


606  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

adhiyadar.  The  term  '  shikmi '  is  used  for  under-tenants, 
but  not  in  Gaya,  where  it  means  a  kind  of  money-paying 
tenant  who  is  permanent,  and  probably  refers  to  the  class 
of  tenant  who  was  not  on  equal  terms  with  the  descendants 
of  original  village  settlers,  though  privileged  as  long  resident 
and  settled. 

§  7.    Local  terms  for  Tenants. 

Where  there  are  special  terms  for  '  tenures,'  or  for  raiyati 
holdings,  there  are  also  special  terms  for  tenants  or  sub- 
tenants ;  as,  for  instance,  the  chukanidar  under  the  jotdar 
in  Rangpur  and  other  districts,  and  the  kol-karsh£dar  in 
Bakirganj.  For  a  variety  of  terms  which  I  do  not  think 
it  would  be  interesting  to  reproduce,  as  merely  indicating 
kinds  of  contract,  it  will  be  sufficient  to  refer  to  the  note 
at  p.  35  of  Finucane  and  Rampini's  Tenancy  Act. 


§  8.    Tenancies  in  Waste-land  clearings. 

Chittagong  presents  to  us  certain  peculiarities  in  the 
system  of  tenancy  which  deserve  to  be  noticed,  because 
they  throw  light  on  the  difficulties  of  a  tenant  law,  and 
how  provisions  which  may  be  effective  in  one  place,  and 
under  one  set  of  circumstances,  fail  to  apply  in  another. 
The  account  that  has  been  given  both  of  land-tenures  and 
of  the  method  of  land-revenue  Settlement  adopted  in  this 
district,  will  have  made  the  subject  so  far  familiar  that 
what  follows  will  be  intelligible.  We  have,  in  fact,  a 
country  where  land  is  extremely  abundant  in  proportion 
to  tenants,  and  where  there  is  indeed  never  likely  to  be 
much  pressure,  because  the  neighbouring  district  of  Arakan 
is  still  a  virgin  wilderness  to  a  great  extent,  and,  like  so 
much  of  Burma  generally,  only  awaits  the  overflow  of 
population  to  turn  it  into  a  source  of  wealth  to  the  agri- 
culturist. Not  only  is  land  abundant,  but  it  is  held  in 
small  patches  which  are  still  distinguished  by  the  names 
of  origin.  The  taluq  is  the  individual  holding,  whether 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     607 

old-settled  revenue-free,  assessed  (i.  e.  resumed)  revenue- 
free,  or  nauabad.  The  result  is  (i)  that  every  one  ekes  out 
his  subsistence  by  taking,  as  a  tenant,  some  patch  of  land 
belonging  to  another ;  (2)  that  every  one  desires  to  have  some 
land  of  which  he  is  owner,  or  at  least  permanent  tenure- 
holder  (qaimi),  because  that  gives  him  the  poiver  of  letting 
•it  out.  A  mere  occupancy- right  is  not  valued ;  for  it  does 
not  enable  a  man  to  get  land  on  any  better  terms  than 
circumstances  always  secure  for  him  as  a  casual  tenant ; 
while  of  itself  it  is  not  a  right  which  enables  him  to  let 
the  plot  and  get  money  by  it. 

A  considerable  portion  of  the  cultivation  is  in  the  hands 
of  tenants-at-will,  called  (as  usual)  'jotdar '  or  '  chasa,'  or 
sometimes '  karshai-raiyat '  (karsha  =  plough).  And  of  course 
a  man  may  be  a  '  chasa '  tenant  on  one  plot,  while  he  is 
owner  (or  taluqdar)  of  another. 

'  Settlements  with  the  cultivators '  (writes  Mr.  Lowis,  the 
Commissioner1)  'are  made  in  March  or  April,  when  each 
jotdar  settles  what  rent  is  to  be  paid  for  the  land  he  proposes 
to  cultivate,  the  rate  being  governed  by  the  state  of  the  rice 
market  and  the  demand  for  the  land.  .  .  .  Sometimes  written 
engagements  are  taken,  but  as  often  as  not  the  arrangement  is 
verbal.  It  is  not  absolutely  necessary  that  a  fresh  engagement 
should  be  entered  into  every  year.  When  a  chasa  has  held 
the  same  land  for  several  years,  he  is  allowed  to  hold  on  at  the 
old  rate  without  attending  at  the  cutcherry  to  settle  afresh. 
...  It  is  always  assumed,  however,  by  both  parties  that,  on 
the  occasion  of  a  marked  rise  or  fall  in  the  price  of  rice,  there 
shall  be  a  corresponding  change  in  the  rent,  after  mutual 
discussion.' 

A  trusted  chasa — 

'  will  be  allowed  to  hold  on  for  some  years  without  a  fresh 
agreement,  while  a  new  man  will  be  required  to  attend  at  the 
beginning  of  each  season  to  settle  his  rent.' 

In  many  cases  rents  are  settled  only  for  one  year,  and  at 
the  end  of  it  either  party  is  at  liberty  to  dissolve  the  con- 

1  Commissioner  of  Chittagoug  to  Board  of  Revenue,  No.  72  C.T., 
dated  8th  December,  1882. 


608  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

nection.  Such  a  system,  Mr.  Lowis  remarks,  would,  on  a 
large  estate,  result  in  rack-renting  ;  but  it  does  not  here,  as 
the  tenant  is  independent,  owing  to  the  small  size  of  the 
holdings  ;  and  if  he  cannot  get  one  bit  on  terms  that  suits 
him,  it  is  no  question  of  breaking  up  his  home  and  going  to 
a  distant  village — he  is  sure  to  find  another,  or  half  a  dozen 
other  plots,  within  a  stone's  throw,  the  owners  of  which  are 
only  too  anxious  to  secure  him.  A  man  is  not  absolutely 
bound  to  get  land  or  starve  ;  he  is  pretty  sure  to  have  some 
of  his  own,  by  which  he  can  live  ;  and  if  he  does  not  get 
extra  land  on  a  tenancy  as  it  pleases  him,  he  can  afford  to 
let  it  alone. 

The  taluqdars  have  thus  the  complete  control  of  the  land, 
but  subject  to  conditions  which  compel  moderation ;  the 
tenants  prefer  to  be  free  also.  '  The  taluqdars,'  says  the 
Collector  regarding  the  Kutabdiya  estates, — 

'  argued  that  no  terms  whatever  could  pay  them  if  the  control 
of  the  land  were  taken  out  of  their  hands  and  the  cultivators 
under  them  were  recorded  with  fixed  rights.  The  reason  of 
this  is,  that  the  cultivators  under  them  cannot  be  relied  on  for 
a  fixed  rent  year  by  year.  They  prefer  to  pay  heavily  on  a 
good  crop  and  lightly  in  a  year  when  they  have  reaped  less  or 
got  lower  prices,  or  have  left  a  larger  area  uncultivated.  More- 
over, each  taluq  has  its  own  small  embankments,  and  the 
taluqdars  must  be  entitled  to  demand  the  labour  of  the 
cultivators  to  ensure  these  being  kept  up.  In  short,  the 
cultivators  do  not  want  fixity  of  tenure,  and  it  would  be  ruinous 
to  the  taluqdars  if  it  were  given  to  them. ' 

§  9.    Alluvial  Tenancies  in  Noakhdli  district. 

Noakhali  is  another  district  where  land  is  abundant, 
owing  to  the  constant  formation  of  more  or  less  rich  silt 
islands  or  'chars  '  out  of  the  river- branches  that  intersect 
the  district. 

These  '  chars,'  of  course,  vary  in  their  durability :  some 
last  but  a  short  time  ;  some  remain  for  many  years,  or  per- 
manently. Most  of  the  recent  chars,  and  even  much  land 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     609 

on  the  older  ones,  is  cultivated  by  ' jotdars  '  on  a  purely 
annual  tenancy.  Tenants  of  this  class  will  come  at  the 
proper  time  to  the  office  of  the  hawdladdr  or  other  tenure- 
holder,  and  offer  to  take  a  certain  plot,  at  a  rate  which 
varies,  and  depends  on  the  quality  of  the  land  and  its 
advantages.  The  agreement  being  completed,  the  tenant 
passes  a  plough-furrow  across  the  land,  as  the  sign  of  his 
taking  possession. 

The  Commissioner  writes  as  follows T  :— 

'  For  the  first  ten  or  even  twenty  years  of  its  existence,  a 
char  is  thus  cultivated  by  jotdars  pure  and  simple, — non- 
resident, nomadic,  and  unsettled.  Gradually,  however,  some  of 
them  settle  near  their  cultivation,  and  come  to  be  looked  on 
as  settled -raiyats,  who  hold  at  some  sort  of  fixed  rate  of  rent. 
There  is  a  rate  for  settled-raiyats,  and  this  is  not  usually 
altered  ;  but  even  a  settled-raiyat  often  sits  loose  to  his  hold- 
ing, and  so  a  custom  has  become  recognized  that  he  should  be 
allowed  some  remission  in  a  bad  season,  and  should  not  be 
expected  to  pay  for  land  not  cultivated. 

'  This  rule  is  not  invariable,  but  I  am  led  to  believe  that  in 
a  bad  season,  after  some  haggling,  a  settled-raiyat  does  gene- 
rally get  some  remission,  while  in  a  good  season  he  has  to  pay 
something  extra  in  one  shape  or  another  ;  in  either  case  the 
rate  is  not  altered,  but  the  arrangements  made  are  the  result 
of  mutual  compromise. 

'There  is  very  little  actual  difference  between  a  settled- 
raiyat  and  a  jotdar.  They  neither  of  them  hold  under  leases  ; 
the  usual  rate  for  both  is  about  the  same  :  only  the  jotdari 
rent  is  admittedly  variable  ;  that  of  the  settled-raiyat  is  not 
variable,  but — which  comes  to  much  the  same  thing — he  can 
generally  get  some  remission  when  things  are  bad. 

'  There  has  always  been  more  land  to  be  cultivated  on  the 
islands  than  cultivators ;  and  land  once  cultivated  so  soon  gets 
covered  with  rank  vegetation — all  the  ranker  for  the  earth 
having  once  been  opened  up — that  cultivators  are  in  demand, 
and  have  always  been  able  pretty  well  to  dictate  their  own 
terms  ;  while  the  facilities  for  obtaining  fresh  land  rent-free, 
or  at  low  rates,  have  induced  unsettled  and  nomadic  habits,  so 

1  To  Board  of  Kevenue,  No.  116  similar  state  of  things  is  described 
C.T.,  dated  nth  February,  1882.  A  in  Tipperah  (Tipra). 

VOL.  I.  B  r 


6lO  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 

that  even  where  cultivators  have  been  for  a  considerable  period 
apparently  settled,  the  hawaladar  knows  that  they  sit  very 
loose  to  the  holding,  and,  if  discontented,  are  apt  to  abandon 
them  in  order  to  acquire  land  elsewhere.' 

§  10.  Comparison  of  this  class  of  Tenancy  with  the  state  of 
Tenancies  generally  at  the  Permanent  Settlement. 

Mr.  J.  S.  Cotton  compares  the  present  state  of  things  in 
the  alluvial  districts  to  the  condition  of  the  '  pahi-kasht,'  or 
casual  or  non-resident  tenants  generally,  at  the  time  of  the 
Permanent  Settlement ;  and  the  existence  of  such  con- 
ditions no  doubt  largely  contributed  to  the  old  belief  that 
the  relations  of  landlord  and  tenant  (generally)  would  settle 
themselves — a  belief  which  resulted  in  the  silence  of  the 
Regulations  as  to  any  definite  terms  of  protection. 

'The  country  was  then  three  parts  waste,  still  slowly  re- 
covering from  the  effects  of  famine.  The  demand  was  on  all 
sides  for  raiyats  to  bring  the  land  under  cultivation  ;  the  rates 
of  rent  were  uniformly  low,  since,  as  soon  as  the  demand  was 
raised  above  what  the  raiyat  chose  to  pay,  he  would  migrate  to 
the  lands  of  a  neighbouring  landlord1.' 

But  as  time  passed,  this  state  of  things  gradually  ceased, 
and  in  the  end  Government  was  obliged  to  devise  protec- 
tive measures,  which  it  did  in  1859,  and  again  in  1885. 

'  But  in  Chittagong,  and  throughout  the  new  alluvial  for- 
mations of  Noakhali  and  Tipperah,  population  is  still  sparse, 
land  still  plentiful,  and  the  demand  is  still  for  raiyats  to  bring 
land  under  cultivation.'  .  .  . 

'  There  is  no  rack-renting  in  Chittagong,  for  there  is  always 
the  probability  that  if  the  rent  is  fixed  too  high  the  land  may 
not  be  taken  up ;  and  if  not  engaged  for,  the  loss  would,  of 
course,  fall  on  the  taluqdar  or  hawaladar,  as  the  case  may  be. 

1  The  Chittagong  raiyats  are,  in  short,  entirely  independent 

1  And   this  to  the    'pahi-kasht'  packed  up  h  is  fofci(drinking-pot)  and 

was  not  what  a  removal  would  be  his  bedding   and   few  moveables ; 

to  an  old  resident  of  a  village.  There  and  as  to  his  hut,  a  frame  of  mud 

was  no  breaking  up  of  an  ancestral  and  bamboos  and  a  thatch  roof  is 

home — even  though  a  humble  one —  easily  renewed  in  one  place  as  well 

and  severing  lifelong  ties  and  asso-  as  another, 
ciations ;    the  casual   tenant,  soon 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLOKD  AND  TENANT.     6 1  I 

of  the  influence  and  interference  of  their  landlords,  and  cultivate 
as  they  please  on  a  yearly  tenure.  It  is  not  surprising  that 
under  such  circumstances  they  do  not  attach  much  importance 
to  the  right  of  occupancy  as  our  law  defines  it.  They  are 
naturally  indisposed  to  bind  themselves  definitely  to  a  parti- 
cular plot  of  land  for  which  they  will  have  to  pay  rent  whether 
they  cultivate  it  or  not.  Their  real  ambition  is  to  get  a 
permanent  lease  ['tenure ']  and  then  to  let  this  to  other  raiyats 
for  cultivation  ;  but,  if  they  cannot  get  this,  they  prefer  to  make 
their  own  terms  with  their  landlord  for  such  lands  as  they  may 
themselves  cultivate. 

'  A  similar  state  of  things  exists  in  the  Dwars  1  of  Jalpaiguri, 
where  so  much  land  is  available  that  an  under-tenant  who  feels 
himself  aggrieved  will  at  once  desert  his  holding  and  take  up 
other  land. 

'  It  is  the  same  in  the  estates  belonging  to  the  Jaipur 
Government 2  in  the  district  of  Bogra  (Bagura).  Owing  to  the 
abundance  of  fallow  and  waste  land  in  this  part  of  the  country, 
the  raiyats  seldom  occupy  the  same  holding  for  any  lengthened 
period,  and  rights  of  occupancy  are  almost  entirely  unknown. 
The  Zamindars  compete  for  raiyats,  and  "the  latter  are  almost 
masters  of  the  situation. "  The  figures  given  by  Mr.  Macpherson 
in  paragraph  8  of  his  report  show  that  nearly  10  per  cent,  of 
the  holdings  on  these  estates  had  been  vacated  during  the  three 
years,  1879-80  to  1881-82,  and  no  less  than  1,320  bi'ghas,  which 
were  cultivated  three  years  before,  had  gone  out  of  cultivation. 
The  amount  of  new  land  taken  under  cultivation  had  prevented 
the  rental  of  the  estates  from  being  reduced  by  more  than  K.  48; 
but  the  results  vary  considerably  in  different  villages,  and 
from  year  to  year.' 

1  Commissioner  to  Board,  No.  868,  2  Mr.  Macpherson's  report  to  the 

dated  and  March,  1878,  paragraph  Board,  No.  61,  dated  22  Jan.  1883. 

ii  ;  and  Board  to  Government,  No.  paragraph  4,  published  on  p.  201  of 

211  A.,    dated    2^th   March,    1878,  the  Selections  from  the  correspondence  on 

paragraph  12.  the  preparation  of  Tables  of  Rent  Rate. 


R  r  2 


6l2  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


SECTION  II. — A  SKETCH  OP  THE  HISTORICAL  CHANGES  IN 
THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT. 


§  i.   Introductory  Remarks. 


I  must  now  endeavour  to  give  a  sketch  of  the  relation 
of  Landlord  and  Tenant  in  Bengal.  Among  the  legacies 
which  the  Permanent  Settlement  has  left  us,  the  controver- 
sies excited  by  the  question  of  the  Zamindar's  right  to  the 
estate,  and  of  the  permanence  of  the  assessment,  sink  into 
insignificance  beside  the  burning  question  of  the  rights  of 
tenants  and  their  liability  to  ejectment  and  to  enhancement 
of  rent.  On  this  subject,  the  difficulty,  once  more,  is  to 
deal  with  the  mass  of  official  literature  that  the  question 
has  evoked,  and  to  place  before  the  student  just  as  much  as 
is  really  important  and  really  authoritative. 

The  main  points  I  have  to  bring  out  are — -first,  that  from 
1 769  onwards  the  Government  was  perfectly  alive  to  the 
fact  that  the  raiyats  of  all  classes — from  the  permanent 
tenure-holder  to  the  humblest  resident  cultivator — needed 
protection  and  were  entitled  to  it ;  second,  that  they  only 
contemplated  certain  means  for  this  protection,  which  were, 
perhaps,  in  any  case,  theoretically  inadequate,  and  which 
certainly,  in  the  course  of  actual  events,  proved  absolutely 
futile.  Thirdly,  I  shall  have  to  illustrate  and  explain  the 
difficult  subject  of  rents  and  their  liability  to  enhancement, 
which  our  ablest  administrators  of  1789  certainly  had  very 
confused  ideas  about.  On  this  subject  I  shall  have  to  point 
out  that  a  great  portion  of  the  controversy  has  arisen  from 
a  failure  to  draw  the  distinction  which  a  careful  considera- 
tion of  the  original  condition  of  the  raiyats  will  be  found  to 
warrant,  and  to  an  utterly  mistaken  view  of  what  the  early 
Regulations  really  laid  down.  It  has  been  sedulously 
maintained — notably  (for  instance)  in  an  elaborate  volume 
of  authorities,  entitled  the  Za/minddri  Settlement  of  Bengal l 

1  An  anonymous  work  in  two  volumes.     Calcutta  :  Brown  &  Co.,  1879  ; 
already  alluded  to. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.     6 1  3 

— not  only  that  the  '  raiyats '  were  the  original  owners  of  the 
soil,  which  is  true  only  to  a  limited  extent  (if  we  take  into 
account  not  merely  historical  facts  of  a  remote  past,  but 
also  the  actual  conditions  which  ages  of  change  brought 
about),  but  also  that  the  '  raiyats '  had  a  general  right l  to 
an  absolutely  unchangeable  rate  of  payment,  which  it  was 
intended  to  make  permanent  and  unalterable,  just  as  much 
as  it  was  to  fix  the  revenue  of  the  Zamindar.  I  do  not  under- 
stand that  even  the  author  of  this  work  goes  so  far  as  to 
assert  that  tenants  really  owing  their  position  to  contract — 
i.  e.  located  on  the  waste  lands — were  or  could  be  entitled 
to  have  a  fixed  rent,  never  to  be  enhanced  ;  and  that  alone 
would  seriously  affect  the  question,  for  at  least  one-third 
of  the  whole  presidency  was  uncultivated  at  Settlement : 
in  many  districts  two-thirds  would  be  nearer  the  mark. 

But,  as  regards  the  raiyats  on  cultivated  land,  it  cannot 
be  contended  that  they  were  all  on  the  same  footing.  Even 
as  regards  those  that  had  once  been  the  real  proprietors  of 
the  holdings  (before  there  were  any  Zamindars,  or  under 
the  rule  of  Rajas  who  were  overlords,  but  never  proprietors), 
it  is  quite  impossible  to  assert  that  their  revenue  contribu- 
tions were  not  liable  to  increase 2.  It  is  true  that,  by  a 
mere  tradition,  the  Settlement  of  Raja  Todar  Mai  was 
remembered  and  looked  back  to  as  a  sort  of  fundamental 
assessment  or  starting-point ;  but  it  was  nowhere  actually 
in  force,  or  had  been  within  recent  memory.  It  is  a 
matter  of  the  plainest  fact  that  the  Mughal  Government 
from  time  to  time  re-assessed  the  lands  and  raised  the 
rates,  just  as  our  own  Government  does  (only  in  a  more 
methodical  way)  in  temporarily-settled  provinces  3.  It  is  a 
mere  question  of  form  that  sometimes  the  assessment  was 
raised  by  actual  re-measurement  and  re-valuation,  and 
sometimes,  in  later  days,  by  the  expedient  of  adding  '  cesses ' 

1  I.  e.  not   limited   to  particular  2  See   ante,  p.  277,  and  Fifth  Rt- 

cases  where  general  and  prescriptive  port,  vol.  i.  104  (Shore's  Minute,  §§ 

usage  could  be  proved,  in   which  13-39,  63,  279). 

case  no  one  ever  doubted  that  the  3  This  fact  is  expressly  asserted  in 

possession  and  the  payment  were  Reg.  I  of  1793,  Sec.  7  (Article  VI  of 

fixed.  the  Proclamation). 


6 14  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

or  abwab  to  the  last  'asl  jama'.  And  as  to  the  rates  of  rent 
spoken  of  'as  pargana  rates,'  they  existed  only  in  theory, 
and  in  practice  would  not  be  found  to  represent  any- 
thing more  than  the  results  of  the  last  re-assessment,  if 
so  much. 

While,  therefore,  it  was  practically  impossible  to  do  any- 
thing else  but  recognize  the  Zamindars  (and  others)  as 
limited  proprietors,  either  in  name  or  practically,  as  has 
been  done  in  every  form  of  Settlement  known  in  British 
India  or  Burma,  and  while  it  was  practically  impossible  to 
lay  down  that  no  class  of  raiyat  should  ever  have  his  rent 
raised,  there  was  a  just  solution  of  the  question,  and  that 
was  for  a  Settlement  Officer  to  inquire  into  and  record 
rights,  and  classify  tenants  exactly,  as  we  have  done  for 
instance  in  the  Central  Provinces,  where,  from  motives  of 
justice  and  State  policy,  we  created,  more  or  less  artificially, 
a  body  of  landlords. 

But  with  all  our  present  machinery  of  rapid  and  accurate 
survey,  with  a  Settlement  Office  that  can  attack  work,  and 
in  a  short  time  have  every  field  and  every  form  of  tenure 
under  its  eye  in  maps  and  tabulated  returns,  and,  above  all, 
under  the  experienced  local  inspection  of  trained  officers, 
— with  all  this  in  mind,  it  is  a  matter  of  some  difficulty 
to  take  ourselves  back  to  1788-89,  and  think  of  the 
small  body  of  Collectors,  the  utter  absence  of  reliable 
native  subordinates,  the  imperfection  of  survey  science, 
and  the  inaccessibility  of  the  districts,  without  roads,  and 
many  of  them  half  cultivated.  But  if  we  can  succeed  in 
doing  this  to  any  extent  whatever,  we  shall  at  once  realize 
how  impossible  it  was  that  the  one  and  only  chance  of 
success  should  ever  have  occurred  to  any  one  as  within 
the  horizon  of  the  practicable ;  the  more  so  as  the  policy 
distinctly  was  to  save  the  newly-made  landlords  from  what 
was  thought  to  be  vexatious  inquisition  into  the  details  of 
their  estate  and  its  management. 

Unfortunately,  as  we  began  (should  I  not  say  were  obliged 
to  begin  ?)  without  the  only  possible  guarantee  of  success, — • 
a  survey  of  estates  and  a  classification  of  rights, — so  the 


CHAP.  IV.]     THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     615 

continuous  and  inevitable  process  of  the  stronger  absorbing 
the  weaker  right,  went  on  ;  and  when  rights  have  been 
changed  and  discoloured  by  a  century  of  growth — or  of 
abuse,  if  it  be  so, — it  is  impossible  for  a  sober  and  practical 
Government,  whatever  it  may  be  for  impassioned  advo- 
cates, to  ignore  accomplished  facts  and  hark  back  to  a 
theoretical  state  of  rights  that  once  existed.  Where  it  is 
difficult  to  defend  the  course  of  legislation,  is  in  the  time 
between  1800  or  1812  and  1845.  The  errors  then  made 
were  fatal ;  but  granted  that  legacy  of  mistake,  I  do  not 
see  how,  from  1 859  onwards,  in  the  divided  state  of  opinion, 
more  could  be  done  than  has  in  fact  been  clone.  Every 
step  had  then  to  be  taken  in .  the  teeth  of  strongly- vested 
interests.  While,  on  the  one  side,  the  raiyat's  advocate 
looks  regretfully  back  to  unquestionable  facts  of  ancient 
right,  and  appeals  to  declarations  of  intentions  the  means 
of  realizing  which  unfortunately  never  existed,  the  landlord's 
advocate,  on  the  other,  relies  on  the  practical  growth  of 
years  and  actual  facts  of  the  present ;  and  it  is  only 
gradually  and  by  cautious  steps  that  a  modern  Government, 
as  umpire  between  the  two,  can  make  its  tenant-law  so  as 
to  do  practical  justice  to  both  sides,  removing  from  time  to 
time,  defects  in  the  law  and  introducing  working  improve- 
ments. Viewing  the  tenant-law  of  Bengal  in  this  light, 
and  making  allowance  for  the  conflict  of  opinion  and  the 
fervid  interests  aroused  on  both  sides,  it  must  be  candidly 
admitted  that  the  progress  of  legislation  from  1859  to  1885 
has  been  anything  but  unsatisfactory,  or  unworthy  of  an 
impartial  and  enlightened  Government. 

§  2.    Protection  to  Tenants  promised. 

The  first  endeavour  I  shall  make  is  to  place  before  the 
reader  the  plainly  declared  intention  of  the  authorities  and 
of  the  legislature  to  protect  the  raiyats ;  because,  though 
the  Regulations  never  expressed  any  intention  of  absolutely 
preventing  any  enhancement  of  rents,  these  declarations 
put  beyond  doubt  the  indefeasible  right  of  Government  to 


6l6  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  II. 

do  what  it  has  done  in  1859  and  in  1885, — viz.  to  pro- 
tect tenant-rights  and  limit  the  power  of  enhancement 
and  eviction.  The  growth  of  the  Zamindar's  power  was 
inevitable  under  the  Regulations  as  they  first  stood,  and 
as  they  continued  even  when  oppression  became  more 
and  more  manifest  as  years  went  on  ;  but  nothing  can 
ever  be  allowed  to  annul  the  force  of  these  early  promises, 
and  disentitle  Government  to  go  yet  further  than  it  has 
done,  if  so  advised,  in  the  direction  of  protecting  tenants. 

It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  the  principle  of  protecting 
the  raiyats  was  never  absent  from  the  minds  of  the  authori- 
ties. As  early  as  1769,  in  the  oft-quoted  Instructions  to 
the  Supervisors,  it  was  said1 :  '  An  equally  important  object 
of  your  attention  is  to  fix  the  amount  of  what  the  Zamin- 
ddr  receives  from  the  raiyat  as  his  income  or  emolument. 
.  .  .  Among  the  chief  effects  which  are  to  be  hoped  from 
your  residence  in  the  province  ...  is  to  convince  the  raiyat 
that  you  will  stand  between  him  and  the  hands  of  oppres- 
sion .  .  .  that,  after  supplying  the  legal  due  of  Government, 
he  may  be  secure  in  the  enjoyment  of  the  remainder  ...  for 
the  raiyat  being  eased  and  secured  from  all  burdens  and 
demands  but  what  are  imposed  by  the  legal  authority  of 
Government  itself,  and  future  pattas'2  being  granted  him 
specifying  the  demand,  he  should  be  taught  that  he  is  to 
regard  the  same  as  a  sacred  and  invariable  pledge  to  him 
that  he  is  liable  to  no  demands  beyond  their  amount.'  The 
instructions  go  on  to  require  the  Supervisor  to  examine 
and  check  the  '  hast-o-biid '  (rent-rolls),  and  see  that  the 
pattas  are  given  accordingly,  and  then  the  raiyat  is  to  be 
'  impressed  in  the  most  forcible  and  convincing  manner 
that  the  tendency  of  your  measures  is  to  his  ease  and  relief, 
.  .  .  that  our  object  is  not  increase  of  rents  or  accumulation 
of  demands,  but  solely  by  fixing  such  as  are  legal  .  .  .  and 
abolishing  such  as  are  fraudulent  and  unauthorized,  not 

1  See  Field,  p.  464  ;  and  the  whole  is  the  written  lease  or  note  of  the 

history  of  the  Supervisors  is  very  terms  of  holding  rent  payment  and 

graphically  given  in  Hunter's  Annals  other  particulars,  drawn  up,  of 

of  Rural  Bengal.  course,  in  the  vernacular. 

*  ( Patta,'  a  term  we  so  often  use. 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     6 1  7 

only  to  redress  his  present  grievances,  but  to  secure  him 
from  all  further  invasions  of  his  property  V 

At  the  time  of  the  Permanent  Settlement  also,  the  Court 
of  Directors  wrote  (1792)  regarding  'the  difficulty  of  pro- 
viding for  an  equitable  adjustment  and  collection  of  the 
rents  payable  by  the  raiyats.'  They  hoped  that  in  time 
every  one  would  learn  his  own  interest,  and  that  things 
would  then  be  managed  by  consent,  without '  interference  of 
authority.'  '  But  as  so  great  a  change,'  they  said,  '  can  only 
be  gradual ;  the  interference  of  Government  may,  for  a  con- 
siderable period,  be  necessary  to  prevent  the  landholders 
from  making  use  of  their  own  permanent  possession  for  the 
purpose  of  exaction  and  oppression ;'...'  and  while  we 
disclaim  any  interference  with  respect  to  the  situation  of 
the  raiyats,  or  the  sums  paid  by  them,  with  any  view  to  an 
addition  of  revenue  to  ourselves,  we  expressly  reserve  the 
right  which  clearly  belongs  to  us  as  sovereigns,  of  inter- 
posing our  authority  in  making  from  time  to  time  all  such 
regulations  as  may  be  necessary  to  prevent  the  raiyats 
being  improperly  disturbed  in  their  possession  or  loaded 
with  unwarrantable  exactions.'  After  adding  that  it  was  a 
maxim  of  the  Mughal  Government  that  a  raiyat,  duly  pay- 
ing his  rent  (revenue)  could  not  be  dispossessed,  they  say : 
'  This  necessarily  supposes  that  there  were  some  measures 
and  limits  by  which  the  rent  could  be  defined,  and  that  it 
was  not  left  to  the  arbitrary  determination  of  the  Zaminddr 
.  .  .  and  in  point  of  fact  the  original  amount  seems  to  have 
been  annually  ascertained  and  fixed  by  the  act  of  the 
sovereign.' 

It  will  be  enough  to  add  to  these  orders,  the  declaration 
of  Regulation  I  of  1793  (Section  8,  cl.  i) :  '  It  being  the  duty 


1  All  this,  be  it  observed,  is  per-  ment,  which  does  not  change  ex- 
fectly  consistent  with  a  legal  and  cept  at  considerable  intervals — 
authoritative  revision  of  the  assess-  twenty  or  thirty  years  or  whatever 
ment,  even  if  the  raiyat  was  re-  period  is  fixed.  The  worst  native 
garded  as  practically  owner  of  his  Governments  often  altered  the  as- 
holding.  No  increase  is  to  be  sessment  annually,  but  our  Govern- 
allowed  beyond  the  rent  lawfully  ment  would  never  have  done  that — 
claimable  for  the  time  being,  i.  e.  apart  from  any  ideas  of  permanency 
according  to  the  Government  assess-  afterwards  evolved. 


6 1 8  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

of  the  Ruling  Power  to  protect  all  classes  .  .  .  the  Governor- 
General  in  Council  will,  whenever  he  may  deem  it  proper, 
enact  such  Regulations  as  he  may  think  necessary  for  the 
protection  and  welfare  of  the  "  dependent  taluqdars,"  raiyats, 
and  other  cultivators  of  the  soil ;  and  no  Zamindar,  &c.,  shall 
be  entitled,  on  this  account  to  make  any  objection  to  the 
discharge  of  the  fixed  assessment  which  they  have  re- 
spectively agreed  to  pay.'  As  to  the  general  effect  of  the 
Regulation  VIII  of  1793  on  the  relative  rights  of  landlord 
and  raiyat,  as  recognized  by  the  Proclamation  and  Rules  of 
Settlement,  I  do  not  think  it  necessary  to  do  more  than  to 
refer  to  the  judgments  delivered  by  the  High  Court  of 
Bengal  in  the  '  Great  Rent  Case '  in  1 865.  An  excellent 
summary  of  the  judgments,  as  far  as  they  concern  this  par- 
ticular point,  will  be  found  in  a  convenient  form  in  the 
Tagore  Lectures  for  1875*.  It  is  of  comparatively  little 
interest,  however,  to  quote  further  examples  of  general 
declarations ;  one  thing  is  certain,  viz.  that  these  declara- 
tions give  ample  authority  for  legislation  whenever  it  is 
required.  A  more  important  question  is — what  actual  and 
practical  provisions  were  made  for  protecting-  tenants  ?  It 
will  be  found  that  the  first  enactments  were  in  fact 
nugatory  and  futile,  and  that  this  result  was  due  partly  to 
their  inherent  inadequacy,  and  partly  to  their  being 
counteracted  by  other  rules  which,  from  a  fear  of  loss  to 
the  Treasury  and  to  the  landlords,  were  afterwards 
gradually  enacted  to  facilitate  the  recovery  of  rents. 


§  3.  Impossibility  of  an  unalterable  Rent  for  Tenants 
generally. 

Though  protection  to  the  raiyat  was  thought  of,  his 
actual  rights  and  position,  as  they  emerged  at  the  end  of 
the  troublous  history  of  Bengal  previous  to  1765,  were  so 
uncertain  that  to  devise  securities  without  making  a  full 

1  See  Phillips,  pp.  312-15. 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  RELATION  OP  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     6 1  9 

local  inquiry  was  an  almost  hopeless  task.  But  in  any 
case,  it  would  have  been  impossible  for  the  framers  of  the 
Regulations  to  adopt  any  such  remedy  as  prohibiting  the 
enhancement  of  rents  generally.  On  the  other  hand,  they 
were  not  prepared  with  any  rules  to  say  when  an  increase 
should  take  place,  and  when  not l. 

It  is  clear  that  Mr.  Shore  never  thought  that  rents  were 
to  be  fixed  for  ever,  but  that  definite  rules  must  be 
found  out  by  which  they  could  be  fixed  legally  and  justly 
from  time  to  time. 

'  It  is  evident  that  in  a  country  where  discretion  has  so  long 
been  the  measure  of  exaction,  where  the  qualities  of  the  soil  and 
the  nature  of  the  produce  suggest  the  rates  of  the  rents  .  .  .  and 
where  endless  and  often  contradictory  customs  subsist  in  the 
same  district  and  village,  the  task  (of  denning  rights  and 
tenures)  must  be  nearly  impossible.  I  do  not  observe,  in  the 
correspondence  of  the  Collector  (of  Eajshahi),  any  specific  rules 
for  the  security  of  the  raiyats.  I  well  know  the  difficulty  of 
making  them,  but  some  must  be  established.  The  great  point 
required  is  to  determine  what  is,  and  what  is  not,  oppression, 
that  justice  may  be  impartially  administered  according  to  fixed 
rules.  .  .  .  Until  the  variable  rules  adopted  in  adjusting  the 
rent  of  the  raiyats  are  simplified  and  rendered  more  definite, 
no  solid  improvement  can  be  expected,'  &c.2 

In  his  minute  replying  to  Shore's  minute  (from  which 
the  above  has  been  taken),  Lord  Cornwallis  disposed  of  the 
difficulty  by  observing  that  if  Government  fixed  its  demand 
on  the  Zamindar,  he  had  '  little  doubt  that  the  landholders 


1  In  the  minute  of  iSthJune,  1789,  tenants,   and   not   of  Government. 

Mr.  Shore  said  :  '  I  have  admitted  Where  rates  exist,  or  the  collections 

.  .  .  the  right  of  the  Government  to  are  made  by  any  permanent  rules, 

interfere  in  regulating  the  assess-  the   interference    of  the    Collector 

ment  upon  the  raiyats,  but  I  object  would  be  unnecessary.     Where  the 

to  the  policy  and  propriety  of  this  reverse  is  the  case  he  would  find  it 

interference  without  evident  neces-  difficult  to  adjust  them.' 

sity.     When   a  Zamindar   has   re-  2  Shore's   minute    as   quoted   by 

fused  or  evaded  the  execution  of  the  Dr.  Field,  pp.  492-493.    It  is  worth 

orders  .  .  .  the  interference  of  the  while  to  refer  to  the  Fifth  Report,  i. 

Collector  may  be   expedient.     The  p.  162,  and  read  the  account  of  the 

regulation  of  the  rents  of  the  raiyats  fixing  of  raiyats'  rents  as  detailed  by 

is   properly  a  transaction  between  Mr.  Shore  in  his  minute  (June,  1789), 

the  Zaminddr  and  landlord  and  his  §§  390  404. 


62O  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

will,  without  difficulty,  be  made  to  grant  pattas  to  the 
raiyats  upon  the  principles  proposed  by  Mr.  Shore.  .  .  .  The 
value  of  the  produce  of  the  land  is  well  knoiun  to  the  pro- 
prietor or  his  officers,  and  to  the  raiyat  who  cultivates  it, 
and  is  a  standard  which  can  always  be  resorted  to  by  both 
parties  for  fixing  equitable  rates.  Further  on  he  draws  a  clear 
distinction  between  raising  rents  and  exacting  arbitrary 
cesses.  And  he  speaks  of  establishing  such  rules  'as  shall 
oblige  the  proprietors  of  the  soil  and  the  raiyat ....  to  come 
to  a  fair  adjustment  of  the  rates  to  be  paid  for  the  different 
kinds  of  lands  or  produce ; '  and  still  further,  Lord  Corn- 
wallis  remarked  that  '  the  rents  of  the  estate  can  only  be 
raised  by  inducing  the  raiyats  to  cultivate  the  more  valuable 
articles  of  produce,  and  to  clear  the  extensive  tracts  of  waste 
land  which  are  to  be  found  in  almost  every  Zamindari  in 
Bengal  V 

§  4.   Reference  to  an  'established  Pargana  Rate.' 

Still,  the  early  Regulations  often  speak  as  if  disputes 
about  rent-rates  could  always  be  settled  with  reference  to 
some  known  and  recorded  standard  called  the  'pargana 
rate.'  preserved  in  the  old  kamingo  accounts. 

It  is  no  doubt  easy  to  quote  passages  showing  that 
Hastings  and  others  had  exaggerated  ideas  of  the  value  of 
such  old  accounts2.  But  as  to  there  being  any  real  'par- 
gana rate '  (other  than  the  traditional  assessment  of  Akbar, 
&c.),  Mr.  Shore  remarked 3 : — 

'  At  present  no  uniformity  whatever  is  observed  in  the  de- 
mands upon  the  raiyats.  The  rates  not  only  vary  in  the 
different  collectorships,  but  in  the  parganas  composing  them,  in 
the  village,  and  in  the  lands  of  the  same  village,  and  the  total 
exacted  far  exceeds  the  rates  of  Todar  MaL' 

The  same  minute  (and  others)  abound  in  exposures  of 

1  It  was  confidently  expected  that  2  See,  for  instance,  Field,  at  pp. 

to  avoid  law-suits  the  parties  would  483-4. 

voluntarily  agree  about  rents  (see  Fifth  3  Minute  of  June,  1789,  §  219. 
Report,  i.  p.  34  at  the  bottom). 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     62  I 

the  lawlessness  of  the  times ;  how  the  despotic  authority 
plundered  the  Zamindars  and  left  them  to  plunder  the 
raiyats  in  turn. 

But,  granted  that  all  this  was  wrong,  and  therefore  not 
to  be  appealed  to  as  justifying  arbitrary  rent-rates,  the 
remedy  was  certainly  not  to  pretend  that  every  one  ought 
to  go  back  to  the  rate  of  the  last  regular  assessment  (Todar 
Mai's  or  any  other),  and  never  depart  from  that. 

In  1812,  Mr.  H.  Colebrooke,  discussing  in  a  minute 
(ist  May,  1812)  the  evils  that  resulted  from  the  Regula- 
tions, wrote  regarding  the  'pargana  rate'  that  it  was 
supposed  by  the  Regulations  that  the  proportion  of  annual 
produce  in  money  or  kind,-  constituting  the  revenue 
demand,  could,  with  certainty,  be  ascertained.  There  was, 
however,  'reason  to  presume  that  the  pargana  rates  are 
become  very  uncertain.'  Mr.  Colebrooke  had  sat  in  the 
Sadr  Diwani  'Adalat  (highest  Court  of  Civil  Law),  and 
declared  that  in  cases  favourably  circumstanced  for 
inquiry,  'the  most  patient  inquiry,  conducted  by  a  very 
intelligent  public  officer,'  failed  to  elicit  any  rule  of  ad- 
justment. In  Benares  it  had  been  found  possible  to  refer 
to  a  table  of  rates  of  1187  (Fasli  era).  In  the  24-Per- 
gunnahs  the  Courts  had  been  able  to  support  claims  to 
refer  to  the  last  general  measurement  undertaken  under 
the  authority  of  Government  before  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment. Other  instances  may  exist,  but  they  are  few ;  and 
the  position,  as  a  general  one,  was  unquestionably  true, 
that  there  was  no  evidence  of  any  permanent  rates  and 
usages  of  parganas  which  could  be  appealed  to. 

Indeed  the  absence  of  any  definite  and  unchanging  stan- 
dard of  rent  or  revenue-rate  was  remarked  some  years 
before  Mr.  Shore's  time.  As  early  as  1776,  Warren  Hastings 
(in  replying  to  a  minute  of  Francis's)  had  written x : — 

'  The  ancient  .  .  .  distribution  of  the  land-rent,  which  was 
formed  about  two  hundred  and  twenty  years  ago,  has  long  since 
ceased  to  serve  as  a  rule.  Under  the  old  Government,  this  dis- 

1  Quoted  by  Field,  p.  483. 


622  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

tribution  was  annually  corrected  by  the  accounts  which  the 
Zanrindars  and  other  collectors  of  the  revenue  were  bound  to 
deliver  into  the  office  of  the  Jcdnwngos  or  King's  registers,  of 
the  increased  or  diminished  rents  of  the  lands  and  of  the 
amount  of  their  receipts,  but  the  neglect  of  these  institutions, 
the  wars  and  revolutions  which  have  since  happened  in  Bengal, 
.  .  .  the  increase  of  cultivation  in  some  parts  of  the  province 
and  the  decrease  in  others,  .  .  .  have  totally  changed  the  face 
of  the  country,  and  rendered  the  tumdr  rent-roll  a  mere  object  of 
curiosity.  The  land-tax  has  therefore  been  collected  for  these 
twenty  years  past,  on  a  conjectural  valuation  of  the  land,  formed 
by  the  amount  of  the  receipts  of  former  years,  and  the  opinions 
of  officers  of  the  revenue,  and  the  assessment  has,  accordingly, 
been  altered  almost  every  year.' 

§  5.  But  even  if  '  Pargana  Rates'  had  been  reliable, 
they  were  never  unalterable. 

But,  even  if  we  assume  that  'pargana  rates'  could  be 
reliably  ascertained,  what  was  there  to  bind  the  Zaminddrs 
never  to  enhance  on  those  of  a  given  date?  The  rates 
(become  the  landlord's  rents)  were  originally  the  revenue 
rates  payable  to  the  State,  and  after  the  full  proof  given  *, 
I  have  no  occasion  to  repeat  that  it  was  perfectly  '  legal ' 
or  customary  to  revise  them  periodically.  Let  us,  however, 
be  quite  clear  on  the  subject. 

Let  us  suppose  that  there  never  had  been  any  official 
Zamindars,  and  that  the  ruling  power  continued  to  deal 
direct  with  the  villagers.  No  one  will  question,  for  a 
moment,  that  under  such  a  state  of  things,  the  cultivators 
of  the  village  were,  in  some  degree  or  sense,  proprietors  of 
their  holdings.  In  some  villages  there  would,  no  doubt, 
have  been  a  group  of  persons  claiming  a  higher  position 
than  the  rest ;  they  were  the  descendants  of  the  original 
founders,  or  the  descendants  of  the  person  to  whom  the 
Raja  had  granted  the  village  in  '  birt,'  and  these  persons 
would  certainly  have  a  position  which  it  is  no  stretch  of 
language  to  call  'proprietary.'  Under  them  would  be  a 

1  See  Bk.  I.  Chap.  V.  pp.  277   280,  and  Bk.  II.  Chap.  I.  p.  416. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     623 

class  of  residents  and  privileged  persons  (qadimi  raiyats) 
in  the  second  rank,  who  acknowledged  that  they  were  not 
equal  to  the  first,  but  probably  paid  no  more  for  their  land, 
and  were  certainly  not  ejectable  at  pleasure.  Besides  those 
there  would  be  tenants  from  other  places. 

Which  of  these  classes  of  village  cultivators  would  have 
reasonably  expected  that  his  payment  to  the  State  would 
never  be  altered,  and  that  there  really  was  in  each 
'pargana'  a  series  of  rates  for  different  kinds  of  soil, 
or  different  degrees  of  value  in  the  holdings — rates 
which  no  power  could  lawfully,  and  at  proper  intervals, 
raise  ? 

Obviously  even  the  highest  class  in  the  village,  would  have, 
from  time  to  time,  to  submit  to  the  Government  raising  the 
rates  either  by  assessment  or  by  imposition  of  abwab ;  the 
second  privileged  class  would  expect  the  same ;  while 
casual  tenants  would  not,  under  any  conceivable  policy,  be 
exempt  from  being  asked  to  pay  more.  Not  only  did  the 
exigencies  of  the  State  vary,  but  when  money  rates  were 
paid,  it  is  obvious  that  as  coinage  became  more  plentiful, 
the  value  of  the  money  decreased,  and  revision  became  a 
matter  of  necessity. 

When,  in  the  course  of  events,  these  State  payments 
became  the  landlord's  rents,  some  similar  power  of 
periodical  revision  (however  limited  on  equitable  grounds 
and  with  reference  to  all  the  circumstances)  must,  in 
reason,  have  been  intended J. 

It  is  perfectly  true  that  people  spoke  about  '  pargana 
rates,'  but  that  merely  meant,  that  a  rate,  as  fixed  at  the 
last  authoritative  assessment,  was  known,  and  was  the 
standard ;  and  what  the  people  who  appealed  to  that, 
desired  was,  not  that  under  no  circumstances  should  these 
rates  be  increased,  but  that  they  should  not  be  increased 
arbitrarily  and  without  mercy,  at  the  will  of  the  tax- 
collector  in  the  shape  of  abwab  and  extra  imposts.  In 

1  I.e.  in  the  express  absence  of  any  — that  as  the  landlord  was  given  a 
declaration — the  economic  results  of  fixed  revenue-liability,  so  were  all 
which  would  have  been  portentous  tenants  given  a  fixed  rent-liability. 


624  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

actual  practice,  there  was  no  uniform  standard  of  assess- 
ment ;  but  if  there  had  been,  it  would  have  been  admittedly 
absurd  to  compel  the  landlords  to  go  back  in  all  cases 
to  an  old  standard  of  assessment,  and  never  advance 
beyond  that,  no  matter  what  the  increase  in  value  of 
the  produce,  or  of  the  land  itself. 

It  is  quite  certain  that,  from  the  first,  under  the  Perma- 
nent Settlement  Regulations,  the  Zamindars  did  raise  their 
rents,  and  Government,  though  (as  already  shown)  willing 
to  protect  the  raiyats,  if  they  had  only  known  any  means 
of  doing  so,  never  contemplated  that  rents  should  remain 
unalterable  in  all  cases :  and,  therefore,  they  never  issued 
orders  to  prevent  change.  In  1812  the  Court  of  Directors 
wrote  to  Bengal,  that  the  Permanent  Settlement  had 
'  secured  to  the  proprietors  of  estates  the  whole  advantage 
of  a  rise  in  their  rental.'  It  is  certain  also  that  from  the 
time  of  Lord  Cornwallis  onwards,  a  rise  in  the  rental, 
not  only  by  cultivating  waste  but  by  raising  the  'nirkh- 
bandi,'  was  contemplated  ;  nor  was  this  affected  by  the 
prohibition  of  illegal  cesses,  which  was  then  thought  the 
main  precaution  to  be  taken  *. 

The  Courts  of  Justice  never  appear  to  have  had  it  dis- 
puted before  them,  that  there  was  any  general  prohibition 
against  enhancement,  though  of  course  there  were  specific 
cases  of  right  arising  from  ancient  grant  or  from  the 
fact  of  an  invariable  rent  having  been  paid  for  so  long  that 
it  gave  rise  to  a  prescription  in  the  special  case.  The 
Privy  Council  has  always  held  '  that  the  right  to  enhance  is 
presumable  until  the  contrary  is  shown  V 

And,  even  if  it  were  conceivable  that  there  should  have 
been  so  extensive  a  prohibition  merely  implied  or  intended 

1  Dr.  Field   (p.  533,  §  281)    has  abwabs  or  cesses.     And  if  the  de- 

fully  disposed  of  the  argument  that  cennial  Settlement  agreements  had 

raiyats'  rents  were  intended  to  be  stipulated    anything     more,    such 

fixed  for  all  time,  based  on  the  fact  stipulations  would   be   overridden 

that  in  the  arrangements  of   1772  by  the  express  words  of  the  Regula- 

made  urith  farmers,  they  were  told  to  tion  VIII  of  1793,  enacted  when  the 

take  only  the  '  jama '  fixed  on  the  decennial  Settlement  was  converted 

raiyats  the  year  before.    The  Zamin-  into  a  permanent  one. 
dars'  qabuliyats  or  Settlement  agree-  a  See     cases     quoted     by    Field, 

ments  only  bound  them  not  to  take  p.  556. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     625 

but  nowhere  expressed,  circumstances  would  soon  have 
rendered  its  maintenance  impossible.  Remembering  what 
a  large  part  of  Bengal  was  waste,  and  how  rapidly  new  land 
was  brought  under  the  plough,  it  was  to  be  expected  that 
new  rates  of  rent  would  arise  ;  and  as  population  increased 
and  competition  for  land  arose,  those  new  rates  would  be 
higher  than  the  old  ones.  Again,  when  an  estate  was  sold 
for  arrears  (as  was  frequently  the  case),  the  existing  leases 
were  all  voided,  except  certain  specified  ones,  and  there- 
fore the  purchasers  would  make  new  terms  with  the 
tenants,  and  rents  would  be  raised  to  the  level  of  the 
higher  rates  '  prevailing '  from  the  cause  first  mentioned l. 

'  Now,'  says  Dr.  Field,  '  if  one-half  of  Bengal  was  waste 
in  1793,  and  could  therefore  be  let  by  the  Zamindars  upon 
their  own  terms,  and  if  half  of  the  landed  property  in  Bengal 
changed  hands  between  1793  and  1815,  under  a  law  which 
authorized  the  purchasers  to  avoid  previous  engagements, 
it  was  easy  to  see  that  the  majority  of  the  raiyats  were,  in 
the  matter  of  rents,  subjected  to  the  uncontrolled  will  of 
their  landlords,  and  the  '  prevailing  rate  of  rent  being  thus 
raised,  there  was  little  difficulty  in  enhancing  the  rents  of 
the  remaining  raiyats  up  to  the  same  level  V 

§  6.  Summary  of  the  Argument. 

It  has  sometimes  been  asserted  that  it  was  the  declared 
intention  of  the  Regulations  that  no  raiyat  should  be  made 
to  pay  more  than  '  pargana  rates  of  1793-' 

There  is  no  doubt  a  great  deal  of  uncertainty  in  the  State 
papers  preceding  the  Regulations ;  it  is  possible  to  pick 
out  phrases  from  which  some  writers  could  be  argued  to 
suppose  that  every  raiyat  was  to  be  protected  for  ever  in 
paying  a  rate  ascertained  and  fixed  in  a  patta  at  the  time 
of  Settlement ;  but  it  is  equally  easy  to  show  that  what  was 
really  meant  was,  that  the  rates  fixed  by  lawful  authority, 

1  Compare  Maine,  Earhj  History  of  succeeding  the  Permanent  Settle- 
Institutions,  p.  184,  and  Hunter's  ment  one-half  the  estates  were  sold. 
Orissa,  i.  57-8.  In  twenty-two  years  2  Field,  p.  559. 

VOL.  I.  S  S 


626  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  11. 

and  not  according  to  arbitrary  exaction,  should  be  paid 
(how  or  by  what  rule  fixed  was  never  determined),  and  that 
these  rates  could  only  be  departed  from  by  a  consent  which 
altered  the  mode  of  cultivation,  and  also  by  the  increase  of 
land  under  cultivation. 

I  may  briefly  also  summarize  the  reasons  why  it  could 
not  have  been  intended  by  any  one  (as  it  certainly  was 
never  declared  by  any  Regulation)  that  all  raiyats'  rents 
were  to  be  absolutely  invariable  : — 

(1)  that  no  class  of  raiyats  (except  of  course  those  who 

had  special  grants)  was  ever  exempt  from  having 
the  revenue  periodically  raised  by  State  authority 
from  time  to  time,  even  when  there  was  no  question 
that  the  raiyat  was  the  practical  owner  of  his  hold- 
ing ;  and  when  Government  limited  its  demand  on 
the  middleman  it  did  not  follow  that  the  revision  of 
the  raiyat's  rent  was  also  foregone,  unless  it  was 
specifically  so  provided,  which  it  never  was J ; 

(2)  that  no  such  thing  as  a  pargana  rate,  fixed  for  all 

time,  existed,  but  only  a  rate  from  time  to  time 
fixed  by  authority ; 

(3)  that  the  change  in  the  value  of  money  and  of  pro- 

duce, the  gradual  change  of  circumstances  whereby, 
as  population  increased  (under  a  peaceful  rule), 
tenants  would  become  more  abundant  and  begin  to 
compete  for  land, — all  tend  to  produce  a  state  of 
things  in  which  an  unchangeable  rent  for  all  classes 
is  a  practical  impossibility  ; 

(4)  that  the  very  fact  that  some  raiyats  held  '  muqarrari ' 

or  fixed  rate  leases,  showed  that  a  fixed  rent  was 
the  exception,  not  the  rule ; 

1  Indeed,  exactly  the  contrary.  to  '  appropriate  to  his  own  use  the 
The  preamble  to  Regulation  XLV  of  difference  between  the  said  pro- 
1793  expressly  states  that  the  rai-  portion'  and  the  fixed  demand, 
vats  were  bound  to  pay  a  proportion  The  whole  preamble  would  have  no 
of  the  annual  produce  of  every  bigha  point  if  it  were  not  that  the  'pro- 
of land  (in  money  or  kind  according  portion '  payable  by  the  raiyat  had 
to  custom",  and  that  the  Govern-  not  been  (in  the  absence  of  express 
ment  fixed  a  demand  on  the  pro-  grants  liable  to  be  fixed  from  time 
prietor  of  every  estate,  and  left  him  to  time  on  periodical  revisions. 


CHAP.  IV.]  THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.  627 

(5)  that  even  if  some  of  the  old  village  cultivators  were 

specially  entitled  to  consideration,  all  raiyats  were 
not,  by  custom,  on  the  same  footing ; 

(6)  that  considering  the  enormous  areas  of  waste  that  in 

time  would  be  brought  under  cultivation,  the  tenants 
who  undertook  it,  could  not  be  on  any  other  foot- 
ing than  that  which  depended  on  contract,  and  these 
would,  in  time,  become  a  very  large  class ; 

(7)  rents  in  kind  are  still  common,  especially  in  Bihar, 

and  in  the  nature  of  things,  these  would  really,  if 
not  nominally,  increase,  and  could  not  escape  being 
converted  into  money  rents  in  time.  In  short,  when 
the  value  of  produce  increased,  and  the  money  com- 
mutation took  place,  and  when  the  cultivation  of 
new  land  called  for  a  reassessment,  the  'nirkh- 
bandi '  or  often  appealed  to  list  of  '  pargana  rates ' 
would  necessarily  rise  (see  Field,  page  546). 

§  7.    Actual  Provisions  in  Regulation  VIII  of  1793 
regarding  Rent. 

The  features  of  the  Permanent  Settlement  law,  as  stereo- 
typed in  Regulation  VIII  of  1793,  have  already  been  stated, 
and  at  p.  433, 1  expressly  reserved  the  provisions  relating 
to  tenants.  Let  us  now  consider  them  briefly. 

The  Regulation  notices  that  there  are  persons  called 
taluqdars  or  '  muqarraridars '  (on  grant  of  fixed  rent),  &c. 
Some  of  these,  as  I  have  explained,  were  recognized  as  pro- 
prietors and  were  settled  with  independently.  With  such 
we  are  not  now  concerned.  The  others  then  remained  '  de- 
pendent '  or  holding  '  tenures '  under  the  proprietors  ;  but  if  Section  49. 
they  had  held  at  a  fixed  rent  for  more  than  twelve  years, 
or  if  their  grant  or  title-deed  showed  a  fixed  rent,  then  these 
tenures  were  '  not  liable  to  be  assessed  with  any  increase ' 
(unless  the  Zammdari  was  held  by  Government  or  let  in 
farm).  And  in  any  case  these  '  dependent '  tenures  were  not  Section  50. 
to  be  enhanced,  except  upon  proof  that  it  was  the  custom  of 
the  district  or  the  special  condition  under  which  the  tenure 

S  S  3 


628  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

Section  51.  was  created.  A  certain  provision  was  also  made  for  one 
other  class — the  old  resident  (or  khudkasht)  raiyats.  Their 
existing  terms  of  holding  could  not  be  interfered  with 
(except  on  proof  of  fraud  in  the  title),  and  the  right  to  raise 
these  rents  was  limited  to  cases — 

(1)  where  the  rent  paid  within  the  previous  three  years 

had  fallen  below  the  nirkh  or  rate  of  the  pargana, 
according  to  the  kanungo's  lists l ; 

(2)  upon  a  general  measurement  of  the  pargana  for  the 

purpose  of  equalizing  and  correcting  the  assessment. 

(This  did  not  apply  to  Bihar,  where  rents  in  kind  are 

taken  2.) 

Then  comes  a  provision  about  the  '  remaining  lands,'— 
i.e.  all  that  are  not  of  the  classes  just  named.  These 
lands  are  to  be  let,  under  the  prescribed  restrictions,  in 
Section  52.  whatever  manner  the  Zamindar  may  think  fit.  The  '  pre- 
scribed restrictions/  as  stated  in  the  Regulation,  are,  that 
persons  appointed  to  collect  rents  are  to  get  authority  by 
a  written  ''amlnama3';  that  all  cesses  (abwab,  mdthaut, 

1  These,    as    I    remarked,    were  must  have  varied  from  period  to 

often  incorrect,  since  the  irregulari-  period  according  as  the  money  value 

ties   of  many  years  would    either  rose,  and  according  to  other  circum- 

have    resulted     in     arbitrary    and  stances. 

various  rates,  or  else  in  some  old  2  In  1789,  Mr.  Harington  gave  a 
rates  being  continued,  which  could  full  statement  of  the  arguments  pro 
not  be  expected  to  last  for  ever  and  con  as  to  enacting  that  the  '  per- 
without  revision.  It  was  the  want  manent  raiyats '  should  be  entitled 
of  any  rule  for  getting  equitable  and  to  hold  for  ever  at  fixed  rents 
correct  rent-rates  that  led  to  all  the  (Harington,  iii.  pp.  461-463!.  He 
trouble.  Mr.  Shore  observes  :  '  In  recommended,  as  the  result,  that 
every  district  in  Bengal,  where  the  for  the  decennial  settlement,  the 
licence  of  exaction  has  not  super-  proprietors  should  be  obliged  to  fix, 
seded  all  rule,  the  rents  of  land  are  during  the  first  three  years,  a  rent 
regulated  by  known  rates  called  which  was  to  hold  good  for  the  re- 
"  nirkh  "  (and  the  list  of  these  par-  maining  seven.  When  the  decen- 
gana  rates  is  the  "  nirkh-bandi ").  nial  settlement  was  made  per- 
These  rates  are  formed  with  respect  manent  the  protection  given  to  the 
to  the  produce  of  the  land,  at  so  permanent  tenants  was  that  stated 
much  per  bigha.  Some  soil  pro-  in  the  text,  which  is  perhaps  not 
duces  two  crops  in  the  year  of  very  definite  or  satisfactory,  for 
different  species  ;  some  three.  The  there  is  nothing  to  show  how  often 
more  profitable  articles,  such  as  the  the  '  general  measurement '  might 
mulberry  plant,  betel-leaf,  tobacco,  have  come  round.  But  an  absolute 
sugarcane,  and  others,  render  the  fixity  of  rent  and  tenure  is  nowhere 
value  of  the  land  proportionately  conceded,  unless  proved  to  have 
great.  These  rates  must  have  been  been  acquired  by  grant  or  by  pre- 
fixed upon  a  measurement  of  the  scription. 
land.'  And  he  might  have  added,  3  So  that  the  raiyat  may  know 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     629 

mangan,  &c.)  are  to  be  consolidated  with  the  substantive 
rent  ('asl)  in  one  sum ;  that  no  ne^v  cesses  are  to  be  im- 
posed. Where  it  was  the  custom  to  vary  the  terms  of 
holding  for  lands  according  to  the  '  articles  produced 
thereon,'  this  was  allowed  to  be  done,  the  law,  however, 
'expecting  that  the  parties  (specifying  both  landlord  and 
tenant)  would  find  it  for  their  mutual  advantage'  to  enter 
into  agreements  for  a  specified  sum,  for  a  certain  quantity 
of  land.  All  rents  were  to  be  specifically  stated  in  pattas 
or  written  leases  (and  details  are  given  as  to  how  this  was 
to  be  done) ;  forms  of  patta  were  to  be  prepared  and  get 
the  Collector's  approval,  and  be  given  out  to  the  raiyats ; 
leases  existing  at  time  of  assessment,  unexpired,  and  not 
contrary  to  anything  in  the  Regulation,  nor  collusive  nor 
fraudulent,  were  to  hold  good  till  expiry.  Accounts  were 
to  be  kept  by  patwaris,  &c. ;  receipts  for  rent  were  to  be 
given ;  rents  of  persons  who  absconded  were  not  to  be 
demanded  from  those  that  remained  (called  ndjdi  pay- 
ments). Instalments  of  rent  were  to  be  fixed  with  due 
regard  to  seasons  of  reaping  and  selling  the  produce. 

These  were  the  only  '  restrictions '  on  the  Zamindar 
'  letting '  his  '  remaining  lands '  in  any  way  he  pleased. 
But  there  was  a  restriction  imposed  on  the  other  side.  For 
fear  that  Zamfndars  should  be  too  liberal,  or  rather  too 
eager  to  get  rid  of  trouble,  by  granting  away  their  estates 
on  long  leases,  and  so  disabling  themselves  from  meeting 
the  Government  demand,  another  Regulation,  passed  at  the 
same  time  (XLIV  of  1793),  prohibited  pattas  being  issued 
for  more  than  ten  years.  It  is  obvious  that  such  a  pro- 
vision contemplated  a  periodic  increase  of  rents,  which 
might  be  foregone  for  ten  years,  but  not  for  more,  or  it  has 
no  meaning J. 

who  he  was  paying  to,  and  not  be  '  Mr.  Field  has  given  a  number 
tricked  into  handing  over  his  rents  of  authorities  (p.  523  et  seq.~]  show- 
to  some  one  who  could  not  discharge  ing  that  this  was  the  meaning  of 
him  legally.  the  Regulations. 


630  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 


§  8.    Eviction. 

It  also  follows  from  these  provisions  that  the  question  of 
eviction  of  tenants  was  undetermined.  The  tenure-holders 
(taluqdars  and  others  similar)  were  of  course  not  liable  to 
be  dispossessed.  And  the  resident  raiyats  were  protected 
to  a  limited  extent.  But  nothing  is  said  about  other 
tenants ;  if  they  would  not  agree  to  the  terms  offered,  and 
were  not  holding  under  an  unexpired  lease,  there  was 
nothing  to  prevent  their  being  removed.  Probably  in 
1793  the  demand  for  tenants  was  so  great  (see  p.  610 
ante],  that  it  was  not  thought  likely  that  the  Zamindar 
would  evict  many;  he  would  be  only  too  glad  to  keep 
them.  However  this  may  be,  there  is  no  provision  in  the 
early  law  on  the  subject,  except  as  above  indicated.  When 
once  the  idea  of  the  Zamindar  being  landlord,  in  the  Eng- 
lish sense,  became  familiar,  it  was  not  surprising  that 
people  should  begin  to  talk  of  the  'inherent  privilege  of 
giving  him  (the  tenant)  due  warning  to  quit1.' 

§  9.    General  Conclusion. 

I  cannot  here  forbear  extracting  Dr.  Field's  just  and 
lucid  summing  up  of  the  discussions  and  orders  which 
preceded  the  Settlement,  giving  the  result  of  Mr.  Shore's 
and  Lord  Cornwallis'  minutes  and  the  orders  of  the  Home 
Government.  He  says2: — 

'  It  will  be  clear  to  any  unprejudiced  person  that  the  Direc- 
tors, and  those  who,  under  their  authority,  conducted  the 
Government  of  Bengal,  were  well  aware  of  the  indefinite  rela- 
tions which  subsisted  between  Zaminddrs  and  raiyats,  were 
well  apprized  of  the  uncertain  nature  of  the  rights  of  the  culti- 
vators of  the  soil s ;  that  practically  nothing  effectual  had  been 

1  See,   for    instance,    the    corre-  provisions  of  Lord  Cornwallis'  Code, 

spondence  quoted  by  Dr.  Field  (p.  no  rights  at  all.' 

531),  and  Land  Tenure,  by  a  Civilian,  2  Page  503,  §  267. 

p.  104 — '  In  point  of  law  and  fact,  3  Uncertain,  in  the  first  place  (I 

the  raiyats  can  claim  [that  is,  ordi-  may  repeat),  because  all  -village  cul- 

nary  tenants  can  claim],  under  the  tivators  were  not  originally  on  an 


CHAP,  iv.]  THE  EELATION  OP  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.  63! 

done  between  1765  and  1790  to  define  or  adjust  the  rights  and 
the  payments  to  be  made  by  the  raiyats  .  .  .  that  Mr.  Hastings 
and  Mr.  Shore  were  of  opinion  that  these  rights  and  payments 
should  be  defined  and  adjusted  before  the  Government  limited 
its  own  demands  upon  the  Zamindars  and  settled  for  ever  the 
amount  of  revenue  payable  by  them  ;  that  it  was  admitted  on 
all  hands  that  up  to  1790  there  were  not  sufficient  materials 
for  this  definition  and  adjustment ;  that  Lord  Cornwallis  was 
sanguine  that  the  combined  effects  of  the  limitation  and  per- 
manent Settlement  of  the  State  demand,  and  of  the  patta 
regulations,  would  have  the  ultimate  effect  of  adjusting  the 
relations  between  the  Zamindars  and  the  raiyats  .  .  .  ;  that  the 
Court  of  Directors  adopted  Lord  Cornwallis'  views,  and  instead 
of  directing  the  rights  of  the  cultivators  of  the  soil  to  be  ascer- 
tained, adjusted,  and  defined  once  for  all  \  contented  themselves 
with  reserving  a  general  right  to  interfere  afterwards,  if  these 
expectations  and  those  of  Lord  Cornwallis  should  be  disap- 
pointed, and  such  interference  should  be  found  necessaiy  for 
the  protection  and  welfare  of  the  raiyats.  Any  unbiassed  indi- 
vidual who  will  read  the  whole  of  the  papers  must  be  satisfied 
that  both  Lord  Cornwallis  and  the  Court  of  Directors  acted  to 
the  best  of  their  judgment  and  entertained  a  very  honest  belief 
that  (a)  the  elimination  of  the  element  of  uncertainty  by  the 
permanent  fixing  of  the  Government  demand,  (&)  the  mutual 
interests  of  the  parties,  and  (c)  the  enforcement  of  the  rules  as 
to  pattas,  would  together  operate  to  assure  and  improve  the 
condition  of  the  raiyats. ' 

equal  footing.  Some  were  certainly  best  it  is  '  uncertain,'  whether  the 
originally  proprietors,  others  only  original  right,  whatever  it  was,  had 
privileged  helpmates  (I  will  not  call  not  been,  in  a  great  many  cases, 
them  tenants)  of  these  proprietors  ;  thoroughly  and  really  lost. 
others  equally  clearly  only  casual  1  A  task  which  indispensably  ne- 
cultivators,  but  who,  from  lapse  of  cessitated  a  survey  and  a  Settlement 
time  or  other  circumstances,  had  staff  to  discover  and  record  rights, 
even  then  great  claims  to  con-  How  impossible  such  a  work  seemed 
sideration.  'Uncertain,'  in  the  in  1789  I  have  already  remarked, 
next  place,  because  rights  get  irre-  The  power  of  doing  it  was  not 
trievably  abandoned,  changed,  and  discovered  till  1822,  when  a  new 
lost,  in  the  lapse  of  years,  and  the  epoch  of  land  administration  corn- 
confusion  caused  by  two  centuries  menced. 
of  doubtful  government ;  and  at 


632  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP  BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

§  10.  Result  of  the  Regulation  Law. 

It  will  now  be  amply  clear  that  there  was  neither  law 
nor  custom  by  which  even  the  old  resident  cultivators 
of  a  village,  and  still  less  other  tenants,  could  expect 
to  go  on  from  decade  to  decade  without  any  increase 
in  their  revenue  (now  become  rent)  payment.  It  was  also 
in  the  nature  of  things  that  tenants  on  waste  land  and 
tenants  offering  themselves  and  willing  to  compete  for 
available  holdings,  should  hold  at  variable  rates  of  rent 
fixed  by  contract  and  mutual  understanding ;  and,  finally, 
the  Regulations  prescribed  nothing  as  to  any  principle  of 
rent  enhancement,  because  the  information  on  which  differ- 
ent classes  of  tenants  and  their  privileges  could  be  distin- 
guished and  formulated,  was  wholly  wanting. 

'  The  necessary  and  natural  result,'  says  Dr.  Field, — 

*  was  that  for  all  things  for  which  the  legislature  did  not  make 
provision,  the  new  course  of  things  under  British  rule  created 
a  practice  and  an  usage  which  adjusted  and  regulated  those 
relations  with  which  Government  did  not  concern  itself  to 
interfere  ;  and  a  common  law  (i.  e.  unwritten  usage  and  prac- 
tice) came  into  existence  which  was  largely  compounded  of  the 
ideas  of  the  ruling  race,  to  which  practical  operation  was  given 
by  a  strong  executive  and  by  means  of  the  Courts  of  Justice.' 


SECTION  III. — PROGRESS  OF  THE  TENANT-LAW  FROM 
1793  T0  l859- 

§  i.  The  'Patta'  Rules. 

The  first  disappointment  experienced  was  the  failure  of 
the  attempt  to  enforce  the  issue  of  written  leases  for  all 
tenancies,  to  which  I  have  alluded1.  Some  tenants,  who 
regarded  themselves  as  really  or  originally  proprietors  of 
their  holdings,  refused  (and  very  naturally)  to  take  a  lease 
for  fear  of  its  being  an  admission  of  a  lower  status  on  their 
part,  implying  that  their  right  and  title  was  derived  from 

1  See  p.  629  ante. 


CHAP,  rv.]    THE  EELATION  OP  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.     633 

the  grantor  of  the  patta,  that  it  was  terminable  (the  patta 
could  not  be  granted  for  more  than  ten  years),  and  that  the 
rent-rate  was  liable  to  alteration.  Many  of  the  tenants  also, 
feared  the  pattas  as  means  of  extortion,  and  refused  to  take 
them1.  The  earlier  Regulations  supposed  that  if  pattas 
were  required,  the  parties  would  agree  as  to  the  rates,  and 
yet  nothing  was  said  as  to  what  was  to  happen  when  pattas 
existing  (or  those  first  granted)  expired.  Regulation  IV  of 
1794  attempted  further  legislation.  Disputes  as  to  rates 
were  to  be  settled  in  the  Civil  Court,  with  reference  to 
'rates  established  in  the  pargana  for  lands  of  the  same 
description  and  quality.'  This  applied  both  to  existing 
tenancies  and  to  new  ones  ;  the- '  pargana  rate '  was  not  to  be 
exceeded  2.  The  facts  about  the  pargana  rates  have  already 
been  stated  (see  §§  4,  5,  p.  620).  It  was  provided  also 
that,  if  people  did  not  take  pattas,  the  landlord  might  post 
up  at  his  office  a  list  of  rates,  and  offer  pattas  at  those  rates, 
and  that  then  he  might  recover  by  suit  or  distraint  at  such 
rates.  '  Thus,'  says  Dr.  Field,  '  the  Zamindars  were  enabled 
to  claim  any  rates  they  pleased,  and  to  distrain  for  rent  at 
those  rates,  and  to  put  on  the  raiyats  the  onus  of  proving 
that  the  rates  so  claimed  were  not  the  "  established"  rates  3.' 
These  suits,  moreover,  became  numerous,  and  so  swamped 
the  Courts,  that  the  Zamindars  in  turn  suffered,  as  they 
could  not  get  decrees  for  rent  really  due. 


§  2.  '  Haftam: 

The   next  step   taken,   therefore,  was   to   facilitate  the 
recovery  of  rents  by  improving  the  laiv  of  distraint.     Re- 


1  They  feared  that  they  would  be 
bound  to  pay  for  the  whole  land 
specified,  even   if  crops   failed,   or 
cattle  died. 

2  Field,  p.  563.     The  rate  might 
easily  be  raised  by  getting  tenants 
to  take  some  private  land  of  the 
Zamindar's    at   high   rates,    which 
were  then  appealed  to  as  examples 
by  which  to  raise  the  average  rates 
of  the  whole  neighbourhood  (Land 
Tenure  by  a  Civilian). 


3  In  1811  the  Collector  of  Eaj- 
shahi  reported  that  the  Regulations 
had  then  been  in  force  eighteen 
years,  and  that  as  to  pattas  and  their 
counterparts  (qabuliyats)  'these  are 
as  few  now  as  ever.'  He  attributed 
this  to  the  fact  that  the  rights  of 
raiyats  had  never  been  defined,  and 
that  those  who  claimed  a  certain 
status  refused  pattas  for  fear  of  com- 
promising their  claim.  The  letter  is 
given  in  detail  by  Field,  pp.  565-66. 


634  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

gulation  VII  of  1799,  popularly  known  as  '  Qanun  haftam  ' 
(seventh  Regulation) l  recites  that  the  revenue  collections 
had  suffered  because  the  landlords  could  not  readily  get  in 
their  rents,  particularly  when  the  land  was  sub-rented  and 
the  crop  not  in  the  immediate  possession  of  the  raiyat2. 
The  law  empowered  landholders  and  farmers  to  delegate 
the  power  of  distraint  to  their  collecting  agents ;  distraint 
might  be  exercised  without  sending  notice  to  any  Court  or 
public  officer,  and  included  crops  and  cattle  and  personal 
effects ;  tools  of  tradesmen  were,  indeed,  exempt,  but 
ploughs  and  seed-grain  and  plough  cattle  were  only  exempt 
if  other  property  could  be  found ;  and  as  the  distrainer  was 
the  judge  of  this,  the  exemption  was  a  dead  letter.  No 
written  demand  was  required  before  distraint,  except  in  the 
case  where  the  tenant  had  no  written  specification  of  the 
exact  time  when  his  instalment  fell  due.  After  the  dis- 
traint was  made,  notice  was  to  be  given  of  sale ;  if  the 
arrear  was  not  at  once  paid,  and  if  the  tenant  absconded  or 
was  otherwise  absent,  then  a  list  of  the  property  was  sent 
to  the  nearest  official  who  had  power  to  hold  a  sale,  and  the 
law  only  required  five  clear  days  between  notice  and  sale. 
The  tenant  must  either  pay  or  find  security  to  institute  a 
suit  to  test  the  rent  and  to  pay  whatever  the  Court  decreed 
with  interest. 

It  was  stated  that  tenants  sometimes  delayed  proceedings 
by  making  unfounded  (criminal)  complaints  of  misfeasance 
and  abuses  in  attachment.  Magistrates  were  to  repress 


1  The  'haftam'  was  followed,  in  them  which  they  were  utterly  un- 
1812,  by  'panjam,'  or  Regulation  able  to  recover;  while  Government 
fifth    (of   which    presently)  :    the  was  selling  their  lands  for  arrears 
peasantry    of  to-day  attribute    all  of  assessment .  .  .  Farmers  and  in- 
their  misfortunes  to  '  panjam '  and  termediate  tenants  were  till  lately 
'  haftam '.  able  to  withhold  their  rents  with 

2  See  Fifth  Report,  i.  pp.  76,  77.  impunity,  and  to  set  the  authority 
In  Feb.  1802  the  Collector  of  Mid-  of    their    landlords     at     defiance, 
napore   reported  that  '  complaints  Landholders  had  no  direct  control 
were  very  general  among  the  Zamin-  over  them  :  they  could  not  proceed 
dars  .  .  .  they  had   not  the   same  against  them,   except  through  the 
powers   over  their  tenants  which  Courts  of  Justice,  and  the  ends  of 
Government   exercised  over  them.  substantial  justice  were  defeated  by 
It  was  notorious  that  many  of  them  delays  and  costs  of  suit.' 

had  large  arrears   of  rent  due  to 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     635 

these  and  fine  the  complainant  if  his  case  appeared  vexa- 
tious ;  and  other  provisions  were  added.  Practically  this 
meant  that  no  one,  unfamiliar  with  new  Courts  and  new 
procedure,  would  venture  to  bring  a  complaint,  for  fear  of 
his  powerful  adversary  making  out  that  it  was  a  vexatious 
one. 

There  were  other  provisions  regarding  the  arrest  of  per- 
sons intending  to  abscond,  and  authorizing  the  seizure  of 
tenures  and  farms  in  arrears,  the  landlord  managing  them 
direct,  and  ultimately  putting  up  the  title  to  sale  if  the 
management  failed  to  realize  the  arrear.  When  default 
occurred  in  the  case  of  a  lease-holder  or  tenant  '  having  a 
right  of  occupancy,  only  so  long  as  a  certain  rent  .  .  .  was 
paid  without  any  right  of  property  or  transferable  pos- 
session '  the  landlord  was  to  have  the  right  of  evicting  the 
defaulter.  No  application  to  a  Court  was  needed,  but 
farmers,  proprietors,  &c.,  were  responsible  for  any  act  ex- 
ceeding their  powers.  The  Regulation  stated  that  it  was 
not  intended  to  limit  or  define  rights  of  any  class,  but  to 
point  out  in  what  manner  defaulting  tenants  might  be 
made  to  pay,  leaving  them  to  recover  their  rights,  if  in- 
fringed, with  full  costs  and  damages,  in  the  established 
Courts  of  Justice. 

It  was  stated  that  '  in  all  other  instances  the  Courts  of 
Justice  will  determine  the  rights  of  every  description  of 
landholder  and  tenant  .  .  .  whether  ascertainable  from 
written  engagements,  defined  by  law,  or  dependent  on 
custom.'  Nothing  in  the  Regulation  took  away  the  power 
of  landlords  to  '  summon,  and  if  necessary  compel,  the 
attendance  of  tenants  for  the  adjustment  of  their  rents,  or 
any  other  just  purpose.5 

No  doubt  this  law  was  passed  in  the  bond  fide  belief 
that  tenants  were  in  fault,  that  the  hands  of  the  landlord 
needed  strengthening,  and  that  his  power  would  be  exer- 
cised fairly,  and  that  the  Courts  would  give  relief  if 
needed.  But  when  it  is  recollected  how  impossible  it  was 
for  the  poor  and  ignorant  to  apply  to  distant  Courts 
under  a  new  and  strange  procedure,  which  took  an  immense 


636  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.  [BOOK  n. 

time — always  a  serious  difficulty  to  people  who  want  to  be 
in  their  fields ; — when  it  was  further  recollected  that  such 
a  law  could  not  fail  to  be  abused,  it  is  difficult  to  read  its 
monstrous  provisions  without  indignation. 

That  this  law  produced  the  most  evil  results  goes  almost 
without  saying1. 

§  3.    Proposals  for  Relief. 

In  1811,  the  evils  produced  were  remarked  on  by  the 
Board  of  Commissioners  at  home,  and  in  India  the  Govern- 
ment issued  a  circular  of  inquiry,  which  still  shows  a  spirit 
of  belief  that  complaints  were  exaggerated,  and  that  if  rents 
were  not  collected  regularly,  there  would  be  a  heavy  accu- 
mulation of  arrears  of  Government  revenue.  Among  the 
opinions  elicited,  Mr.  H.  Colebrooke's  was  among  the  most 
valuable.  Other  officers  followed  suit.  Having  clearly 
pointed  out  that  the  remedy  of  appeal  to  the  Courts  was, 
in  the  case  of  poor  people,  quite  inefficient — '  many  of  the 
rules  designed  for  the  protection  of  the  raiyats  having  been 
perverted  into  engines  for  their  destruction, — it  was  urged 
that  definition  of  rights  should  be  undertaken,  and  that  if 
people  had  no  rights  the}7  should  be  told  so. 

The  abolition  of  the  local  native  offices  of  kanungo  and 
patwari  during  the  first  years,  was  appealed  to  as  faci- 
litating the  destruction  of  rights ;  but  this  may  be  doubted. 
The  village  accountant  is  of  no  use  if  the  whole  system  of 
village  organization  has  perished.  And  the  district  ac- 
countant can  be  of  no  use  under  a  system  where  there  is 
no  public  control  of  the  details  of  revenue  collection,  but 
where  the  landlords  pay  their  lump  sums  into  the  Col- 
lector's treasury  direct.  Both  officers  naturally  became 
mere  servants  of  the  Zamindar,  and  therefore  they  had 
been  abolished.  This  step  was  taken  because  it  was  found 
that  the  formal  records  which  they  still  prepared  were  use- 
less ;  in  some  cases  these  were  altogether  neglected  ;  in 

1  Those  desirous  of  some  details  may  read  the  quotation  from  Official 
Reports  in  Field,  p.  584,  et  seq. 


CHAP.  IV.]     THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.    637 

others  they  were  falsely  framed  to  suit  the  purposes  of  the 
Zamindars. 

Among  the  points  discussed  by  Mr.  Colebrooke  were  the 
restriction  of  pattas  to  ten  years,  prescribing  the  form,  and 
invalidating  all  that,  though  definite,  were  not  in  due  form; 
the  invalidating  en  bloc  all  existing  leases  and  tenures 
on  a  sale  of  an  estate  for  arrears ;  above  all,  he  exposed 
the  fallacy  which  lay  at  the  root  of  the  reference  so  often 
made  to  'established  pargana  rates'  (see  p.  621). 

Mr.  Colebrooke  proposed  that  where  '  pargana  rates ' 
were  not  available,  definite  protection  should  be  given  to 
the  resident  (khudkasht)  raiyats  :  '  This  will  silently  sub- 
stitute a  new  and  definite  rule  in  place  of  ancient  but 
uncertain  usages.'  He  proposed  that  in  individual  cases 
of  renewed  pattas  or  new  pattas  in  place  of  an  old  one 
voided  by  a  sale,  the  rate  should  be  that  which  was 
actually  paid  for  similar  land  in  the  vicinity ;  and  that 
where  there  had  been  a  wholesale  cancelling  of  the  pattas 
of  a  village  or  estate  consequent  on  a  sale,  new  rates  should 
not  exceed  the  highest  rate  actually  paid  in  the  three 
preceding  years.  And  in  the  case  of  taluqddrs,  after  cal- 
culating the  raiyats'  jama'  on  these  principles,  the  tenure- 
holder  was  to  be  definitely  allowed  10  per  cent,  on  the 
total,  plus  a  reasonable  allowance  for  cost  of  collection. 

I  only  state  the  proposals  generally  and  in  outline,  for 
the  purpose  of  indicating  the  historical  birth  of  the  'modern 
tenant  law,  which  substitutes  defined  rules  practically 
securing  certain  advantages,  for  pretended  references  to 
ancient  standards  impossible  of  access. 

§  4.    'Panjam.' 

The  main  proposals  of  Mr.  Colebrooke  were  adopted  in 
'Qanun  Panjam,'  or  Regulation  V  of  1812. 

The  ten-years'  restriction  as  to  leases  was  removed,  and 
any  form  of  lease  was  allowed  as  long  as  it  was  definite, 
but  this  was  not  to  be  construed  to  sanction  '  cesses '  and 
exactions  in  any  guise.  It  limits  the  avoidance  of  exist- 


638  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

ing  leases  on  sale  of  the  estate  for  arrears  ;  it  declares  the 
uncertainty  of  '  pargana  rates,'  and  substitutes  rules  similar 
to  those  above  stated  for  adjusting  rents  on  renewal  of 
pattas.  Enhancement  was  to  be  preceded  by  a  formal 
notice,  without  which  no  enhanced  rent  would  be  recover- 
able. The  law  of  distraint  was  softened,  and  implements 
of  husbandry,  plough  cattle,  &c.,  were  absolutely  exempted. 
The  Regulation  still  made  no  provision  for  defining 
rights  by  record,  and  thus  only  dealt  with  a  part  of  the 
evil ;  it  would,  however,  have  been  a  relief  were  it  not  for 
the,  fact  that  it  was  unfortunately  neutralized  by  other 
Regulations 1. 

§  5.    Farming  Estates. 

It  was  during  this  period  that  the  creation  of  farming 
tenures,  which  I  have  fully  explained  under  the  name  of 
'Patni,'  came  to  notice,  and  it  was  found  desirable  to 
recognize  them.  (See  p.  543  ante.)  Their  advantages  I 
have  already  pointed  out.  On  the  other  hand,  they  may 
tend  to  oppression.  The  manager  or  leaseholder  often 
re-transferred  portions  of  the  estate  to  sub-lessees,  and  such 
a  person  had  no  other  interest  but  to  amass  the  largest 
profit  to  himself,  regardless  whether,  on  going  out,  he  left 
behind  him  an  estate  sucked  dry  and  tenants  verging  on 
misery.  In  1843,  the  system  was  described  as  'striking 
its  roots  all  over  the  country,  and  grinding  down  the 
poorer  classes  to  a  bare  subsistence.' 

It  should,  however,  be  remembered  that  it  is  in  the 
Central  and  North -West  Bengal  that  those  'patnis'  were 
most  common.  In  East  Bengal  generally,  the  tenants  have 
rather  the  upper  hand  of  the  Zamfnd&rs  than  the  reverse. 

1  It  is  not  necessary  to  go  into      which  will  explain    how   it   came 
this   in   detail.     At  p.  654  of  Dr.       about. 
Field's  book  will  be  found  a  footnote 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     639 

§  6.    Alteration  of  Sale  Laws  as  affecting  Tenants. 

The  next  series  of  enactments  that  affected  tenants  were 
the  modifications  in  the  sale  Jaws,  and  especially  what  was 
provided  about  the  clear  title  which  the  purchaser  would 
get,  that  is,  a  title  free  of  encumbrances  created  by  the 
defaulter  or  his  predecessors  being  representatives  of  the 
original  engager.  It  was,  of  course,  impossible  equitably 
to  avoid  all  encumbrances,  and  Regulation  XI  of  1822 
made  certain  exemptions  ;  among  them  it  protected  '  khud- 
kasht-qadimi  raiyats  or  resident  and  hereditary  cultivators 
having  a  prescriptive  right-of-occupancy  V  and  the  pur- 
chaser was  not  to  demand  a  higher  rate  of  rent  from  such 
a  tenant  than  was  receivable  by  the  predecessor,  unless  in 
specified  cases  where  a  rent  lower  than  was  justly  demand- 
able  had  been  fixed  by  him.  '  This  gave  rise,'  says  Dr. 
Field,  '  to  a  doctrine  that  khudkdsht  raiyats  who  had  their 
origin  subsequent  to  the  Settlement  (1789)  were  liable  to 
eviction,  though,  if  not  evicted,  they  could  only  be  called  on 
to  pay  rents  determined  according  to  the  law  and  usage  of 
the  country ;  and  also  that  the  possession  of  all  raiyats 
whose  title  commenced  subsequent  to  the  Settlement,  was 
simply  a  permissive  one,  that  is,  retained  with  consent  of 
the  landlord.  The  establishment  of  this  principle  left  the 
Zamindars  free  to  enhance  the  rents  of  all  but  a  small  class 
of  raiyats  up  to  any  point  that  competition  could  run  them  ; 
because,  though  the  provisions  of  the  Sale  Regulations  ap- 
plied only  to  estates  which  had  been  sold  for  arrears,  yet 
the  principle  being  established,  it  was  soon  extended  by  the 
power  of  the  Zamindars,  to  other  estates  also.  Quite  apart 
from  this  power,  the  raising  of  rents  in  one  place  tended  to 
create  a  higher  '  prevailing  rate '  which  could  by  law  be 
imposed  on  the  tenants  of  any  estate  independently  of  there 
being  a  revenue  sale.  Moreover,  those  tenants  well  knew 
that  if  they  resisted,  the  Zaminddr  would  accomplish  his 

1  Construed  to  mean  resident  the  decennial  Settlement.  (Bengal 
raiyats  who  had  been  in  possession  Law  Reports,  Supplementary  Vol., 
for  more  than  twelve  years  before  p.  215.) 


640  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  11. 

purpose  by  allowing  the  estate  to  fall  into  arrears  and  be 
sold,  purchasing  it  himself  (free  of  the  old  leases)  in  the 
name  of  a  relation  or  dependent l. 

This  law  remained  in  force  till  1841,  when  Act  XII  pro- 
vided that  a  sale  should  void  all  tenancies  and  tenures 
created  since  the  Settlement,  and  leave  all  tenants  to  be 
enhanced  at  discretion  after  notice  given,  except  certain 
specified  cases,  which  were  certainly  made  more  definite 
than  before.  Some  changes,  not  affecting  the  rent  ques- 
tion, were  made  by  Act  I  of  1845  ;  and  this  law  remained 
in  force  till  1859,  when  the  Tenant  Act  X  of  1859  was 
passed,  and  the  Sale  Law  (XI  of  1859)  also  (five  days 
after  Act  X) 2.  The  great  feature  of  the  modern  sale  law, 
as  it  affects  tenures,  is,  that  it,  for  the  first  time,  hit  upon 
a  proper  device  for  protecting  them,  by  registration.  Entry 
in  a  General  Register  protects  them  against  auction-pur- 
chasers, and  entry  in  a  Special  Register  protects  even 
against  the  Government. 

We  shall  recur  to  the  Sale  Laws  in  the  following  chapter 
on  Revenue  Business. 

1  These  '  banami '  transactions  as  'Affrays  and  litigations  cannot  but 
they  are  called,  are  a  favourite  de-  ensue.    There  must  always,  in  every 
vice   all  over  India  for  concealing  case,  be  years  of  enmity  between 
the  property  really  belonging  to  one  the  new  landlord  and  his  tenantry, 
person  by  making  it  appear  to  be-  There  being  no  record  of  the  protected, 
long  to  another.  he  assumes  that  none  are  protected, 

The  term  is  '  ba-nam,'  in  the  name  while  the  tenants  set  up  groundless 

of   (another),'   not,    as    incorrectly  claims    to    protection,    of  ten-times 

written,  fce-nfim,  which  would  mean  supported  by  the  late  Zamindar  .  .  . 

(be)  without  a  name.  I  can  imagine  no  condition  more 

2  The  connection  of  the  sale  law  pitiable  than  that  of  the  inhabitants 
with  the  tenant's  rights  was  impor-  of  a  Zaminddri  transferred  by  sale 
tant  when  sales  were  frequent.    The  for  arrears. 

whole  body  of  the  tenants  was  .  .  .  We  can  talk  and  write  with 
alarmed,  because  there  was  no  indifference  of  it  (re-adjustment  of 
means  of  making  the  defaulter  hand  rent),  but  to  the  tenants  on  an  es- 
over  his  papers  to  the  purchaser.  tate,  a  sale  was  as  the  spring  of  a 
The  latter  came  in  as  a  stranger,  wild  beast  into  a  fold,  or  the  burst- 
not  knowing  one  tenant  from  ing  of  a  shell  in  a  square.'  (Sir  H. 
another,  nor  the  protected  classes  Ricketts,  1850.) 
from  the  unprotected. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     64 1 


k  SECTION  IV. — MODERN  TENANT  LAW. 

§  i.  Act  X  of  1859. 
This  Act  came  at  a  time  when  the  evils  of  the  existing 
state  of  things  were  so  patent,  that,  in  giving  his  assent 
to  the  Act  as  passed  by  the  Legislative  Council  on  29th 
April,  1859,  Lord  Canning  was  able  to  say,  '  no  objection  is 
suggested  to  the  nature  of  the  Settlement  which  the  Bill 
contemplates.'  In  fact,  almost  the  only  serious  discussion 
which  arose  was  on  the  provision  which  made  over  rent 
cases  to  revenue  officers  sitting  as  Courts  (with  only  a 
reference,  by  way  of  appeal,  to  the  Civil  Court  in  certain 
cases). 

I  will  borrow  Dr.  Field's  excellent  analysis l  of  the  Act 
under  nine  heads,  and  make  a  few  remarks  on  each.  These 
will  not  be  out  of  place,  because  there  are  still  a  few  dis- 
tricts where  the  Act  is  in  force  (as  I  will  presently  explain), 
and  in  any  case  the  student  will  hardly  understand  the 
effect  of  the  law  of  1885  without  some  idea  of  what  the 
reforms  effected  by  the  first '  modern '  tenant  law,  if  I  may 
so  call  it,  actually  were. 

The  Act  exhibited  these  main  features : — 
I.  The  abolition  of  the  landlord's  power  to  compel  at- 
tendance of  raiyats  at  their  offices. 
II.  The  definition  of  a  few  classes  of '  tenants '  whose  rent 
was  fixed  (not  then  classifying   or   attempting 
any  distinction  between  heritable  and  transferable 
tenures  and  tenancies}. 

III.  A  right  of  occupancy  for  tenants  (with  exception  of 
those  on  the  landlord's  home  farm — sir,  nij-jot, 
and  khamar  land — who  held  on  lease  from  year 
to  year;  and  excepting  also  sub-tenants).  This  right 
was  acquired  by  continuous  holding  (personally, 
or  by  the  predecessor  from  whom  the  holding 

1  The  whole  chapter  on  Act  X  in  by  students  desiring  to  go  a  little 
Dr.  Field's  book  may  well  be  read  more  into  detail  (p.  743  et  seq.). 

VOL.  I.  T  t 


642  LAND   SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

descended)  of  the  same  land  for   twelve  years. 

It  was  conditional,  of  course,  on  duly  paying  the 

rent  (which  was   enhanceable,  but  only  on  the 

conditions  prescribed  in  the  Act). 
IV.  Making   provision    for    settling  rent-disputes    and 

questions  of  abatement  and  enhancement. 
V.  A  renewed  attempt  to  bring  about  an  interchange  of 

pattas  (leases)  and  qabuliyats  (counterparts). 
VI.  An  attempt  to  compel  receipts  for  rent  and  to  prevent 

exaction  of  excess  rent. 

VII.  Distraint  was  modified  but  not  abolished. 
VIII.  Transfer  of  original  jurisdiction   in  suits   between 

landlord  and  tenant  from  the  Civil  to  the  Revenue 

Courts  (limited  appeal  to  the  principal  Civil  Court 

of  the  district). 
XI.  Registration  of  transfers  of  permanent  transferable 

interests  intermediate  between  the  cultivator  and 

the  landlord. 

§  2.    Remarks  on  these  Heads. — Special  classes  of  Tenants. 

I.  The  first  head  calls  for  no  remark ;  its  natural  result 
was  that  duress  and  coercion  were  prevented,  to  an  extent 
dependent  on  the  raiyats'  knowledge  of  the  law,  and  the 
perfection    of   the    subdivisional    system,    whereby   local 
courts  and  the  protective  action  of  the  '  Sub-Deputy  Col- 
lector and  Magistrate '  were  brought  nearer  to  the  people's 
doors. 

II.  The   tenures    called    ' muqarrari '    and   '  istimrdri' 
which  were   always  permanent,  and,  in  the   former   case 
had  the  benefit  of  a  fixed  rent,  had  been  acknowledged,  as 
we  have  seen,  from  the  days  of  the  Regulation  VIII  of 
1793  ;  a  rather  uncertain  protection  had  also  been  given  by 
Regulations  V  of  1812,  and  XI  of  1822,  to  the  old  resident 
cultivators  called  qadimi-khudkasht.      The    Act   of  1859 
extended  this   by  allowing  every  dependent   taluqddr  or 
other  person  possessing  a  permanent,  transferable,  interest  in 


CHAP,  iv.]     THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     643 

land1  who  held  at  a  fixed  rent,  which  had  not  been  changed 
since  the  Permanent  Settlement,  to  be  exempt  from  enhance- 
ment. Even  raiyats  (who  had  not  a  permanent;  transfer- 
able interest)  whose  rents  had  not  been  changed  since  1793 
were  also  exempt,  being  entitled  to  pattas  at  those  rates. 

And  as  it  was  often  difficult  to  carry  evidence  so  far 
back,  the  privileged  classes  were  aided  by  a  presumption  of 
law  that  if  the  rent  had  not  been  changed  for  twenty  years 
before  suit,  it  had  been  unchanged  since  the  Settlement. 
The  landlord  might  rebut  by  showing  that  a  change  had 
taken  place,  or  that  the  tenure  or  raiyat's  holding  had  been 
created,  and  therefore  the  rent  fixed,  at  some  time  subse- 
quent to  the  Settlement. 

Dr.  Field  remarks  that  the  only  class  who  would  have 
had  any  difficulty  in  producing  the  rebutting  proof  (if 
any  existed),  supposing  they  had  kept  proper  accounts, 
would  be  the  auction-purchasers,  a  class  not  entitled  to 
much  sympathy. 

Head  III.  The  occupancy-right  after  twelve  years,  was 
a  sort  of  cutting  the  Gordian  knot  of  a  complicated  question. 
It  was  quite  certain  that  all  the  old  village  cultivators  at 
the  time  of  Settlement  were — if  in  the  lapse  of  ages  they 
had  lost  actual  proprietary  rights — certainly  entitled  to 
be  considered  '  ex-proprietors '  in  some  sense.  Yet  it  was 
not  all  of  these  that  could  get  the  protection  mentioned 
under  Head  II ;  and  even  if  they  could,  there  were  many 
tenants  of  less  pretensions  who  were  still,  in  the  belief  and 
feeling  of  the  people,  entitled  to  occupancy-rights.  In  the 
sixty  years  that  had  elapsed  since  Settlement,  a  number 
of  such  rights  had  grown  up,  and  tenancies  had  been  held 
from  father  to  son ;  so  that  a  general  rule  of  the  kind  was 
more  likely  to  be  just  in  the  long  run  than  any  attempt 
to  distinguish  or  classify 2.  I  have  stated  the  exceptions 

1  Dr.  Field  thinks  this  left  it  un-  but  perhaps  this  could  not  be  legally 

certain  whether  the  'jot,'  '  hawala,'  proved  (p.  7551. 
'  ganthi,'  and  similar  tenures  I  have  2  The  draft  Bill  limited  the  rule 

described  were  protected  ;  in  popular  to  resident  raiyats,  but  this  was  not 

estimation  they  were  certainly  per-  adopted  in  the  Act  as  passed.     If 

manent,  heritable,  and  transferable,  some  tenants  got,  under  this  clause, 

T  t  2 


644  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

which  were  intended  to  protect  the  landlord's  home-farm, 
and  give  him  the  full  benefit  of  that. 

It  was  further  enacted  that  a  decree  of  Court  must,  in  all 
cases,  be  the  means  of  ejectment ;  and  that  decree  could 
only  be  passed  on  the  ground  of  non-payment  of  rent.  It 
is  obvious,  however,  that  a  protection  from  ejectment  is  not 
sufficient  of  itself ;  for  if  enhancement  is  not  also  regulated, 
the  landlord  might  demand  such  a  rent  that  the  tenant 
could  not  pay  it,  and  so  be  evicted  on  that  ground.  It 
was,  therefore,  necessary  to  add  two  more  provisions :  (i) 
that  the  landlord  could  not  enhance  without  order  of  the 
Revenue  Court,  and  (2)  that  the  Court  should  only  enhance 
on  certain  principles. 

§  3.    Enhancement;  and  other  Rent-rules. 

Head  IV. — The  principles  of  enhancement  were : — 
(a)  The  Court  started  with   the  presumption  that  the 
existing  rent  was  fair  and  equitable  till  the  land- 
lord showed  the  contrary. 

(6)  The  '  contrary '  was  shown  when  it  appeared  that  the 

rent  paid  was  below  the  prevailing  rate  payable 

by  the  same  class  of  raiyat  for  land  of  a  similar 

description  and  with  similar  advantages  in  the 

places  adjacent ; 

(c)  that  the  value  of  the  produce  or  the  productive  powers 

of  the  land  had  been  increased  otherwise  than  by  the 

agency  (or  at  the  expense)  of  the  raiyat ; 

(d}  that  the  quantity  of  land  held  by  the  raiyat  proved 

on  measurement  to  be  greater  than  that  for  which 

rent  had  been  previously  paid. 

I  may  dismiss  (d)  without  remark,  as  it  is  not  really  an 
enhancement  at  all. 

(6)  is  also  a  question  of  enhancement  only  as  regards  the 

rather  more  than  an  absolutely  ac-  The  landlords  had  had  their  innings 

curate  criterion  of  right  would  have  for  sixty  years,  and  if  the  tenantry 

allowed,  it  was  no  more  than  a  com-  now  got  a  little  more  than  was  due, 

pensation  for  years    of   suffering.  it  would  be  hard  to  complain  of  it. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.      645 

individual ;  it  makes  one  man  pay  as  much  as  his  fellows ; 
it  does  not  raise  the  rent  payable  by  the  class  generally. 

(c)  This  is  the  important  ground:  but  it  proved  very 
difficult  of  application.  The  Great  Rent  Case  of  1865  l,  in 
which  all  the  fifteen  Judges  of  the  High  Court  gave  judg- 
ments reviewing  the  whole  history  of  rent  since  the  Perma- 
nent Settlement,  was  an  endeavour  to  settle  it ;  but  while 
the  decision  of  the  majority  gave  a  rule,  it  was  one  which 
it  was  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  apply  in  practice. 

The  enhanced  rent  was  to  be  calculated  so  as  to  bear  to 
the  old  rent  the  same  proportion  that  the  proved  increase 
of  value  in  produce  did  to  the  old  value.  Or  in  a,  formula. 
thus : — 


Former    gross 
value  of  pro- 
duce (average 
of  3-5  normal 

years). 

Present    gross 
value  of  pro- 
duce (average 
of  3-5  normal 

years). 

J  Former 
"  l     rate 

.    l  Enhanced 
'    i        rate. 

The  first  three  terms  had  to  be  proved,  but  the  difficulty 
of  proving  when  the  rent  was  previously  fixed,  so  as  to  give 
the  date  at  which  the  '  former '  value  was  to  be  taken  for 
comparison  with  '  present '  value,  was  very  great.  '  The 
most  experienced  officers,'  says  Dr.  Field,  '  have  pronounced 
the  rule  to  be  unworkable,  and  the  Zamindars  have  confirmed 
the  verdict  by  giving  up  all  attempt  to  work  it  in  their  own 
interest.' 

We  must  also  notice  that  Act  X  gives  some  general 
rules  for  all  tenants.  No  tenant  can  be  made  to  pay  a 
higher  rent  than  the  rent  payable  for  the  previous  year, 
unless  a  written  notice  has  been  served  on  him  before  the 
close  of  the  agricultural  year,  specifying  the  higher  rent 
claimed  and  the  reason  of  the  enhancement ;  and  the  tenant 
can  contest  this,  either  by  suit  or  in  answer  to  a  suit  for 
arrears.  This  applies  to  tenants  not  holding  under  any  agree- 
ment, or  under  an  agreement  indefinite  as  to  period, 

1  Thakurani   Dasi   vs.   Bisheshur      another  case — Hills  vs.  Ishar  Ghos. 
Mukharji — Bengal  Law  Rep.,  Supp.        Weekly  Rep.  (special  volume). 
Vol.   (Full   Bench}  202.      See  also 


646  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

or  under  one  which  has  expired  or  become  void  by  sale  of 
the  estate  for  arrears  of  revenue. 

§  4.    Pattas  and  Receipts. 

Heads  V  and  VI  require  no  remark.  It  is  now  recog- 
nized that,  what  with  decrees  of  Court  and  improved 
means  of  record,  it  is  immaterial  whether  pattas  are  given 
or  not. 

§  5.    Law  of  Distraint. 

Head  VII. — Distraint  is  to  be  made  only  against  culti- 
vators (i.  e.  not  against  farmers,  patnidars,  &c.)5  and  only  for 
the  rent  of  one  year ;  no  distraint  is  allowed  for  any  sum 
in  excess  of  the  rent  payable  for  the  same  land  in  the  pre- 
ceding year,  unless  a  written  engagement  for  the  payment 
of  such  excess  had  been  executed  by  the  cultivator. 

Before  distraint,  a  written  notice  specifying  the  demand, 
and  the  grounds  on  which  it  was  made,  is  required.  After 
distraint,  application  must  be  made  to  the  proper  officer  for 
sale  within  five  days.  If  the  distraint  was  made  while  the 
crop  was  standing,  the  cultivator  may  reap  and  gather  it. 

It  is  stated  that  these  provisions,  good  as  they  seem  on 
paper,  were  not  useful  in  practice. 

§  6.    Revenue  Courts. 

Head  VIII. — The  transfer  of  jurisdiction  in  1859  was 
cancelled  ten  years  later ;  but  that  Act  (B.  C.  VIII.  of  1869) 
did  not  apply  to  all  districts * ;  so  that  where  it  or  the  sub- 
sequent Act  of  1885  does  not  apply,  Act  X  of  1859  still 
retains  the  Revenue  Courts.  The  reason  for  giving  revenue 
officers  power  in  these  matters,  is  that  the  experience  of 
Civil  Courts  is  not  always  such  as  enables  them  to  under- 
stand revenue  practice,  and  that  the  settlement  of  rents 
depends  on  facts  and  circumstances  not  '  easily  reducible  to 

1  See  §  9,  post. 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OE  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     647 

the  usual  forms  of  evidence.'  Officers  daily  dealing  with 
land-management,  and  knowing  the  local  details  in  many 
cases,  acquire  a  sense  of  fitness  and  a  practical  power  of 
adjusting  rents  which  are  invaluable,  but  cannot  always  be 
adequately  explained  in  a  formal  judgment. 

§  7.    Transfer  of  Tenures. 

Head  IX. — The  provisions  for  registering  transfers  of  farms, 
taluqs,  and  tenures  intermediate  between  the  cultivator  or 
the  landlord,  were  thought  necessary,  and  have  been  retained 
on  a  somewhat  different  basis  even  in  the  later  law  of  1885 
(as  we  shall  presently  see).  But  they  are  said  not  to  work, 
owing  to  a  fear  (which  is  legally  groundless)  that  registry 
of  a  transfer  would  imply  the  landlord's  admission  of 
its  validity.  On  the  other  hand,  the  rules  were  supposed 
to  check  secret  transfers  and  transactions  whereby  one  man 
held  in  the  name  of  the  other,  and  thus  created  difficulties  in 
cases  where  the  real  owner  of  the  tenure  was  required  to  be 
known ;  and  it  was  believed  that  they  prevented  litigation. 

§  8.    Some  objections  to  the  Act. 

Act  X  of  1859  was  not  a  complete  Code  of  Tenant  law, 
and  yet  contained  no  provision  that  it  was  not  intended  to 
touch  any  customary  right  not  inconsistent  with, or  expressly 
or  impliedly  disallowed  or  modified  by  it.  It  also  failed 
to  recognize,  as  distinct  from  raiyats'  holdings,  tenures 
which,  if  not  easily  definable,  were,  nevertheless,  in  the 
popular  estimation,  permanent,  heritable,  and  transferable. 

The  landlords  also  objected  to  the  working  of  the  enhance- 
ment clauses,  which  failed  where  they  considered  they  had 
a  good  claim l. 

1  '  The  principal  faults  of  Act  X  of  could  not  prove,  and  the  landlord 

1859  have  been  said  to  be  that  it  one  which  he   could   not  enforce.' 

placed  the  right  of  occupancy  which  (Introduction  to  R.  and  F.  Tenant  Act.} 

it  recognized  in  the  tenant,  and  the  Minor  amendments  have  been  made 

right  of  enhancement,  which  it  re-  in  Act  X,  and  appear  incorporated 

cognized  in  the  landlord,  on  a  pre-  in  the  Legislative  Department  edi- 

carious  footing.  It  gave,  or  professed  tion  in  the '  Lower  Provinces  Code.' 
to  give,  the  raiyat  a  right  which  he 


648  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

§  9.    Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1869. 

This  Act  of  the  Bengal  Council  was  merely  a  new 
edition  of  Act  X  of  1  859,  with  certain  amendments  of  detail 
(not  of  principle  as  regards  tenants'  rights).  The  details 
need  not  occupy  our  attention  here  ;  they  relate  to  matters 
of  limitation  of  suits,  to  powers  of  measurement  of  estates, 
and  so  forth.  The  important  change  was  the  re-transfer  of 
landlord  and  tenant  cases  to  the  Civil  Courts. 

The  Act  only  applied  to  districts  to  which  it  was  ex- 
pressly extended,  and  these  were  the  permanently-settled, 
and  what  I  may  call  '  regular  '  districts,  in  the  Bhagulpore, 
Patna,  Rajshahi,  Bardwan,  Presidency,  Dacca,  and  Chitta- 
gong  Civil  Divisions  ;  and  the  law  did  not  apply  to  Jalpai- 
guri,  Darjiling,  the  Orissa  districts,  the  Chutiya  Nagpur 
districts,  and  the  Santal  Pergunnahs.  It  is  therefore  a 
local  question  whether  Act  X  of  1859  (and  its  amending 
Acts)  still  remains  in  force  :  it  does  if  declared  in  force,  and 
if  neither  Bengal  Act  VIII  of  1869  nor  Act  VIII  of  1885 
has  superseded  it.  Act  VIII  of  1885  is  in  force  in  all  the 
Bengal  and  Bihar  districts,  not  being  Scheduled  Districts, 
and  is  not  in  force  in  Orissa. 

§  10.    Local  operation  of  the  several  Acts. 

Full  details  on  this  subject  will  be  found  in  the  notes  to 
Section  i  (3)  of  Act  VIII  of  1885.  The  following  table  is 
generally  correct  :  — 

Regulation  Districts  in  the  Divisions  of  — 
Bhagulpur 
Patna 
Rajshahi 
Bardwan     .........  I  Act  VIII  of  1885. 

Presidency  ......... 

(Dacca)  Dakha  ... 
Chittagong  ......... 

Katak1...,  .  .      .    , 

Balasor  Ac* 


.  .. 

Puri  ..................  j      ing  Acts. 

1  Banki,    formerly    a    scheduled      Orissa  is  a    scheduled   tract,  and 
tract,  has  now  (Act  XXV  of  1881)      Act  X  has  not  been  applied  to  it. 
become  part  of  Katak.    Angul  in 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     649 


Chutiya  Nagpur  ......  S  ^h^da£i..  .'.'.'.'.'.'.  I  Bengal  Act  II  of  1869  and 

(Singhbhum  .........  }      also  I  of  1879- 

Manbhum  ................................................  Act  X  of  1859  and  Bengal 

Act  II  of  1869. 

Santal  Pergunnahs  ....................................  Regulation  III  of  1872  and 

Rent  Rgulation  II  of  1886. 

Chittagong  Hill  Tracts  ..............................  See  Act  XXII  of  1860. 

Jalpaiguri  ...............      (a)  South    of  dis-     Act  X  of  1859,  &c. 

trict,  once  part  of 
the  old  Ramgarh 
District. 
(fc)  Western  Dwars.   See  Act  XVI  of  1869. 

Darjiling  ................................................  Act  X  of  1859,  &c. 

The  Act  of  1885  may  be  extended  to  any  of  the  Scheduled 
Districts  (by  Section  3,  Act  XIV  of  1874),  and  may  be  ex- 
tended to  Orissa  (by  the  Act  itself,  Section  I  (3)  ). 


§  ii.    The  origin  of  Act  VIII  of  1885. 

As  no  one  is  likely  to  enter  on  a  detailed  study  of  the 
present  law  applicable  to  the  larger  and  most  important 
part  of  Bengal  and  Bihar,  without  Rampini  and  Finucane's 
edition  in  their  hand,  it  will  be  my  part  only  to  call  attention 
to  the  salient  points. 

In  1876  a  bill  for  a  serious  alteration  as  regards  defini- 
tion of  rights  was  commenced  with,  but  only  led  to  the 
appointment  of  a  Rent  Law  Commission  (in  1879)  to  inquire 
into  the  whole  subject,  aided  by  a  Committee  of  experienced 
officials,  indigo-planters,  and  landlords,  to  consider  the 
special  difficulties  of  Bihar.  A  complete  draft  law  was 
prepared  by  their  means  in  1880;  but  the  Government 
could  not  accept  the  draft  in  its  entirety.  Several  other 
drafts  were  then  made  under  various  authority,  and  the 
present  law  was  introduced  into  the  Legislative  Council  of 
India  in  1883,  and  received  assent  on  I4th  March,  1885.  It 
was  declared  to  come  into  force  on  ist  November,  I8851, 
except  certain  portions,  the  operation  of  which  was  by  law 
(Act  XX  of  1885)  deferred  to  ist  February,  1886. 

1  Notification,  Cakutta  Gazette,  4th  September,  1885. 


650  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 


§  12.    Analysis  of  the  Law  of  1885. 

In  this  Act  (as  amended  by  Act  VIII  of  1886)  the  follow- 
ing classes  are  recognized  : — 

(i)  Tenure-holders   and    under-tenure-holders    (e.g.   the 
patnidar  and  darpatnidar)  ; 

Raiyats  at  fixed  rates ; 


(2)  Raiyats 


Occupancy -raiyats ; 


Settled-raiyats ; 
Non-oceupancy-raiyats. 

(3)  Under-raiyats  (or  sub-tenants). 

This,  it  will  be  observed,  obviates  the  objection  to  the  old 
Act,  as  regards  reducing  holders  of  tenures  to  being  merely 
a  kind  of  tenant. 

Any  non-proprietary  holding  exceeding  100  bighas,  is 
presumed  to  be  a  '  tenure '  till  the  contrary  is  shown. 

The  tenure-holder,  who  has  paid  a  fixed  rent  from  1793, 
Sec.  6.  is,  as  before,  protected  from  enhancement,  except  on  proof 
that  local  custom,  or  the  terms  of  the  tenure,  warrant  an 
increase,  or  that  the  tenure-holder,  by  receiving  reduction 
of  his  rent  (not  being  on  account  of  loss  of  area)  has  sub- 
jected himself  to  the  payment  of  the  increase  demanded, 
and  that  the  lands  are  capable  of  affording  it1.  And  in 
this  (rare)  case  of  enhancement,  the  limit  is  (subject  to  any 
contract  between  the  parties)  such  customary  rate  as  other 
tenure-holders  in  the  vicinity  are  paying;  if  such  a  rate 
does  not  exist,  then  the  limit  is  what  the  Court  thinks  fair 
and  equitable.  And  in  drawing  conclusions  the  Court  will 
never  leave  the  tenure-holder  with  a  less  profit  than  10  per 
cent,  on  the  gross  collections  of  rent,  and  will  have  regard 
to  the  conditions  under  which  the  tenure  arose,  whether  it 
paid  a  fine  to  begin  with,  or  was  for  reclamation,  and  what 
Sec.  7.  improvements  have  been  made.  The  rent  once  enhanced 
cannot  again  be  raised  for  fifteen  years. 

1  This  resulted  from  an  old  stand-  another.   It  is  explained  in  §  384  of 

ing  custom  that  if  a  taluqdar  ac-  Shore's  Minute,  printed  in  the  Fifth 

cepted    remission   or  reduction    at  Report,  vol.  i.  p.  162. 
one  time,  he  must  accept  increase  at 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     651 

The  tenure-holder  cannot  be  ejected,  except  on  breach  of 
some  express  condition,  not  inconsistent  with  the  Act.  A 
tenure  is  heritable  and  may  be  bequeathed,  and  is  trans- 
ferable by  registered  instrument,  or  by  course  of  law. 

Sections  13  to  15  are  the  ones  altered  by  Act  VIII  of 
1886  and  represent  the  amended  form  of  the  'Registry' 
rules  for  securing  that  it  be  known  who  was  the  actual 
tenure -holder,  repressing  'banami'  holdings  (see  note,  p.  640), 
arid  preventing  litigation — noted  under  Head  IX  of  Act  X 
of  1859. 

§  13.    Raiyats. 

The  first  class  of  raiyat  •  may  hold  either  at  a  fixed  rent 
or  a  fixed  rate  of  rent ;  the  distinction  is  obvious.  He  is 
subject  to  the  same  provisions  as  to  succession  and  transfer 
as  a  tenure-holder,  and  he  cannot  be  ejected  except  on 
breach  of  a  condition  (consistent  with  the  Act),  whereby  he  Sec.  18. 
becomes,  by  contract,  liable  to  ejectment.  The  second 
class  (occupancy-raiyats)  includes,  generally,  all  who,  imme- 
diately before  November  1885,  had  the  right  of  occupancy, 
by  the  operation  of  any  law,  by  custom,  or  otherwise ;  so 
that  all  existing  rights  are  saved. 

Not  only  so,  but  any  tenant  (before  or  after  the  Act)  who 
has  held  for  twelve  years  continuously  any  land  in  the 
village,  whether  under  a  lease  or  not,  becomes  a  '  settled- 
raiyat.'  It  need  not  be  the  same  plot  of  land  (as  under 
Act  X),  so  that  a  landlord  cannot  evade  occupancy  by 
shifting  the  site  of  the  cultivation  within  the  same  village. 

The  holding  may  have  been  by  means  of  the  person  whose 
heir  the  present  holder  is. 

A  person  is  a  '  settled-raiyat '  as  long  as  he  holds  any  land 
as  a  raiyat  in  the  village,  and  for  one  year  thereafter :  and 
even  if  the  tenant  abandon,  but  return  in  time,  under  section 
87  he  does  not  lose  his  right.  The  raiyat  starts  with  the 
presumption  in  his  favour  that  he  has  held  for  twelve 
years  ;  it  is,  of  course,  much  easier  for  the  landlord  to  show  Sec.  20  (7). 
how  long  he  really  has  been  there,  if  he  is  not  a  twelve- 
years'  tenant. 


652  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 

Section  ai  should  be  read  with  Section  178,  and  the 
notes  ;  these  will  explain  the  object,  which  is  generally,  to 
prevent  an  ignorant  tenant  contracting  himself  out  of  the 
benefit  of  occupancy ;  and  especially  doing  so  between 
March  1883  and  the  passing  of  the  Act,  when  the  whole 
matter  was  in  Council,  and  sharp  landlords  might  have 
brought  pressure  to  bear  on  tenants  to  make  such  contracts. 

Section  a  a  makes  provision  in  cases  of  merger  of  rights 
by  transfer,  succession,  &c. 

The  occupancy-tenant  has  to  pay  rent '  at  fair  and  equit- 
able rates.'  He  cannot  be  ejected  except  by  Court  decree, 
on  the  ground  that  he  has  used  his  land  in  a  manner  which 
renders  it  unfit  for  the  purpose  of  the  tenancy,  or  has  broken 
a  condition  (consistent  with  the  Act)  on  breach  of  which  he 
is  by  contract  liable  to  ejectment1. 

An  occupancy-right  (subject  to  any  custom  to  the  con- 
trary) descends  by  inheritance ;  but  in  default  of  heirs  it 
dies  out  (i.e.  does  not  lapse  to  the  Crown). 

It  will  be  observed  that  the  law  is  intentionally  silent  as 
to  whether  occupancy-rights  are  transferable  by  bequest, 
sale,  gift,  mortgage,  &c.,  or  not.  The  matter  is  regulated 
by  custom,  which  is  saved  by  Section  183.  (See  illustra- 
tion i  to  the  section 2.) 

The  'private  lands'  of  proprietors  are  (as  before)  protected 
from  the  growth  of  occupancy-rights,  only  that  the  subject 
is  specially  dealt  with  in  chapter  xi  of  the  Act,  which 
provides  clearly  for  determining  what  are  private  l%nds. 

Thus,  it  will  be  seen  that  comparing  Heads  II  and  III  of 
the  abstract  Act  of  1 859  (p.  642)  a  very  considerable  advance 
has  been  made  in  the  law. 

1  And  even  then  section  155  must  2  The  law  on  the  whole  subject 

be    read,   as   it   affords   a    remedy       of  transferability  is  given  at  pages 
against  absolute  ejectment.  70-2,  F.  and  R.  Tenancy  Act. 


CHAP,  iv.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     653 


§  14.    Enhancement. 

It  will  here  "also  be  interesting  to  look  back  to  p.  644, 
Head  IV  (Enhancement).  Here  we  found  the  law  of  1859 
was  somewhat  impracticable.  It  was  one  of  the  main  objects 
of  the  law  of  1885  to  effect  an  improvement.  As  far  as  the 
landlords  are  concerned,  the  new  rules  for  deciding  an 
enhancement  suit  are  certainly  made  easier  and  more  prac- 
tical ;  while  the  tenant  has  been  protected  by  not  being 
allowed,  in  his  ignorance,  to  bind  himself  to  submit  to  an 
unreasonable  enhancement,  so  that  'a  raiyat  cannot  now 
contract  himself  out  of  almost  any  of  the  rights  conferred 
upon  him  by  the  Act  V 

The  initial  presumption  (as  under  the  former  Act)  is,  that 
the  existing  rent  of  an  occupancy-tenant  is  'fair  and 
equitable ' ;  the  landlord  must  prove  that  it  ought  to  be 
enhanced. 

A  money  rent  cannot  be  enhanced  except  as  provided  by 
the  Act. 

A  produce  rent  cannot  be  enhanced  at  all,  and  very  na- 
turally so,  for  it  is  a  question  of  sharing  the  produce,  and 
this  really  enhances  itself  by  the  rise  in  value  of  the  share 
which  naturally  occurs. 

Section  40,  however,  gives  either  the  landlord  or  occu- 
pancy-tenant power  to  apply  for  a  commutation  of  a  grain- 
rent  into  a  cash -rent. 

The  specific  provisions  of  the  Act  stand  thus  : — 

I.  Enhancement  by  Contract. 

The  conditions  are  that — 

(a)  Contract  is  to  be  written  and  registered ;  Sec.  29. 

(6)  The  rise  agreed  on  must  not  exceed  2  annas  in  the 
rupee ; 

(c)  The  rent  fixed  is  not  to  be  liable  to  further  enhance- 
ment for  fifteen  years. 

1  F.  and  R  Tenancy  Act,  Introduction,  p.  xiii. 


654  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH   INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

There  are,  however,  provisoes  added,  which  should  be 
referred  to ;  for  instance,  (6)  will  not  apply  where  a  higher 
•  rate  is  contracted  for  on  the  express  ground  that  the  land- 
lord has  made,  or  will  make,  an  improvement  to  which  the 
raiyat  is  not  otherwise  entitled.  The  provisoes  explain 
themselves,  except,  perhaps,  the  first,  which  refers  to  the 
case  where  a  tenant,  though  entitled  to  ignore  the  contract, 
because  not  in  writing  or  not  registered,  has  actually  paid 
a  certain  rate  of  rent  for  three  consecutive  years  (which 
he  might  have  refused  if  he  had  chosen). 

II.  Enhancement  by  Suit  in  Court. 
The  grounds  on  which  a  decree  can  be  made  are  : — 
Sec  30  (a)  That  the  rate  is  below  what  other  occupancy-tenants 

pay,  in  the  absence  of  special  circumstances  ; 
(6)  Rise  in  average  local  price  of  staple  food-crops  dur- 
ing currency  of  present  rent ; 
(c)  Increase  in  productive  powers  of  the  land — 

(1)  By  landlord's  improvement ; 

(2)  Fluvial  action  (which  includes  a  change  in  the 

course  of  the  river  rendering  irrigation  possible). 
These  three  grounds  are  nearly  but  not  quite,  the  same 
as  the  older  law,  and  are  such  as  are  usually  entered  in 
modern  Tenancy  Acts1. 

In  order  that  these  principles  of  enhancement  may  be 
8608.31,32,  applied  properly,  the  Act  goes  on  to  explain  their  use. 
33,  and  34.      ^s  ^o  ^aj  foe  rates  generally  paid  during  the  previous 
three  or  more  years  are  to  be  looked  to  ;  and  enhancement 
will  not  be  decreed  unless  there  is  a  substantial  difference 
between  the  rate  so  discovered,  and  that  which  the  raiyat  is 
paying.     A  '  local  inquiry  '  may  be  ordered  with  a  view  of 
discovering  the  prevailing  rate. 

The  caste  of  the  cultivator  will  only  be  taken  into  consider- 
ation when  it  is  proved  that  the  local  custom  requires  it. 

1  The  student  will  find  it  instruc-  1886  (Oudh\  section  33,  and  com- 

tive  to  turn  to  the  similar  sections  pare  them  with  section  17,  Act  X  of 

in   Act  XII  of    1881    (N.-W.   Pro-  1859,  and  this  section  30. 
vinces),  section    13,   Act  XXII   of 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     655 

As  to  (6),  the  average  prices  for  the  ten  years  immediately 
preceding  the  suit  are  compared  with  the  average  prices 
'  during  such  other  decennial  period  as  it  may  appear 
equitable  and  practicable  to  take  for  comparison.'  Then 
the  rule  of  enhancement,  stated  in  the  form  of  a  proportion 
sum,  so  that  the  student  may  compare  it  with  the  old  rule 
(cf.  p.  645,  ante)  will  be — 


Value   of  pro-1)        /Value   in   10-  \ 

duce  in  select-  I    .  J    years  period  I  . .  J  Former 
i  ^  .  ^     *  -I'll     ^ » •  *\ 


ed     10  -  years  j    *    J    immediately  f "    )    rent, 
period.  J        (.   before  suit.    /        \ 


'    |       rent. 


Enhanced 


Provided  that  the  excess  of  the  second  term  over  the  first 
term  is  to  be  reduced  by  one-third  in  order  to  give  the 
enhanced  rate ;  and  if  a  ten-year  period  is  not  practicable 
a  shorter  period  may  be  used. 

As  to  (c).  The  landlord's  improvements  must  have  been 
registered.  The  registration  (in  a  book  kept  for  the  pur- 
pose) will  obviate  any  dispute  as  to  whether  an  improvement 
has  been  made  or  not.  And,  naturally,  as  '  improvements ' 
vary,  the  increase  of  rent  will  depend  on  the  amount  of 
increase  in  the  productive  power  of  the  soil  which  is  likely 
to  result ;  the  cheapness  and  costliness  of  the  improvement ; 
the  question  whether  the  improvement  will  require  a  costly 
style  of  cultivation  to  benefit  from  it ;  and  lastly,  it  is 
important  to  consider  whether  the  rent  is  not  already  so 
high  that  the  land,  even  as  improved,  cannot  well  bear 
a  higher  rate. 

As  all  these  matters  are,  to  some  extent,  matters  of  ex- 
pectation and  probability,  any  decree  made  is  liable  to 
reconsideration,  '  in  the  event  of  the  improvement  not  pro- 
ducing, or  ceasing  to  produce,  the  estimated  effect.'  For  the 
case  of  '  fluvial  action,'  Section  34  may  be  referred  to. 

Sections  35  and  36  contain  the  important  general  provisoes 
that  in  no  case  is  an  enhancement  to  be  decreed  '  which  is, 
under  the  circumstances  of  the  case,  unfair  or  inequitable  ' ; 
and  that  if  a  sudden  enhancement  would  press  hardly,  the 
increase  may  be  gradual,  i.e.  by  rises  extending  over  not 
more  than  five  years  till  the  full  rate  is  reached. 


656  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BBITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

Section  37  is  also  by  way  of  general  proviso,  since  an 
enhancement  on  the  ground  of  '  prevailing  rate '  or  of '  rise 
in  prices '  (a,  6)  will  not  be  allowed,  if,  within  the  fifteen 
years  next  before  the  suit,  there  has  been — 

(1)  A  contract  for  enhancement  dated  after  March  2nd, 

1883; 

(2)  A   decree   for   commutation   of  grain-rent   to    cash 

(Section  40) ; 

(3)  A  decree  for  enhancement  (or  a  decree  of  dismissal  of 

suit   on  the  merits)   on  the   same   grounds,  'or 
grounds  corresponding  thereto.' 

It  should  be  added  that  to  facilitate,  in   future,  these 
Sec.  39.  inquiries  about  the  value  of  produce,  the  law  prescribes  the 
maintenance  of  price  lists  by  the  Collector. 

§  15.    Reduction  of  Rent. — Commutation. 

As  rent  can  be  enhanced,  so  there  are  occasions  when 
a  reduction  may  be  called  for  and  justly  enforced  by  law  if 

Sec.  38.  refused  voluntarily.     And  it  has  already  been  mentioned 
that  grain-rents  (still  so  common  in  Bihar,  p.  602,  ante}  can  . 

Sec.  40.  be  commuted  to  cash,  on  demand  of  either  landlord  or 
tenant. 

Grain-rents  are  both  natural  and  useful  in  certain  cases 
and  in  the  early  stages  of  society.  If,  for  instance,  in  out- 
lying and  precarious  tracts  crops  are  liable  to  loss  by  flood 
or  drought,  or  locusts  or  wild  beasts,  the  tenant  who  has  to 
give  only  a  fraction  of  the  grain — actually  produced  and 
garnered,  receives  a  practical  reduction  in  bad  years ;  the 
calamity  of  season  and  uncertainty  fall  on  both  parties 
equally.  But  in  other  places,  where  this  ground  does  not 
exist,  other  objections  come  to  light — fraud  and  concealment 
on  one  side,  over-estimate  and  extortion  on  the  other,  and 
the  loss  to  the  tenant  of  a  rise  in  value.  As  the  country 
becomes  more  settled,  and  cultivation  reaches  its  limits,  the 
tendency  is  always  to  give  up  grain-rents. 


CHAP.  IV.]  THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.  657 


§  1 6.    Non-occupancy  Tenants. 

The  ordinary  raiyat  is  not,  and  ought  not  to  be,  in  any 
country  in  India,  left  entirely  to  '  competition.'  All  tenant 
laws  admit  the  principle  that  some  protection  he  requires. 

If  a  tenant  accepts  land  for  the  first  time,  he  must  natu- 
rally accept  the  terms  offered1 ;  if  he  does  not  like  them,  let 
him  give  up  his  attempt  to  get  the  land,  in  favour  of  some 
one  who  does ;  and  if  the  landlord  finds  that  no  one  will 
accept  his  terms,  naturally  he  will  come  down. 

But  once  the  tenant  has  accepted,  he  cannot  be  subject 
to  extortion.  Further  enhancement  must  be  by  registered 
agreement2  or  by  means  of  what  the  Act  calls  an  agree- 
ment under  Section  46,  of  which  presently. 

JEjectment  has,  also,  to  be  regulated.  It  is  obvious  that 
it  is  of  no  use  regulating  enhancement  without  regulating 
ejectment,  and  vice  versa. 

Section  89  has  here  to  be  read,  because  it  applies  to  all 
tenants.  There  is  no  ejectment,  except  by  decree  of  Court ; 
Section  44  gives  plainly  the  grounds  on  which  an  ordinary 
raiyat  can  be  decreed  against 3. 

Section  46  requires  some  remark.  Supposing  the  tenant 
refuses  to  accept  a  landlord's  demand  for  enhancement  and 
so  becomes  liable  to  a  suit  for  ejectment ;  the  landlord  must, 
as  a  preliminary  measure,  put  into  Court  a  proposed  agree- 
ment which  will  be  served  on  the  tenant  in  a  specified  way. 
If  the  tenant  fails  to  accept  this,  a  suit  for  ejectment  will  be 
lodged.  When  such  a  suit  is  lodged,  the  Court  will  declare 
what  is  a  fair  and  equitable  rent  and  give  the  tenant  the 
option  of  paying  that, — which  will  not  be  subject  to  any 
further  enhancement  for  Jive  years. 

1  See,   however,   Section    47.     A  hanced  rate  which  he  might  have 

man  must  be  bond  fide  a  new  comer,  refused. 

not  a  man  really  already  on  the  3  The  ordinary  raiyat  is   ejected 

land,  whom  the  Zamindar  proposes  for  arrears.     The  tenure-holder  and 

to  treat  as  a  new-comer.  occupancy-raiyat  of  both  classes  is 

a  Unless,  as  in  a  previous  section,  not;    his  tenure  is  put  up  to  sale 

the  tenant  has  de  facto  waived  this,  (^Section  65). 
by  paying  for  three  years  the  en- 

VOL.  I.  U  U 


658  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

If  the  tenant  will  not  have  this,  of  course  a  decree  for 
ejectment  will  issue.  Under-raiyats  are  protected  by  Sec- 
tions 48  and  49,  which  need  no  comment. 


§  17.    General  Provisions  as  to  Rents. 

It  will  be  observed  that  the  whole  question  of  pattas  has 
been  allowed  to  drop.  Receipts  for  rent  are  retained,  and 
various  provisions  are  made. 

The  general  principles  of  rent  need  only  be  read  (Chapter 
VIII)  to  be  understood. 

The  old  principle  about  rents  not  changed  since  Settle- 
ment is  retained,  and  with  it  the  twenty  years'  prescription 
already  explained. 

An  alteration  in  area  of  a  tenancy  may  always  involve 
an  alteration  of  rent  without  infringement  of  the  privileges 
already  noticed. 

Rent  is  always  payable,  subject  to  agreement  or  esta- 
blished usage,  in  four  (quarterly)  instalments. 

Sections  56-60  go  into  details  about  receipts  for  rent,  and 
counterparts,  which  will,  perhaps,  not  prove  very  effective, 
or  be  easily  enforced. 

§  1 8.    Arrears  of  Rent. 

Sections  65  to  68  should  be  read  on  the  subject  of 
arrears  ;  interest  is  allowed  by  law,  and  damages  in  some 
cases  of  wilful  non-payment ;  but  not  both.  Any  decree 
for  ejectment  on  the  ground  of  arrears  (amount  to  be  speci- 
fied) can  be  avoided,  if  the  tenant,  within  fifteen  days,  pays 
the  amount  with  costs. 

The  landlord  cannot  harass  a  tenant  by  successive  suits 
for  arrears  ;  having  got  his  decree,  he  cannot  sue  again  for 
Sec.  147.  three  months.  The  restrictions  on  execution  of  decrees  for 
rent  have  been  removed  to  a  great  extent  by  reason  of  the 
application  of  the  Civil  Procedure  Code  subject  to  certain 
modifications.  A  decree  for  arrears  of  rent  must  be  ex- 
ecuted by  the  landlord  himself  or  a  transferee  of  the 


CHAP.  IV.]    THE  EELATION  OF  LANDLORD  AND  TENANT.     659 

landlord's  interest  in  the  land,  not  by  any  chance  assignee 
of  the  decree  ;  on  the  other  hand,  there  is  no  restriction  as 
to  the  order  in  which  certain  property  must  be  proceeded 
against,  &c.,  other  than  what  the  Civil  Procedure  Code 
prescribes. 

The  tenant's  holding  is  treated  as  hypothecated  for  the 
rent  due,  and  no  transfer  is  valid  while  any  arrears  of  rent 
which  have  accrued  are  unpaid  *. 

§  19.    Produce  Rents. 

The  Sections  69  to  71  provide  for  various  matters  likely 
to  be  in  dispute,  e.g.  appointing  an  officer  to  make  an 
appraisement  of  the  standing  crops,  and  to  make  a  division 
(see  p.  602  ante),  and  defining  the  right  of  possession  of  the 
crop  and  the  grain  at  the  threshing-floor. 

§  20.    Improvements. 

Chapter  IX  deals  with  a  number  of  additional  matters 
between  landlord  and  tenant,  which  will  give  relief.  The 
whole  question  of  improvements  is  dealt  with,  defining 
what  an  improvement  is,  settling  that  occupancy  and  fixed- 
rate  raiyats  can  always  make  improvements  of  all  kinds, 
but  that  non-occupancy  tenants  can  only  make  improve- 
ments of  certain  kinds,  and  giving  a  convenient  power  of 
reference  to  the  Collector,  whose  decision  is  final.  There  is 
special  provision  for  registering  improvements  and  recording 
evidence  as  to  their  being  made,  intended  to  save  future 
disputes. 

There  are,  of  course,  provisions   for   compensation  for 
improvements  on  ejectment.     Also,  when  ejectment  takes 
place,  there  is  a  protection  in  respect  of  growing  crops  and  Sec.  156. 
land  prepared  for  sowing.     As  the  number  of  tenants  fixed 
in  their  holdings  is  now  great,  a  reasonable  facility  is  given 

^ 

1  In  these  remarks,  I  have  gone  cedure  sections  about  execution  of 
out  of  the  order  of  the  Act  in  order  decrees,  &c.,  come  later  on  in  the 
to  complete  the  subject ;  the  pro-  Act. 

U  U  2 


66O  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

to  landlords  to  apply  to  the  Civil  Courts  for  an  order  to 
retake  a  plot  of  ground  wanted  for  religious,  charitable,  or 
educational  buildings,  on  fair  terms. 

§  21.    Miscellaneous  Provisions. 

Section  85  regulates  the  raiyat's  power  of  sub-letting,  and 
Section  90  the  landlord's  power  of  measurement.  Section 
93,  et  seq.,  call  for  some  remark,  as  these  provisions  will 
probably  smooth  over  many  cases  of  dispute,  where  there 
are  co-sharers  on  an  estate,  and  they  are  at  feud  as  to 
the  management ;  this  harasses  tenants  greatly,  and  a 
'  common  manager '  can  now  be  appointed. 

§  22.    Distraint. 

Passing  over  some  intermediate  chapters,  it  will  be  ob- 
served that  Chapter  XII  regulates  the  power  of  distraint. 
It  can  now  only  be  done  through  the  Civil  Court ;  and  not- 
withstanding the  attachment,  the  tenant  can  reap,  gather, 
or  store  the  produce,  and  do  everything  necessary  to  its 
preservation. 

§  23.    Record-of- Rights. 

I  left  out  of  its  place  Chapter  X,  which  is  really  the  most 
important  feature  of  the  Act,  and  if  I  may  venture  a  pro- 
phecy, will  be  gradually  acted  on,  till  the  only  complete 
satisfaction  for  all  classes  of  rights  is  gained,  viz.  a  cadastral 
survey  and  record- of-rights  for  every  estate,  large  and 
small,  in  the  province. 

Under  circumstances  stated  in  Section  101,  a  survey  anc 
a  record- of-rights  can  be  ordered  for  a  local  area  in  an\ 
case  with  the  sanction  of  the  Governor-General  in  Council, 
and  in  certain  specified  cases  without  such  sanction. 

And  among  such  cases  I  may  mention  that  the  procedure 
applies  to  all  estates  under  the  Court  of  Wards  and  all  kh^ 
mahals  or  estates  which  are  or  have  become  the  property  oi 
Government. 


CHAP.  IV.]     THE  RELATION  OF  LANDLOED  AND  TENANT.     66 1 

Where  this  Act  is  in  force,  Act  VIII  of  1879  is  repealed  ; 
and  as  Government,  in  its  own  estates,  as  landlord,  is  sub- 
ject to  the  same  liabilities  to  tenant-occupancy  and  other 
rights  as  other  landlords,  it  desires  to  have  those  rights 
defined  and  protected  and  its  own  management  facilitated, 
provision  is  made  for  a  record-of-rights  and  a  settlement  of 
rents.  (See  page  459). 

In  any  area  in  which  this  survey  and  record-of-rights  is 
ordered,  the  ordinary  Courts  are  precluded  from  entertain- 
ing any  suit  for  alteration  of  rent  or  the  determination  of 
the  status  of  any  tenant. 

§  24.    Jurisdiction. 

The  law  of  1885  retains  the  jurisdiction  of  Civil  Courts 
over  suits  between  landlord  and  tenant,  except  in  the  case 
of  a  survey  and  record  above  mentioned.  The  High  Court 
is  empowered  to  make  rules,  declaring  that  any  portions 
of  the  Civil  Procedure  Code  do  not  apply,  or  apply  with 
modifications :  and,  as  already  stated,  the  Act  itself,  in 
Chapter  XIII,  makes  certain  special  provisions  as  regards 
procedure. 

§  25.    Sale  of  Tenures  for  Arrears. 

The  sale  law  has  (as  we  have  seen),  from  time  to  time, 
dealt  with  the  '  clear-title '  to  be  given  when  an  estate  is 
put  up  to  sale  for  arrears  of  the  Government  revenue;  and 
as  tenures,  and  certain  raiyati  holdings,  can  be  sold  for 
arrears  of  rent,  in  executing  a  decree,  there  are  similar 
questions  as  to  voiding  the  subordinate  contracts  or  rights. 
These  are  dealt  with  in  Chapter  XIV.  Briefly,  all  such 
subordinate  rights  are  classed  into  (i)  'protected  interests' 
and  (2)  '  incumbrances ' ;  the  former  are  not  voidable,  the 
latter  are,  but  only  in  certain  cases. 


CHAPTER  V. 

THE    EE VENUE    OFFICERS    OF    BENGAL. 

§  i.    Introductory. 

THE  system  of  public  administration  by  means  of  District 
Officers  throughout  the  Provinces,  may  be  said  to  have  been 
derived  from  Bengal.  There  the  system  originated ;  there 
it  was  modified  from  time  to  time  by  way  of  experiment, 
and  ultimately  issued  from  the  crucible  of  a  very  severe 
testing,  in  its  modern  form.  It  is  natural  to  expect  that 
the  system,  ultimately  perfected  in  BENGAL,  has,  to  a  large 
extent,  been  the  model  on  which  district  government  has 
been  developed  in  all  the  other  provinces. 

It  will  be  desirable  therefore  to  examine  the  administra- 
tive machinery  of  Bengal  and  to  follow  the  steps  by  which 
it  has  attained  its  present  form,  somewhat  more  in  detail 
than  we  shall  need  to  do  in  the  case  of  other  provinces. 

§  2.    General  Outlines  of  Provincial  Administration. 

I  have  stated  (p.  389),  as  a  general  fact,  that  the  main  out- 
lines of  the  administrative  system  are  everywhere  the  same. 
Immediately  under  the  Local  Government  or  Administra- 
tion, with  its  Revenue  Secretaries,  i.  e.  Secretaries  who  take 
charge  of  the  correspondence  relating  to  revenue  matters, 
we  shall  generally  find,  first,  a  central  controlling  revenue 
authority  over  the  whole  province1,  whether  under  the 
name  of  a  '  Board  of  Revenue '  or  of  one  or  more  '  Financial 
Commissioners.' 

1  Bombay  is  an  exception,  as  presently  noted. 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    REVENUE    OFFICERS    OF    BENGAL.  663 

The  whole  of  the  province  is  divided  out  into  a  number 
of  DISTRICTS,  and  these  are  generally,  but  not  always, 
formed  into  groups  of  three  to  five  as  DIVISIONS  under 
Commissioners,  who  form  a  supervising  and  controUing 
agency,  intermediate  between  the  chief  authority  and  the 
District  Officer1. 

The  DISTRICT  is  presided  over  by  a  COLLECTOR,  who  is 
also  the  District  Magistrate.  His  general  official  title  is 
'  Magistrate  and  Collector,'  while  in  provinces  or  parts  of 
provinces  where  formerly  what  was  called  the  Non-Regu- 
lation system  prevailed,  the  District  head  is  styled  '  Deputy 
Commissioner  V 

The  local  sub-division  of  districts,  though  always  carried 
out,  is  not  so  uniform,  and  will  be  spoken  of  later. 

The  Department  of  '  Land  Records  and  Agriculture '  has 
now  become  an  integral  and  important  factor  in  the  revenue 
administration  (Bk.  I,  Chap.  V,  p.  349) ;  the  '  Director,' 
who  may  or  may  not  have  the  charge  of  Settlements,  as 
'  Commissioner  of  Settlements,'  assists  the  district  officers 
by  systematizing,  directing,  and  constantly  inspecting,  the 
preparation  of  local  maps  and  land  records  and  statistics. 
These  not  only  concern  the  Settlement  work  of  districts 
where  that  is  subject  to  periodical  revision,  but  intimately 
concern  the  revenue  administration,  as  the  means  of 
keeping  the  Collector  informed  of  the  progress  and  state  of 
all  estates,  with  reference  to  their  management,  to  advances 
for  agricultural  improvements,  and  to  the  remission  or 
suspension  of  land-revenue  which  calamities  of  season  may 
call  for. 

Now  we  must  return  to  the  special  system  of  Bengal. 

1  In  Madras  no  '  Division '  inter-  the  reader  may,  if  ho  pleases,  look 

venes  between  the  District  and  the  on  the  Board  as  in  fact  a  body  of 

Board   of  Revenue.     But   the   dis-  Commissioners,  only  aggregated  in 

tricts  are  large  and  are  subdivided.  one  central  office. 

To  some  extent,  therefore,  the  officer  2  The   title   is   still    maintained. 

of  a  sub-division  may  be  regarded  Formeiiy,theDeputy-Commissioner 

as  the  real  district  officer,  and  the  had  Civil  Court  powers :  moreover, 

Collector  rather  as  a  sort  of  Com-  the  latter  was  always  a  covenanted 

missioner  over  him.      Again,    the  civilian   (by   statute^  ;   the  former 

Board  now  consists  of  an  aggregate  might  be,  and  still  often  is,  an  Un- 

of  '  Commissioners,'   in   charge   of  covenanted  or  a  Military  officer. 
different  branches  of  work  ;    and 


664  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  11. 


§  3.    The  Board  of  Revenue. 

it  has  already  been  indicated  more  than  once,  that  on 
first  assuming  the  government  of  '  Bengal,  Bihar  and 
Orissa,'  no  attempt  was  made  to  interfere  with  the  native 
method  of  revenue  management.  In  1769,  as  we  shall  see, 
an  attempt  at  supervision,  excellent  in  theory  but  impossi- 
ble in  practice,  was  made.  In  1 770,  two  '  Revenue  Councils,' 
sitting  at  Patna  and  Murshidabad,  were  established,  and 
soon  after,  '  District  Collectors '  were  tried.  A  Board  of 
Revenue  was  appointed  at  Calcutta,  to  supervise  the  revenue 
generally;  it  consisted  of  the  Governor  and  Members  of 
Council ,  with  an  Accountant-General.  After  the  Regulating 
Act  of  1773,  a  new  experiment  was  made;  the  Collectors 
were  withdrawn  from  districts  and  aggregated  into  six 
'  Provincial  Councils  V 

These  were  supervised  by  the  Calcutta  Board  remodelled 
as  a  '  Committee  of  Revenue.' 

In  1781,  it  was  found,  as  might  be  expected,  that  district 
control  was  indispensable,  so  the  six  Councils  were  dis- 
solved, and  Collectors  remanded  to  the  districts.  The 
Controlling  Committee  at  Calcutta,  up  to  this  time,  con- 
sisted only  of  members  of  the  Government.  But  this  was 
found  inconvenient,  as  the  members,  in  their  other  capa- 
cities, had  more  than  enough  to  occupy  their  time.  The 
Committee  gradually  became  a  separate  body  of  Civil 
Servants,  but  in  1786  the  President  was  still  a  member 
of  the  Government2. 

Reg.  II  of       The  Regulations  of  1793  recognized  this  '  Board  of  Reve- 
nue' and  conferred  powers — 

1  Sitting   at  Calcutta,  Bardwan,  vants  of  the  Company.' 

Murshidabad,  Dacca,  Dinajpur,  and  For  the    information    regarding 

Patna.  the  official  staff,  I  am  indebted  to  a 

a  '  It  is  therefore  full  time,'  wrote  very  good  historical  sketch  prefixed 

the  Court  of  Directors,  '  to  adopt  a  to  the  Report  of  the  Salaries  Commission 

settled  plan,  and  for  that  purpose  (Calcutta,  1886),  to  the  Report  of  the 

we  direct  that  there  be  a  "  Board  of  Salaries      Commission       (Ministerial 

Revenue  "  to  reside  in  Calcutta,  to  Officers),  1868,  and  to  Papers  relating 

consist  of  one  of  the  junior  Members  to  Village  and  Indigenous  Agency  Em- 

of  Council,  and  four  others  of  the  ployed  in  the  Census  of  1872  (Calcutta, 

most  intelligent  of  the  senior  ser-  1873). 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    BE  VENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  665 

(i)  To  summon  any  officer  to  the  Presidency  to  explain 
and  justify  his  conduct,  to  impose  a  fine  not 
exceeding  a  month's  salary,  and  to  suspend  him 
from  office1. 

No  further  alteration  was  made  till  1807,  and  then  on]y 
to  provide  supervision  for  other  acquisitions  of  territory. 
By  Kegulation  X  of  1807  a  '  Board  of  Commissioners '  was 
appointed  for  the  'Upper  Provinces,'  and  in  1817  a  Board 
for  Benares  and  Bihar,  including  two  districts  of  Bengal. 
(This  was  rescinded  by  Regulation  I  of  1819.) 

By  Regulation  III  of  1822  (still  in  force)  provision  was 
made  for  the  better  division  of  labour  ;  three  Boards  of  Reve- 
nue were  constituted — one  for  the  '  Lower  Provinces,'  one  for 
'  Central  Bengal,'  and  one  for  the  '  Western  Provinces.' 

In  1829  a  final  change  was  made.  The  previous  history 
of  the  Boards  marks  the  difficulty  which  was  increasingly 
felt  as  the  revenue  system  developed,  cultivation  extended, 
and  work  increased.  The  Boards  were  directly  responsible 
for  too  much  detail  and  too  much  judicial  work.  The 
idea  therefore  soon  gained  acceptance,  that  it  would  be 
better  to  arrange  for  the  direct  supervision  of  manageable 
groups  of  districts  by  Revenue  Commissioners,  and  restrict 
the  scope  of  the  Board's  duties  to  a  general  and  ultimate 
control  at  head-quarters. 

The  Board  of  Revenue  at  Calcutta  (at  first  called  the 
Sudder  (Sadr)  Revenue  Board)  remained  for  Bengal,  and 
the  Board  for  the  Upper  Provinces  became  the  Board  which 
now  sits  under  the  Lieutenant-Go vernor  of  the  North -West 
Provinces ;  the  third  Board  (Central  Bengal)  was  abolished. 
Bengal  was  then  apportioned  into  eleven  Divisions 2. 

The  functions  of  the  Central  Board  at  Calcutta  being  thus 
restricted  to  the  superior  control,  it  was  possible  to  unite 
with  it  what  had  been,  since  1819,  a  separate  Board  for 
Trade,  Customs,  Opium,  &c.  This  was  effected  by  Act 
XLIV  of  1850,  and  the  title  'Sudder  Board'  was  dropped. 

1  These  provisions  were  never  re-  2  And    the   North- Western    Pro- 

scinded  till  Act  XII  of  1873  declared      vinces  into  nine, 
them  repealed  as  obsolete. 


666  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

The  '  Board  of  Revenue  for  the  Lower  Provinces '  is  hence- 
forth the  official  designation.  Regulation  III  of  1822  (still 
in  force)  enables  the  Government  to  empower  any  Member 
of  the  Board  to  exercise  all  or  any  of  the  powers  of  the 
whole  Board l ;  this  Regulation  also  states  the  general 
powers  of  control  possessed  by  the  Board,  though,  of  course, 
other  Regulations  and  Acts  have  to  be  referred  to  in  order 
to  trace  the  entire  scope  of  legal  provisions  giving  powers. 
The  Board  of  Revenue  now  consists  of  two  members  with 
two  Secretaries2.  It  exercises  general  powers  of  control 
and  sanction,  and  regulates,  by  the  issue  of  Standing  Orders 
and  Circulars,  the  procedure  and  conduct  of  official  busi- 
ness in  all  revenue  departments  whenever  these  matters 
are  not  directly  provided  for  by  Acts  of  the  Legislature,  or 
rules  having  the  force  of  law  made  pursuant  to  such  Acts. 
Some  idea  of  the  extent  and  variety  of  the  duties  and  powers 
of  the  Board  of  Revenue,  in  supervising  officials,  reviewing 
decisions  and  orders,  sanctioning  Settlements,  controlling 
sales  for  arrears  of  revenue,  controlling  the  Land  Registers, 
Irrigation,  Embankments,  Customs,  Salt,  Opium,  Excise,  the 
Court  of  Wards,  Stamps,  and  many  other  matters,  may  be 
gained  by  a  glance  at  the  columns  under  the  head  of  the 
'  Board  of  Revenue,  Bengal,'  in  the  '  General  Index  to 
Enactments  relating  to  India,'  or  to  the  volumes  of  Standing 
Orders. 

§  4.    Commissioners. 

As  already  indicated,  the  appointment  of  Commissioners 
of  Divisions,  with  general  powers  of  supervision  and  con- 
trol, but  subject  to  the  Board  of  Revenue,  dates  from  1829 
(Regulation  I  of  that  year).  The  territorial  extent  of  the 
Commissioner's  charge  was  then  wisely  determined  to  be 
such,  that  the  presiding  officer  might  '  be  easy  of  access  to 
the  people'  and  be  able  'frequently  to  visit  the  different 

1  An  order  has  recently  beei\  is-  Opium,  Stamps,  Excise,  &c. 

sued  (1889)  empowering  each  Mem-  2  By  the  24  &  25  Viet.,  cap.  54,  the 

ber  to  exercise  the  whole  power  of  members  and  Secretaries  are  to  be 

the  Board,  one  in  mattersof  Revenue,  Civil  Servants, 
the  other  for  Miscellaneous  Revenue, 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    REVENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  667 

parts  of  their  respective  jurisdictions.'  At  first  the  Com- 
missioners had  Civil  Court  powers  and  were  Criminal 
Judges  of  Circuit.  They  were,  however,  relieved  of  Civil 
Court  duties  by  Act  III  of  I8351;  and  afterwards  were 
relieved  of  criminal  duties  by  the  appointment  of  separate 
Sessions  Judges  under  the  Code  of  Criminal  Procedure. 

In  other  provinces,  it  may  be  mentioned,  the  union  of 
civil  and  criminal  powers  in  the  Commissioner's  office 
lasted  much  longer,  and  has  not  yet  altogether  ceased  in 
some  provinces.  In  the  Panjab  it  lasted  till  the  Courts 
Act  of  ist  November,  1884.  In  the  Central  Provinces  it 
still  exists,  and  so  in  some  other  places. 

Even  in  provinces  where  the  ordinary  civil  and  criminal 
(appellate  and  original)  jurisdiction  of  Commissioners  has 
ceased,  the  Commissioners  have  some  judicial  or  quasi- 
judicial  duties,  inasmuch  as  under  the  Tenancy  and  Revenue 
Laws,  a  number  of  matters  are  excluded  from  the  cognizance 
of  Civil  Courts,  and  are  disposed  of  by  Revenue  Officers,  and 
by  such  officers  sitting  as  Revenue  Courts,  and  the  appeal 
lies  to  the  Commissioners. 

In  Bengal,  rent  cases  and  appeals  are  heard  by  the  Civil 
Courts2,  but  there  are  still  important  revenue  matters  in 
which  an  appeal  of  a  ^turn-judicial  nature  lies  from  the 
Collector's  order  to  the  Commissioner. 

Commissioners  also  retain  a  general  control  in  police 
matters.  The  minor  changes  in  the  law  between  1837  and 
1861,  which  have  occurred,  do  not  directly  concern  us  here. 

The  wide  scope  of  the  duty  of  a  Commissioner  of  Division 
in  Bengal  is  well  summed  up  in  the  Salaries  Commission 
Report  (1885-86),  and  as  this  gives  an  excellent  general 
idea  of  what  the  Commissioner's  duty  is  everywhere,  it 
may  be  quoted  in  extenso : — 

3  i  Nearly  every  one  of  the  numerous  duties  of  the  District 
Officer  is  exercised  by  him  subject  to  the  supervision  of  the 
Commissioner  of  Revenue  and  Circuit,  and  even  in  those 

1  Salary  Commission  Report,  chapter  II.  §  9. 

2  Except  in  Orissa,  Chutiya  Nagpiir,  and  the  Santal  Parganas. 

3  §  18  of  the  Repoi-t,  1886. 


668  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

branches  of  public  business  which  do  not,  ordinarily,  come 
under  his  immediate  observation,  he  is  at  any  time  liable  to  be 
called  on  by  Government  to  interfere  or  to  give  an  opinion. 
His  work,  like  that  of  the  Magistrate- Collector,  may  be  divided 
into  administrative  and  judicial — the  former  is  far  more  onerous 
than  the  latter.  A  Commissioner's  administrative  work  is  very 
difficult  to  define,  and  there  is  hardly  anything,  except  perhaps 
taking  command  of  a  fleet,  or  performing  a  surgical  operation, 
that  he  may  not  be  called  upon,  at  one  time  or  another,  to 
undertake.  He  has  to  inspect  the  offices  of  all  the  Collectors 
under  him  once  a  year,  and  the  Sub-divisional  Officers,  as  far  as 
he  can,  and  to  see  not  only  that  work  is  properly  performed, 
but  that  the  people  in  all  parts  of  the  division  are  treated  with 
due  consideration,  and  all  that  affects  their  interest  is  carefully 
watched  and  reported  by  District  and  Sub-divisional  Officers  as 
well  as  by  the  Police.  He  has  to  collect  information  from  his 
District  Officers  concerning  a  vast  variety  of  matters,  and  pre- 
sent it  in  a  suitable  shape  to  Government.  He  receives  constant 
applications  from  the  Collectors  for  sanction  to  the  disburse- 
ment of  money,  and  the  performance  of  official  acts,  and  to 
these  he  replies  in  some  cases  by  giving  sanction  himself ;  in 
others  by  referring  the  question  to  higher  authority.  He  is 
also  referred  to  for  instructions  on  all  sorts  of  questions  by  his 
subordinates,  and  these  references,  if  he  is  an  active  man,  not 
afraid  of  responsibility,  he  answers  himself ;  if  he  is  not  such 
a  man,  he  merely  sends  them  on  to  Government,  or  to  the 
Board  for  orders.  He  has  to  write  carefully  considered  opinions 
on  legislative  measures  while  passing  through  the  Council,  and 
a  large  number  of  annual  reports  and  occasional  reports  on  a 
number  of  subjects.  .  .  .  His  judicial  work  consists  in  hearing 
appeals  in  Settlement,  partition,  certificate  sale,  wards'  and 
Government  estates,  and  under  several  other  revenue  laws  :  as 
well  as  appeals  from  ministerial  and  police  officers  regarding 
dismissal  or  other  punishment.  Lately,  also,  the  Local  Self- 
Government  Act  has  added  considerably  to  his  work ;  and 
some  Commissioners  have  also  a  large  amount  of  political  and 
civil  work.  Thus,  the  Commissioner  of  Orissa  is  also  Superin- 
tendent of  the  Tributary  .States,  a  duty  which  entails  on  him 
a  large  amount  of  civil  and  criminal  work,  besides  that  of 
supervision,  advice,  and  guidance  to  the  Kajas  of  the  several 
estates. 

'  The  Commissioner  of  Chutiya  Nagpur  has  similar  work,  but 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    KEVENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  669 

on  a  smaller  scale.  The  Commissioner  of  Bhagalpur  has  civil 
and  criminal  jurisdiction  in  the  Santal  Parganas,  and  the  Com- 
missioner of  Chittagong  in  the  Hill  Tracts  of  his  Division.' 

There  are  now  in  Bengal  nine  Divisions  over  groups  of 
districts : — 


i.  Bardwan,             over  6  districts. 

2.  Presidency,            ,, 

6        „ 

3.  Rajshahi,                „ 

7 

4.  Dacca  (  Dhaka  \      ,, 

4 

5.  Chittagong,            „ 

4 

6.  Patna,                     ,, 

5         » 

7.  Bhagalpur,             „ 

3         „ 

8.  Orissa,                     ,, 

3  districts  (besides  political  charge 

of  the  Tributary  States). 

9.  Chutiya  Nagpur,  ,, 

4  districts. 

§  5-    Collectors. 

In  speaking  of  the  Board  of  Revenue,  mention  was  made 
that,  as  early  as  1769,  'supervisors'  were  appointed,  with 
a  view  to  collecting  information  of  all  kinds,  and  to  keep- 
ing a  check  on  the  work  of  the  Muhammadan  district 
officers  *. 

They  did  not  continue  long:  in  May,  1772,  they  were 
styled  Collectors;  and  in  1773  ^ne7  were  withdrawn,  as 
already  stated,  and  the  districts  left  to  native  officers — 
'  Diwan '  and  '  'Amil.' 

After  the  various  attempts  at  revenue  administration  by 
means  of  local  and  central  committees,  District  Collectors 
were  again  appointed  in  1786.  The  main  changes  in  the 
office  since  that  time  have  been  with  reference  to  the  union 
of  Magisterial  and  Civil  Court  powers  with  Revenue  duties. 
At  first  (in  1787)  it  was  considered  desirable  that  the 
'  people  accustomed  to  despotic  authority  should  look  to 
one  master.'  But  in  the  course  of  time,  and  after  several 
changes  enacted  by  law,  the  Civil  Court  powers  were 

1  See  p.  392.  The  letter  describing      have  seen  is  in  Hunter's  Annals  of 
their  duties  is  given  in  Field,  p.  463.       Rural  Bengal,  pp.  262  65. 
The  best  account  of  Supervisors  I 


670  LAND    SYSTEMS   OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

withdrawn  and  Criminal  powers  alone  remained  in  union 
with  the  Revenue  powers.  It  was  in  1831  that  the  Regu- 
lations gave  rise  to  the  modern  office  of  '  Magistrate  ant 
Collector.'  But  in  1837  the  double  function  was  for  a  time 
divided,  owing  to  the  pressure  of  Revenue  work.  The 
separation  was  gradually  carried  out,  and  up  to  1845, 
Collector  after  Collector  was  relieved  of  Magisterial  duty. 
It  was  only  in  1 859  *  that  the  Magisterial  and  Revenue 
functions  were  again,  finally,  united. 

Though  the  possession  of  Magisterial  authority  in  the 
district  is  deemed  essential  for  the  Collector's  position,  it  is 
not  to  be  supposed  that  time  would  suffice  for  the  chief 
officers  to  take  a  large  share  in  the  disposal  of  the  daily 
work  of  the  Criminal  Courts.  Various  expedients  were 
resorted  to,  such  as  the  creation  of  '  Joint-Magistrates ' 
(Act  XV  of  1843),  with  which  a  Revenue  Manual  is  not 
concerned. 

The  division  of  Criminal  and  Revenue  labour  has  been 
much  facilitated  by  the  modern  system  of  sub-dividing 
districts  and  giving  local  officers  charge. 

At  the  present  time  all  grades  of  Magistrates,  whether 
District  Magistrates,  or  Assistants,  or  Joint-Magistrates,  or 
Uncovenanted  Deputy  Magistrates,  derive  their  Magisterial 
powers  from  the  Code  of  Criminal  Procedure.  And  under 
that  Code  there  may  be  Honorary  and  other  Magistrates 
who  have  no  official  position  as  Revenue  Officers. 

The  Revenue  duties  of  the  Collector,  with  which  alone 
we  are  here  concerned,  were  originally  enumerated  in  Regu- 
lation II  of  1793.  His  duties  have  increased  in  many 
directions.  The  land-revenue,  which  in  the  days  of  the 
decennial  Settlement  is  quoted  as  385  lakhs,  had  risen  in 
1888-89  to  over  380  lakhs2.  The  Collector  has  to  look 
after  the  collection  of  this  LAND-REVENUE,  involving  the 
sale  for  arrears  in  ths  case  of  the  '  Zamindari '  estates,  and 
the  certificate  procedure,  as  it  is  called,  under  the  '  Public 

1  Despatch  of  Secretaiy  of  State,       number  of  permanently-settled  ami 
No.  15,  dated  i4th  April,  1859.  other   estates  can  be   seen   in  the 

2  The   list  of  districts  and   the      table  at  pp.  470-1.     See  also  p.  442. 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    REVENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  67 1 

Demands  Eecovery  Act'  (B.  Act  VII  of  1880)  in  others. 
He  has  also  the  collection  of  the  local  or  provincial  rates, 
which  consist  of  the  Public  Works  cess  (B.  Act  IX  of  1 880 1), 
a  cess  levied  for  roads  and  provincial  public  works ;  and  the 
Postal  cess  (B.  Act  VIII  of  1862)  which  provides  for  local 
official  postage.  Besides  this,  there  is  the  whole  subject  of 
the  EXCISE  revenue  under  his  care  (this  revenue  in  1884-85 
exceeded  10  lakhs).  To  this  must  be  added  the  super- 
vision of  the  LiCENSE-Tax  and  IxcoME-Tax,  and  the  STAMP 
Revenue.  Besides  the  collection  of  these  revenues,  there 
are  all  the  connected  duties  which  the  land-revenue  system 
entails,  viz.  the  registration  of  titles  to  land;  issue  and 
recovery  of  loans  for  agricultural  improvements  ;  embank- 
ments (on  the  maintenance  of  which  agriculture  in  many 
parts  depends) ;  irrigation  (in  some  districts) ;  the  open- 
ing of  separate  accounts,  for  sharers  and  others  in  estates 
paying  one  sum  of  revenue ;  management  of  patwaris  in 
Bihar;  various  applications  under  the  Tenancy  Law  (Act 
VIII  of  1885) ;  the  management  of  estates  of  minors  under 
the  Court  of  Wards,  and  of  attached  estates  (for  recovery 
of  debts  due  by  the  owners). 

Besides  all  these  matters,  there  are  various  miscellaneous 
duties  connected  with  supply  of  provisions  for  troops  on  the 
march ;  the  occasional  acquisition  of  land  for  public  pur- 
poses ;  Municipalities  and  Local  Boards  ;  Ferries  ;  Pounds  ; 
Emigration ;  Primary  Education,  and  others ;  to  say  no- 
thing of  his  responsibility  as  Magistrate  for  the  Police  and 
Criminal  administration  of  the  district.  The  District  Officer 
is  designed  to  be  the  central  authority,  the  '  Hakim,'  par 
excellence,  of  his  district.  Sir  George  Campbell  wrote  in 
1871-72  (Administration  Report,  Part  I,  p.  66) : — 

'  It  is  the  Lieutenant-Governor's  wish  to  render  the  heads  of 
districts  (the  Magistrate-Collectors)  no  longer  the  drudges  of 
many  departments  and  masters  of  none,  but  in  fact  the  general 
controlling  authority  over  all  departments  in  each  district.  .  .  . 
Departments  are  excellent  servants,  but,  as  he  considers,  very 

1  With  amending  Acts,  e.  g.  II  of  1881,  and  VII  of  1881. 


672  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  u. 

bad  masters.  He  has,  therefore,  striven  to  make  the  Magistrate- 
Collector  of  a  great  Bengal  district,  generally  comprising  one- 
and-a-half  to  two-and-a-half  millions  of  inhabitants,  the  real 
executive  chief  and  Administrator  of  the  tract  of  country  com- 
mitted to  him,  and  supreme  over  everyone  and  everything, 
except  the  proceedings  of  the  Courts  of  Justice.' 


§  6.   Collectors  Office. 

The  Collector  has  under  him  both  an  '  English  Office,' 
i.  e.  clerks  and  accountants  for  the  correspondence  and 
accounts  kept  up  in  English  for  communication  with  other 
offices  and  departments,  and  a  '  Vernacular  Office,'  of 
which,  however,  the  members  mostly  know  English,  and 
make  use  of  it  to  some  extent. 

In  Bengal,  the  Vernacular  Office  has  long  been  divided 
into  departments,  the  sarishtadar,  the  treasurer  (khazanchi), 
the  record-keeper,  and  the  '  taujih-navis ' ;  these  are  all 
assisted  by  native  readers  and  clerks  (Munshi  and  Mu- 
harir). 

The  '  Sarishtadar '  (as  his  name  imports)  keeps  the  '  files ' 
that  are  pending,  and  is,  in  fact,  responsible  for  the  super- 
vision of  the  whole  vernacular  office  and  for  the  care  of 
different  records,  petitions,  and  papers,  that  are  undergoing 
inquiry  and  are  awaiting  orders. 

The  Native  treasurer  is  under  the  Deputy  or  Assistant 
Collector  who  is  in  charge  of  the  district  treasury,  and  his 
duties  require  no  notice  here. 

The  Record-keeper  takes  care  of  the  records.  There  is, 
always,  one  department  for  English  correspondence,  and 
another  for  files  of  vernacular  '  cases.'  He  arranges  and 
classifies  the  records,  keeps  the  general  registers  prescribed 
by  the  Land  Registration  Act  in  Bengal,  and  makes  reports 
regarding  mutations  of  proprietors,  and  other  matters  which 
the  registers  show,  and  he  supervises  the  issue  of  authenti- 
cated copies  of  papers. 

The  taujih-navis  maintains  the  revenue-roll  and  prepares 
the  returns  showing  the  state  of  the  collections,  what  pay- 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    EEVENTJE    OFFICEBS    OP   BENGAL.  673 

ments  of  land-revenue  fall  due,  what  are  in  arrears,  and  so 
forth. 

There  is  also  the  district  Nazir  or  '  Sheriff'  and  his  Naib 
or  Deputy.  This  person  acts  as  the  guardian  of  property 
attached,  and  sees  to  the  issue  of  processes  and  notices. 
Besides  which  he  is  the  general  sort  of  '  housekeeper '  to  the 
District  Officer,  looking  after  the  furniture,  '  pankhas,'  the 
district  tents,  and  so  forth. 

Some  such  distribution  of  business  as  this — varying  of 
course  in  details,  and  in  the  local  titles  of  the  officials — will 
be  found  in  every  Collector's  head-quarters  office  in  India. 

§  7.    The  Collector  s  Assistants. 

From  an  early  date  there  were,  besides  the  Collectors,  offi- 
cers called  Assistant- Collectors,  but  they  had  no  legal  powers. 
By  Regulation  IV  of  1821,  the  Collectors  were  first  formally 
empowered  to  delegate  to  their  (Covenanted)  Assistants  any 
part  of  their  duties  to  which  they  could  not  themselves 
give  due  attention.  By  Regulation  IX  of  1833  the  appoint- 
ment of  Uncovenanted  Officers  with  the  title  of  '  Deputy 
Collectors '  was  legalized. 

These  provisions  resulted  (in  connection  with  different 
laws  giving  magisterial  powers)  in  the  official  titles  of 
'  the  Magistrate  and  Collector,'  '  Joint  Magistrate  and  De- 
puty Collector,'  'Assistant  Magistrate  and  Collector,' 
'  Deputy  Collector  and  Deputy  Magistrate  (Uncovenanted).' 

In  1872,  Executive  Revenue  Officers  called  '  Sub-Deputy 
Collectors '  were  appointed  for  the  purpose  of  giving  local 
or  special  aid  for  particular  places  or  departments  of  duty. 
The  Sub-Deputy  Collector  is  appointed  by  executive  au- 
thority, and  can  be  invested  with  such  powers  of  a  Deputy 
Collector  under  various  Acts  and  Regulations  as  may  be 
necessary.  Even  Kamingos  (of  whom  hereafter)  are  now 
reckoned  on  the  staff  of  the  revenue-agency,  as,  where  they 
are  employed,  they  can  be  utilized  in  various  ways,  super- 
vising partitions  of  estates,  making  assessments  in  connec- 
tion with  the  levy  of  cesses  or  rates,  and  so  forth. 

VOL.  I.  XX 


674  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

In  order  to  facilitate  the  district  management  and  turn  to 
best  account  the  powers  of  the  various  grades  of  officers,  the 
plan  of  sub-dividing  the  district  and  giving  the  charge  of 
the  sub-division  to  one  of  the  district  officers  in  subordina- 
tion to  the  District  Officer,  was  long  ago  thought  of.  In 
1845  thirty-four  sub-divisions  were  made,  but  as  the 
system  developed,  the  number  rose  to  its  present  figure  of 
ninety. 

Attention  should  be  directed  to  this  feature  of  the  Bengal 
district,  because  it  marks  an  important  difference  between 
that  province  and  the  other  provinces,  where  the  Native 
Government  had  not  introduced  the  system  of  revenue 
collection  by  Zamindars.  In  all  other  provinces,  speaking 
generally,  the  districts  are  divided  up  into  small  local 
revenue  divisions,  known  variously  as  the  '  tahsil,'  the 
pargana,  or  the  taluka ;  and  when  this  is  the  case,  there  is 
a  native  or  other  officer  in  charge  (called  by  various  titles — 
tahsildar,  mamlatdar,  &c.),  with  his  writers  and  revenue- 
accountants  and  treasurers.  There  are  often,  under  this 
officer,  other  subordinates,  to  aid  in  the  general  work  of  the 
tahsil,  or  taluka,  and  help  in  the  supervision  of  the  village 
officials;  and  finally  for  each  village  or  group  of  villages1, 
a  system  of  headmen  and  village-accountants.  Thus  there 
is  a  complete  revenue  hierarchy,  from  the  District  Collector 
at  the  top  to  the  village  officer  at  the  bottom.  In 
provinces  where  this  system  exists,  in  more  or  less  com- 
pleteness, there  may  be  primary  sub-divisions  of  districts 
in  case  the  district  is  large,  and  there  is  some  important 
town  with  its  connected  territory,  at  which  it  is  desirable 
to  relieve  the  Collector  by  posting  an  Assistant  or  Deputy. 
In  Bengal,  the  revenue  history  has  already  shown  us 
how  the  Zamindari  system  gradually  swept  away  2  all  but 
the  memory  of  loCal  limits  of  parganas,  destroying  the 
agency  of  'Amils  or  Tahsildars,  with  their  Kanungos  and 
the  village  Patwaris  or  accountants.  Deprived  then,  of 

1  Village  pahcdris  generally  look  stance)  survived  in  the  Bihar  dis- 

after  groups  of  villages  or  '  circles.'  tricts,    and   other   features   of  old 

'J  I  am,  of  course,  speaking  gene-  revenue  days  in  other  places, 
rally.     Patwaris  in  villages  (for  in- 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    KEVENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  675 

what  I  may  call  the  natural  sub-division  of  revenue-work 
which  facilitates  administration  in  other  parts,  and  there 
being  no  field-registers  and  maps  of  each  village,  revenue- 
management  would  be  now  impossible,  were  it  not  for  the 
Sub-divisions  in  charge  of  Sub-Deputy  Collectors  subordi- 
nate to  the  Collectors.  It  may  be  asked  why  the  need  of 
sub-division  of  labour  has  arisen  and  why  such  an  increase 
of  official  work  has  taken  place  ?  The  Salaries  Commission 
remarks  in  answer  : — 

'  This  increase  in  the  superior  executive  staff,  is  accounted 
for  by  the  gradual  development  and  perfecting  of  our  Adminis- 
trative system,  the  chief  feature  of  which  has  been  a  cautious 
and  gradual  advance.  New  laws  have  been  and  are  being  con- 
stantly enacted  to  provide  for  the  growing  requirements  of  the 
people,  to  remedy  abuses,  and  to  regulate  procedure.  New 
measures,  undreamt  of  a  hundred  years  ago,  have  been  intro- 
duced as  experience  showed  the  necessity  for  them,  and  matters 
once  considered  of  so  little  importance  as  to  be  left  to  be  dis- 
posed of  by  Collectors  according  to  their  own  ideas,  have  been 
made  the  subject  of  intricate  legal  provisions  and  fenced  about 
with  safeguards  and  restrictions  of  all  kinds.  Large  as  the 
present  executive  body  may  seem  when  contrasted  with  that  of 
the  early  years  of  the  present  century,  there  is  little  doubt  that 
it  is  even  now  barely  strong  enough  for  all  the  work  it  has 
to  do.' 

At  this  point,  then,  our  account  of  the  Revenue  Officers 
of  Bengal  ceases  to  be  a  guide  to  what  exists  in  other 
provinces,  and  we  must  therefore  devote  a  brief  special 
study  to  the  local  pargana  and  village  agency  as  it  exists  in 
Bengal. 

§  8.    Village  Officers  in  Bengal. 

After  looking  through  all  the  evidence  collected  in  1872, 
I  see  no  reason  to  think  that  the  villages  of  Bengal  were 
different  from  those  which  were  found  wherever  the  Aryan 
conquests  extended,  or  where  kingdoms,  which,  if  not  Hindu 
had  adopted  the  Hindu  constitution,  existed.  I  do  not 
include  in  this  remark  the  districts  of  Chutiya  Nagpur 

X  X  2 


676  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

or  the  Santdl  Pergunnahs,  the  villages  of  which  I  have 
elsewhere  described. 

In  Chittagong  and  other  places,  where  the  colonization  of 
the  waste  has  been  of  comparatively  recent  or  modern  origin, 
there  are  also  special  features.  It  is  impossible  to  carry 
on  cultivation  in  jungle  country  in  India  without  co- 
operation ;  and  that  implies  a  grouping  of  cultivators,  a 
headman — or  headmen  of  the  different  castes  or  sections 
associated,  and  some  artisans  and  helpers.  I  am  aware 
of  no  form  of  Indian  cultivating  settlement  of  which  this 
is  not  true. 

In  Chittagong,  for  instance,  with  its  local  institutions— 
the  '  tarf '  and  the  associated  '  taluqdars,'  we  find  that  there 
are  headmen  of  local  groups  known  as  '  Matabar '  (corrup- 
tion of  the  Arabic  mu'tabir  =  respectable  or  trusted  man), 
though  they  are  not  officially  recognized. 

In  the  ordinary  districts  in  Bihar  as  well  as  Bengal, 
the  old  constitution  is  so  far  traceable,  that  the  '  headman ' 
survives  with  the  almost  universal  name  of  '  Mandal.'  He 
is  still  hereditary  as  a  rule  ;  but  the  elective  element  is  not 
wanting ;  and  the  villages  would  reject  an  incompetent 
heir,  and  elect  a  more  promising  one.  In  some  cases  the 
term  '  pradhdn '  is  used,  but  in  more  than  one  district  I 
h'nd  it  doubted  whether  this  does  not  really  indicate 
a  parvenu  headman,  not  of  the  old  organization,  but  one 
who  has  gained  the  position  by  official  interference,  and 
by  his  own  wealth  and  influence.  In  villages  where,  from 
the  earliest  days,  we  can  find  no  trace  of  any  idea  of 
proprietorship  except  in  the  lot  occupied  by  the  family  for 
clearing  and  cultivation,  we  are  probably  in  presence  of 
the  '  raiyatwari  type '  of  village,  which  was  discussed  in 
Book  I,  Chap.  IV.  And  this  is  a  form  of  land-holding 
which  lends  itself  to  change;  for  there  is  a  tendency  for 
persons  of  various  kinds  to  assume  the  landlord  position, 
the  old  holders  of  land  becoming  his  '  raiyats,'  or  under- 
proprietors,  or  something  analogous.  And  thus  it  is  we 
so  often  have  traces  of  the  effects  of  a  Raja's  grant, 
and  other  forms  of  over-lordship,  which,  at  a  remote  date, 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    REVENUE    OFFICEES    OF   BENGAL.  677 

or  perhaps  at  a  comparatively  modern  one,  introduced 
a  change.  A  proprietary  body,  being  the  multiplication  of 
a  grantee's  or  of  a  chief's  family,  claims  the  village  and 
divides  it  into  sections,  called  '  patti,'  or  '  muhalla,'  and 
when  we  find  that  there  are  several  'mandals,'  one  at 
the  head  of  each  section,  we  may  reasonably  conclude  that 
something  of  the  kind  has  occurred.  In  fact,  every  member 
of  the  proprietary  families  calls  himself,  and  is  called. 
'  mandal '  in  Bengal,  '  patel '  in  Central  India ;  though 
only  one  man  is  the  official  head,  or  two  or  more  if  there 
are  sub-divisions  of  the  village.  These  have  a  certain  pre- 
cedence on  occasions — appear  first  on  the  puny  a  or  first 
day  of  rent  payment,  and  receive  small  offerings,  and  such 
like  marks  of  superiority. 

Directly  the  milage  system  falls  into  abeyance,  and  the 
State  officers  no  longer  deal  with  the  village-heads,  for  rent 
collection,  but  look  to  larger  estate-holders  as  Zamindars, 
taluqdars,  and  the  like,  the  headman  drops  out  of  con- 
sideration ; — but  not  altogether,  for  he  is  still  useful,  and 
in  some  places  the  estate-holder  will  assume  to  appoint 
him,  or  rather  confirm  or  recognize  his  appointment. 
But  the  milage  accountant  either  disappears  or  becomes 
the  mere  servant  of  the  landlord,  keeping  his  accounts 
with  his  tenants,  without  any  sense  of  public  duty  or 
responsibility,  or  dignity.  The  village  watchman  (gorait. 
budhwar,  &c.)  remains,  and  so  the  '  chaukidar  '  or  guardian 
of  roads,  and  other  similar  functionaries :  and  the  artisans 
remain  of  course,  still  receiving  certain  grain-dues,  or 
perhaps  rewarded  by  a  bit  of  '  chakaran '  or  rent-free 
service  land,  which  the  landlord  does  not,  out  of  policy, 
resume. 

That  is,  I  believe,  in  brief,  the  true  state  of  the  case  as 
regards  the  village  headmen,  and  the  village  accountants  in 
Bengal.  In  Bihar,  the  old  institutions  survived  more  per- 
fectly, because  there  the  villages  seem  to  have  been  held 
by  minor  chiefs  or  even  petty  officers  of  the  Raja's  army; — 
at  any  rate,  the  circumstances  were  such,  that  the  land- 
lords were  small  holders  :  the  greater  chiefs  did  not  often 


678  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

develop  into  Zamindars ;  and  therefore,  even  though  the 
village  gained  a  'proprietor,'  or  several  joint  proprietors, 
the  form  of  its  constitution  survived :  moreover  as  villages 
paying  grain-rents  require  the  services  of  village  officers 
more  than  those  paying  cash  rents,  the  patwaris  more 
generally  remained. 

§  9.    The  Kdntingo  and  the  Patwdri. 

As  ike  village  system  disappeared  under  the  later  plan  of 
farming  or  contracting  for  the  revenues,  so  the  parganci 
system,  of  which  the  kdnungo  was  the  representative, 
disappeared  also.  '  Qanun-go '  means x,  the  '  teller,'  of 
the  'rule,'  but  it  rather  refers  to  the  rule  or  standard  of 
what  was  proper  in  assessment,  and  measurement,  than  to 
any  general  legal  knowledge  possessed  by  the  pargana 
officer.  In  1793  ^  was  thought  that  the  retention  of  the 
kanungo  would  be  a  good  check  on  the  Zamindar ;  and  the 
latter  was  required  to  maintain  patwdris  in  the  villages, 
and  they  were,  in  turn,  to  render  accounts  to  the  kanungo. 
But  they  did  no  such  thing ;  the  one  idea  of  the  Zamindar 
had  originally  been — in  the  days  of  Mughal  decline — to 
pay  as  little  to  the  treasury  as  possible,  and  therefore  to 
conceal  what  he  really  got  out  of  the  villages.  Under 
British  law,  it  is  true,  his  payment  was  positively  fixed, 
but  still  he  felt  that,  perhaps,  something  would  happen  if 
it  was  known  accidentally  what  was  the  real  rent-total  he 
got ;  hence  he  took  care  that  any  accounts  he  sent  in  were 
framed  so  as  to  suit  his  interests.  Naturally  enough,  both 
kanungos  and  patwaris  were  soon  abolished,  the  latter 
being  employed  by  Zamindars  as  their  clerks. 

But  the  growing  evils  which  I  have  described  in  the  last 
chapter  gradually  attracted  attention;  and  in  1815  the 
Court  of  Directors  conceived  that  the  patwaris  might  be 
made  Government  servants  ;  the  scheme  fell  through,  and 

1  The  word  ought  always  to  be  mon    revenue    term,   that   I   have 
written  with  '  q '  to   represent  the  generally  retained  the  usual  but  in- 
true  vernacular  word,  but  Kanungo  correct  spelling. 
with  a  '  A; '  has  become  such  a  com- 


CHAP,  v.]      THE    REVENUE    OFFICERS    OF   BENGAL.  679 

the  patwaris,  where  they  existed,  remained  as  servants  of 
the  landlords.  Then  it  was  thought  the  kdntingos  might 
be  revived,  so  as  to  supervise  the  patwaris.  Regulations 
were  accordingly  passed  in  1817,  1818,  and  1819.  Regu- 
lation I  of  1819  directed  the  re- establishment  of  kanungos 
and  defined  the  duties  of  patwaris.  But  these  offices  are 
part  of  certain  machinery  ;  they  are  calculated  to  work 
with  the  machinery  as  a  whole  ;  they  cannot  be  detached 
and  introduced  into  a  totally  different  system.  In  1827  ^ 
was  found  that  the  kanungos  had  done  nothing,  and  that 
the  land-owners  had  been  determined  in  their  opposition. 
In  Orissa  alone  (where  the  Settlements  are  temporary 
village  Settlements)  kanungos  and  patwaris  have  sur- 
vived. 

'  Efforts  have,  of  late,  been  made,'  says  the  author  of  the 
Report  of  1883  on  the  Land-Revenue  system, — 

'  to  revivify  patwaris.  Throughout  the  province  provision 
was  made  for  their  appointment,  or  for  the  performance  of 
their  duties  in  all  Settlements,  under  instructions  issued  in 
1872  l.  As  a  rule,  in  every  estate  of  which  the  revenue  was 
above  R.  300,  remuneration  for  a  patwdri  formed  a  set-off  against 
the  assessment:  and  in  a  smaller  estate,  the  Settlement-holder 
engaged  himself  to  perform  the  duties  required  of  a  pattvdri. 
Except  in  Orissa  and  Bihar,  however,  no  successful  results 
sprang  from  the  attempt.  .  .  .  The  system  was  generally  con- 
demned by  officers  in  Bengal  proper  as  being  vexatious  and 
irritating  to  the  landlords,  useless  for  all  practical  purposes, 
wasteful  of  Government  money,  and  opposed  to  the  present 
customs  and  traditions  of  the  land-owning  classes.  The  Govern- 
ment, therefore,  at  the  suggestion  of  the  Board,  directed  that 
no  further  attempts  should  be  made  to  revive  the  institu- 
tion, and  that  allowances  granted  in  the  estates  should  be 
resumed. 

1  By    Sir    G.    Campbell,    whose  more  of  '  village '  management  in 

official  life  had  mostly  been  passed  the  system  ;  and  just  in  proportion 

where  village  Settlements  were  in  as  that  is  the  case,  the  utility  of 

force,  and  where  the  patwari,  being  the  village  accountant  becomes  more 

a  natural  feature  of  the  system,  was  manifest : — it  may  be  but  little,  for 

indispensable.    The  use  of  patwaris  even  the  Orissa  patwaris'  accounts 

in  Orissa  and  in  Bihar  illustrates  are  said  to  be  quite  untrustworthy, 
this :  in  these  districts  there  is 


63o 


LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 


'  In  Bihar  (and  in  the  Munger  district)  steps  were  taken  to 
give  the  system  a  more  effective  existence.  The  re-organiza- 
tion has  been  completed  in  Munger,  and  has  reached  an 
advanced  state  in  the  Bihar  Districts.' 

The  report  from  which  this  is  quoted  is  dated  1883.  and 
it  is  there  stated  that  fresh  legislation  would  be  required  : 
but  I  have  not  seen  any  proposal  on  the  subject  during  the 
six  years  that  have  since  elapsed *. 

The  Settlement  Manual,  1888,  at  p.  18,  gives  the  rules 
for  entertaining  patwaris  in  Government  estates,  or  estates 
held  direct,  or  under  farm.  In  temporarily-settled  estates 
where  Government  is  not  proprietor,  the  Settlement  natu- 
rally makes  provision  for  the  patwaris  who  will  maintain 
the  records.  A  patwari  is  separately  found  for  each  estate, 
or  group  of  estates,  having  a  rental  of  R.  2000. 


§  10.    Chittagong  Local  Establishments. 

The  Chittagong  District  has  always  been  an  exception; 
there  being  no  Zamindars  of  large  estates,  but  only  small 
holdings  in  groups  of  very  independent  taluqdars,  almost 
like  a  raiyatwari  country,  the  kaniingo  has  always  been 
useful,  and  the  country  is  now  divided  into  '  tahsils,'  with 
tahsildars  under  whom  the  kanungos  work  very  much  as  in 
Northern  India. 


1  It  was  still  undetermined  in 
1887  (see  Board's  Annual  Report, 
Section  137).  Regulations  XII  of 
1817  and  I  of  1819  are  still  in  force 
(nominally). 

If  I  may  venture  an  opinion,  fur- 
ther legislation  may  give  a  certain 
legal  status  to  the  officers,  but  it 
will  not  infuse  life  into  them.  Pat- 


waris require  kanungos,  under 
orders  of  the  Land  Record  Depart- 
ment, to  inspect  them :  but  the 
patwari  can  do  nothing  unless  he 
has  accounts,  maps,  field-indexes, 
and  records  determined  by  authority 
to  start  with.  That  he  has  not  in 
Bengal ;  herein  lies  the  futility  of 
all  schemes  for  utilizing  thejn. 


CHAPTER  VI. 

LAND-REVENUE   BUSINESS    AND    PROCEDURE. 

SECTION  I. — INTRODUCTORY. 

I  DO  not  propose  to  go  into  any  detail  on  these  subjects  ; 
the  object  of  this  chapter  is  merely  to  indicate  how  certain 
main  heads  of  administration  are  provided  for.  For  the 
Permanent  Settlement,  with  its  total  absence  of  survey  and 
record-of-rights,  has  left  a  necessity  for  a  variety  of  special 
laws. 

For  example,  there  is  the  Registration  of  landed  property. 
I  do  not  here  speak  of  the  ordinary  Registration  law 
under  which  bonds,  mortgages,  and  other  documents,  are 
either  compulsorily  or  voluntarily  registered,  but  to  the 
maintenance  of  registers  or  lists  of  the  various  landed 
interests,  which  shall  have  public  credit  or  authority. 
The  preparation  of  such  registers  has  also  been  brought 
about  indirectly  in  various  ways.  There  is  the  direct 
law,  beginning  with  the  old  regulation  for  making  five- 
yearly  registers  of  Proprietary  estates  in  the  Collector's 
office.  Then  another  record  grew  out  of  the  necessity  for 
imposing  on  all  estates  a  cess  for  maintaining  roads,  and 
local  public  works,  as  will  presently  appear.  A  still 
further  registration  was  brought  about  by  the  sale-law. 
We  have  already  seen  how  early  it  was  perceived  to  be 
necessary  to  give  full  value  to  the  prior  lien  of  the  State  on 
all  land  for  its  revenue-dues.  This  could  not  be  effective 
if  the  land  were  so  encumbered  by  the  defaulting  holder 
that  at  sale  it  would  fetch  nothing.  So  that  in  some  form, 


682  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  H. 

or  to  some  extent,  it  became  a  matter  of  necessity  to  record 
such  encumbrances,  and  distinguish  those  subordinate  in- 
terests, which,  in  common  fairness,  ought  not  to  be  avoided  ; 
such  (for  instance)  as  might  not  have  been  created  by  the 
landlord  in  full  knowledge  that  his  acts  would  be  held 
subject  to  the  prior  claims  of  the  State.  After  many  changes 
which  have  been  incidentally  sketched  in  the  preceding 
pages,  the  device  was  hit  on  of  opening  certain  registers, 
and  allowing  that  interests  registered  in  the  one  or  the 
other  should  have  a  certain  protection  in  the  event  of  the 
estate  going  to  auction  for  arrears  of  revenue. 

Another  outcome  of  the  special  system  is  the  '  Certificate 
Procedure '  of  Bengal.  When  an  estate  cannot,  or  will  not, 
pay  its  revenue,  it  has  always  been  the  legal  remedy  to  put 
it  up  for  sale.  But  in  Bengal,  besides  the  Zamindari 
estates  which  are  so  dealt  with,  the  Government  has  a 
number  of  estates,  held  by  itself,  or  under  its  management, 
and  has  rents  and  other  dues  to  get  in  where  there  is  no 
estate  to  sell,  and  where  some  other  less  formal  and  (to  the 
State)  less  troublesome  method  than  a  law-suit  and  the 
execution  of  a  decree,  had  to  be  devised. 

The  special  Survey  law  was  another  outcome  of  the  state 
of  things  which  has  grown  up  out  of  the  Permanent  Settle- 
ment. 

Again,  the  local  circumstances  of  Bengal,  and  the  action 
of  rivers  in  some  districts,  have  also  necessitated  a  special 
law  regarding  drainage,  by  which  important  works  can  be 
carried  out  by  local  Commissioners  under  the  supervision 
of  Government.  A  similar  law  also  deals  with  watercourses 
and  embankments,  or  works  both  for  retaining  water  in 
tanks  or  reservoirs,  as  well  as  keeping  out  water  where, 
but  for  the  embankment,  it  would  flood  the  land  and  con- 
vert it  into  a  marsh.  Formerly,  it  would  seem  the  native 
Governments  entrusted  the  duty  of  maintaining  public 
watercourses  and  embankments  to  the  Zamindars  as  public 
officers,  and  allowed  them  to  deduct  from  the  revenue  certain 
charges  under  the  name  of  'pul-bandi'  and  the  like.  At 
Settlement  our  Government  determined  to  assess  the  revenue 


CHAP,  vi.]     LAND-EEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PEOCEDURE.     683 

in  one  sum,  on  which  no  deductions  were  to  be  allowed. 
But  the  Zamindars  still  bound  themselves  to  some  extent, 
and  in  general  terms,  to  maintain  embankments l.  All 
this  was,  however,  very  indefinite,  and  from  time  to  time 
Regulations  were  passed  to  deal  with  the  subject.  The 
existing  law  is  in  Bengal  Act  II  of  1882. 

Besides  these  more  special  branches  of  Bengal  Collectorate 
law,  there  are  the  usual  subjects  (relating  to  land)  of  par- 
tition of  estates,  acquisition  of  land  for  public  purposes, 
management  of  estates  by  the  Court  of  Wards  (Act  (B)  IX 
of  1879  and  amending  Acts)2. 

I  now  proceed  to  notice  specially,  a  few  of  the  more 
important  branches  of  business,  confining  myself  to  those 
directly  connected  with  land-revenue. 


SECTION  II. — REGISTRATION  OF  LANDED  PROPERTY. 

§  i.    Object  and  Practice  of  Land-Registration. 

It  was  the  intention  of  the  legislature  from  the  first,  that 
there  should  be  at  least  one  Register  kept  up,  showing  the 
extent  and  particulars  of  each  estate  separately  assessed 
with  revenue  payable  to  Government.  The  object  was  to 
enable  the  Collectors  to  apportion  the  revenue  in  cases  of 
partition,  and  to  enable  the  Civil  Courts  to  know  when  an 
estate  changed  hands,  or  happened  to  be  transferred  from 
one  district  to  another.  The  registers  were  first  directed  to 
deal  with  the  land  as  grouped  by  estates  only 3,  but  after- 

1  But  construction  was  to  be  under-  judgment  (I.  L.  R.,  7,  Calcutta,  505") 

taken   by  the   State.     One    of  the  quoted  at  length  in  H.  A.  D.  Phillips' 

clauses  of  the  Zamindar's  engage-  Revenue  and  Collectorate  Law,  p.  165. 

ment  used  to  be  :  '  the  construction  2  The  New  Guardian  and  Wards 

of  "beri"  (small  embankments),  the  Act,  VIII  of  1890,  which  has  sim- 

excavation    of  silt    from    "  khal  "  plified  and  consolidated  the  general 

(water-courses),  the  construction  of  law  of  minors,  &c.  (and  repeals  the 

"gangura"   (larger  embankments)  old  Act  XL  of  1858)  does  not  touch 

in  connection  with  the  salt  and  sweet  the  Bengal  Act  quoted  in  the  text, 

lands  of  the  pargana,  shall  be  made  (See  Sec.  3  of  the  new  Act. ) 

by  the  Government  of  the  Hon'ble  3  And    any  estate    might    have 

Company.'     The   whole   history  of  lands  belonging  to  it  scattered  over 

the  Regulations  relating  to  embank-  half  the  district  or  extending  into 

ments   is  given  in  a  High  Court  other  districts.      Reg.   XLVIII   of 


684  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.          [BOOK  n. 

wards  'pargana  registers,'  dealing  with  the  lands  as  they  lay, 
and  accounting  for  every  plot  in  each  pargana  and  its  sub- 
divisions, were  ordered.  The  law  on  this  subject  was  never 
very  well  carried  out,  and  the  Regulation  was  both  cum- 
brous and  incomplete.  It  is,  however,  unnecessary  in  this 
place  to  dwell  on  the  history  of  the  past ;  it  is  enough  to 
turn  to  the  present  law  (Bengal  Act  VII  of  1876) 1. 

The  object  of  the  registration  is  simply  to  know  who  is 
the  person  answerable,  as  in  possession,  for  every  plot  of 
land  in  the  district,  whether  revenue-paying  or  revenue- 
free.  Every  person  in  possession,  whether  as  owner  or 
manager  of  the  land,  or  of  any  share  in  it,  is  bound,  under 
heavy  penalty,  to  register.  Registration  is  optional  in 
the  case  of  mortgagees  who  have  a  lien  but  not  possession 
of  the  soil. 

The  Act  does  not  apply  to  certain  special  localities,  e.g.  the 
Western  Dwars,  the  Kolhan  estate,  and  the  political  estates 
in  the  Singbhum  district.  The  possibility  of  overcoming 
the  difficulties  of  the  old  system  is  largely  owing  to  the 
land-survey,  of  which  mention  will  presently  be  made.  In 
the  course  of  the  survey,  descriptive  lists  of  the  land 
were  prepared  (and  the  survey  followed  the  local  areas 
or  villages,  or  was,  in  revenue  language,  mauzawdr). 
Registers  showing  the  estates  as  made  up  of  lands  in  dif- 
ferent villages,  or  of  groups  of  villages  locally  compact 
(i.  e.  mahalwar  registers),  are  easily  prepared  from  those  first 
mentioned,  by  simply  abstracting  them.  In  September, 
1888,  the  Board  noticed  in  a  circular,  that  proposals  for 
legislation  to  enforce  the  record  of  all  changes  subsequent 
to  the  initial  registration,  had  been  abandoned  for  the  pre- 

1 793  was  the  first  law :  that  directed  there  were  did  not  explain  who  the 

an  (English)  alphabetical  register,  owners  were,  and  furnished  no  in- 

with  a  supplementary  register   of  formation  at  all  about  under-tenures 

changes  by  sale,  inheritance,   &c. ,  and  raiyats. 

and  every  fifth  year  the  registers  1  As  amended  by  Act  V  of  1878. 

were  to  be  written  out  anew.     The  See  also    Chapter  V   of   the  First 

Regulation  was   amended    by   No.  Volume  of  the  Rules  of  the  Revenue  De- 

VIII   of   1800;    but   up  till    1876,  partment  (edition  of  1878),  with  ad- 

practically,  the  registers  were  not  ditions    prescribed    in    September, 

properly  kept,  nor  were  any  penal-  1888,  by  Board's  Circular. 
ties    enforced.     Such    registers    as 


CHAP,  vi.]    LAND-BEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE.     685 

sent.  But  '  various  disqualifications  are  now  imposed  by 
law  on  those  who  neglect  to  register.  Under  Section  78 
of  Act  VII  (B.C.)  of  1876,  no  one  is  bound  to  pay  rent  to 
an  unregistered  proprietor.  A  revenue  officer  making 
a  Settlement  of  rents  under  the  Tenancy  Act  (1885)  may 
refuse  to  entertain  an  application  for  enhancement  or  settle- 
ment of  fair  rents  from  a  proprietor  who  is  not  registered. 
It  is  only  registered  proprietors  who  are  entitled  to  partition 
(batwara),  or  to  open  separate  accounts  with  the  Collector 
whether  for  revenue  or  cesses,  to  bring  a  patni  to  sale,  to 
object  to  common  or  special  registry  (of  this  hereafter),  and 
to  claim  surplus  sale-proceeds  on  the  estates  of  which  they 
are  proprietors  being  sold  for.  arrears  of  revenue.'  In  order 
to  facilitate  registration,  the  Board  supply,  free  of  cost, 
forms  of  application  which  are  to  be  had  from  stamp- 
vendors  and  others. 


§  2.    Form  of  Registration. 

The  registers  at  present  required  by  law  are  : — 
(A),  a  register  showing  the  revenue-paying  lands  in  the 
district.  This  is  divided  into  two  parts,  to  show  the  lands 
which  belong  to  estates  the  revenue  of  which  is  payable  in 
the  district,  and  lands  within  the  district,  which  form  por- 
tions of  estates  whose  assessment  is  payable  in  other 
districts. 

(B),  a  register  of  revenue-free  lands.  This  is  divided 
into  three  parts  showing  (i)  perpetual  revenue-free  grants  ; 
(2)  lands  held  by  Government  or  companies  for  public  pur- 
poses free  of  revenue  ;  and  (3)  unassessed  waste  land  and 
other  lands  not  included  in  part  i  or  2. 

(C)  is  a  register  of  lands  paying  revenue  and  those  held 
revenue-free,  arranged  '  mauzawar,'  i.  e.  the  register  is  a  list 
of  the  villages  in  each  local  sub-division  (adopted  for  the 
purpose  by  order  of  the  Board)  and  accounting  for  all  the 
lands  in  each  village,  showing  to  what  estate  each  belong, 
which  are  revenue-free,  and  so  on. 

(D)  is  an  'intermediate'  register  for  all  kinds  of  land, 


686  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF    BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  ir. 

showing  the  changes  in  proprietary  rights  resulting  from 
sale,  succession,  lapse,  or  other  transfer,  and  changes  caused 
by  the  alteration  of  district  and  other  boundaries. 

The  registers  are  only  re-written  when  the  changes  have 
become  so  numerous  as  to  affect  the  original  register  very 
considerably  and  make  it  no  longer  of  any  use  for  reference. 
The  Act  makes  it  obligatory  on  persons  interested  to  give 
information  with  a  view  to  the  preparation  of  the  registers. 
It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  registration  only  describes 
the  person  in  possession.  It  decides  no  question  of  right. 
Section  89  of  the  Act  expressly  states  that  any  one  may 
sue  for  possession  or  for  a  declaration  of  right,  the  Act 
n  ot  with  standing. 

§  3.    'DdJckil-khdrij.' — Subsequent  Changes. 

The  proceedings  for  reporting  and  registering  changes  in 
proprietorship  are  spoken  of  as  '  dakhil-kharij,'  and  closely 
resemble  the  same  procedure  in  other  provinces.  The 
'  dakhil-kharij '  proceedings  are  solely  concerned  with  the 
fact  of,  or  right  to,  possession.  If  the  applicant's  possession 
of,  succession  to,  or  acquisition  by  transfer  of  the  pro- 
perty is  disputed,  the  Collector  will  summarily  determine 
the  right  to  possession,  and  will  then  see  that  the  party  is 
put  in  possession,  and  will  make  the  entry  in  the  register 
accordingly1. 

The  details  of  procedure  for  obtaining  mutation  of  names 
will  be  found  in  the  Act. 

The  work  of  registration  is  now  practically  complete,  or 
will  shortly  be  so.  In  1887  it  was  reported  complete  in 
thirty-seven  out  of  the  forty-three  districts  to  which  the  law 
applies,  and  was  practically  complete  in  the  remaining 
districts.  In  the  Orissa  districts  and  in  Chittagong  there 
was  a  source  of  unusual  labour  in  the  number  of  petty 
revenue-free  holdings,  and  the  work  was  brought  to  a  close 
by  rejecting  from  registration  very  small  free-holdings. 

1  Bengal  Act  VII  of  1876,  section       Dakhil  means  '  entering '  :  kharij  is 
55,  as  amended  by  Act  V  of  1878.       '  putting  out.' 


CHAP.  VI.]    LAND-REVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE.     687 


§  4.    Registration  of  subordinate  Interests  in  Lind, 

It  will  be  observed  that  these  registers  do  not  profess 
to  deal  with  any  subordinate  rights  or  interests ;  there  is 
nothing  in  Bengal  which  answers  to  the  '  Record- of-Rights ' 
of  the  North -West  Provinces1.  It  so  happens,  however, 
that  the  Road  and  Public  Works  Cess,  Bengal  Act  IX  of 
i88o2,  has  resulted  in  a  record  of  subordinate  rights  also. 
The  results  are,  however,  vitiated  by  the  system  of  summary 
valuation  (for  purposes  of  the  Cess  calculation)  which  the 
Act  necessarily  provides.  This  summary  valuation  '  with- 
draws from  sight  all  details  of  tenures,  under-tenures,  and 
raiyati  holdings  contained  in  such  estates  or  tenures  as  are 
summarily  valued.'  '  In  the  instructions  issued  to  officers  3 
under  the  Act  IX  of  1880  (B.C.)  an  attempt  has  been  made 
to  remedy  this  defect  in  the  returns,  by  declaring  that  the 
least  possible  recourse  should  be  had  to  the  process  of  sum- 
mary valuation.'  The  Road  Cess  is  a  tax  levied  on  all 
classes  of  proprietors,  including  every  grade  of  tenure- 
holders,  down  to  a  limit  of  cultivators  paying  R.  100  in  the 
year  as  rent ;  and  hence  a  register  has  to  be  made  of  them. 
There  is  no  legal  validity,  as  evidence  of  right,  attached  to 
these  returns. 

There  is  another  method,  however,  of  registering  under- 
tenures.  We  have  seen  that  it  has  been  always  the  law 
that  when  an  estate  is  sold  for  arrears  of  revenue,  all  leases 
and  under-tenures  (with  certain  exceptions4)  are  liable  to 
be  voided,  and  the  purchaser  gets  a  clear  and  complete 
'  Parliamentary '  title.  This  is  so  under  the  Sale  Law  (Act 
XI  of  1 859)  and  its  Amending  Acts 5.  To  protect  such 

1  Except  of  course  in  Government  '"  The   Board   has    issued   a    col- 
estates  or  in  temporary  Settlements       lection    of    Rules    called    the    Cess 
under  Regulation  VII  of  1822,  or  in       Manual,  1888. 

cases   where,    under    the   Tenancy  4  Now  contained  in  section  37  of 

Act,  Chapter   X,    or  other    special  Act  XI  of  1859. 

(local     law\    records-of- rights    are  5  Act    (B.C.)    Ill   of    1862,    Act 

made.  (B.C.)    VII   of    1868.    Act    (B.C.) 

2  Acts  X  of  1871  and  II  of  1877  II  of  1871,  and  Act  VII  (B.  C.)  of 
have  been  repealed  and  superseded  1880. 

by  the  Act  quoted  in  the  text. 


688  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  H. 

Act  XI  of  tenures,  the  Act  provides 1  that  they  may  be  registered  either 

1850,  sec.       .  ,  •     i  >  •    L        <>  n        •    i        L-  • 

38  to  50.  in  a  common  or  a  special  register J.  Registration  in 
the  former  protects  them  from  being  voided  on  sale  of  the 
estate  for  arrears,  by  any  party  other  than  Government ;  and 
special  registration  protects  them  absolutely.  The  Act  also 
provides  that  the  rights  of  sharers  may  be  protected  (and 
this  is  important,  because  otherwise  the  default  of  one 
sharer  might  cause  the  whole  estate  to  be  sold).  'Separate 
Sec.  10.  accounts '  are  opened  with  sharers  on  application.  Separate 
Sec.  ii.  accounts  can  also  be  opened  for  sharers,  who  not  only  have 
a  specified  fractional  interest  in  an  estate  (and  therefore  are 
liable  for  a  known  fraction  of  the  revenue),  but  whose  shares 
consist  of  '  a  specific  portion  of  the  land  of  the  estate ' : 
Section  70,  Act  VII  of  1876,  also  contemplates  separate 
accounts  of  '  complex  shares '  as  therein  described.  And 
Part  V  of  Act  VII  of  1877  (Land  Registration)  should  be 
read  as  to  '  separate  accounts '  generally. 

For  the  procedure  necessary  to  the  registering,  the  Act 
itself  must  be  consulted. 


SECTION  III. — COLLECTION  OF  THE  LAND-REVENUE. 

§  i.    The  Taujih  Department. 

For  the  purposes  of  revenue  collection,  besides  the  lists 
of  estates  just  described,  there  must  be  kept  up  lists 
showing  the  revenue  payable  by  each  estate  or  separately 
assessed  portion  of  an  estate.  There  is  a  general  district 
revenue-roll,  divided  into  two  parts — one  showing  the 
revenue  fixed  permanently  or  for  a  time,  and  payable  by 

1  See  Board's  Rules,  vol.  i.  ch.  xiv.  '  special '    389    (rental    R.  46.099). 

2  Up  to  the    end  of    1887,    the  Separate    accounts    (under  section 
'  common  register'  contained  2502  10)  were  40.524,  with  a  revenue  de- 
holdings  with  an  area  of  28,037,819  mand  of  over  6o|  lakhs.     Accounts 
acres, and  arevenueofR.  1,21,94,842.  for  specific  shares  (section  11)  were 
The  '  special  register '  contained  256  3680,   with   a   revenue  demand  of 
holdings,   of  8,861,964  acres,   with  over  4|  lakhs.     Accounts  under  sec- 
a    revenue    of    R.    30,85,888.     The  tion  70  (Act  VII  of  1876  B.C.)  were 
tenures   registered   were  '  common '  7,061,   with  a  revenue  demand  of 
4440     (rental     R.  24,35.234),     and  something  over  5  lakhs. 


CHAP,  vi.]    LAND-EEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE.  .  689 

proprietors,  farmers,  or  other  engagees  for  the  whole ;  the 
other  showing  the  rent  or  revenue  in  estates  in  which  the 
raiyats  pay  direct  to  Government.  It  is  not  necessary 
to  go  into  further  detail  on  the  subject1. 

§  2.    Sale  Laws. 

The  effects  of  the  Law  of  Sale  for  arrears  have  been 
noticed  in  previous  chapters. 

The  present  law  on  the  subject  is  to  be  found  in  Act  XI 
of  1859,  as  amended  and  amplified  by  Bengal  Acts  III  of 
1862  and  VII  of  1868,  and  still  more  recently  by  Bengal  Act 
VII  of  1880  for  the  recovery  of  '  Public  Demands.' 

An  '  arrear '  accrues,  if  the  '  kist '  (properly  gist)  or  instal- 
ment of  revenue  due  for  any  month  remains  unpaid  on  the 
first  of  the  following  month.      In  some  cases  notice  for  Act  XI  of 
fifteen  days   before   sale  is   required,  and  the   later  Act  *  and  ^^ 

enables  Government  to  empower  Collectors  to  issue  warn-  B.  Actvil 
,,  of  1868. 

ing  notices  in  all  cases.  sec.  6. 

Sharers  of  joint  estates  can  protect  themselves  from  their 
shares  being  sold  for  arrears  along  with  the  rest  of  the 
estate,  by  applying  for  and  obtaining  an  order  for  a  '  sepa- 
rate revenue  account'  of  their  share,  as  I  mentioned  at 
page  688.  But  if  on  a  sale  being  notified  (subject  to 
the  exception  of  the  separate  shares),  it  is  found  that  the 
estate,  subject  to  such  exception,  will  not  fetch  a  price  equal 
to  the  amount  in  arrear,  then  notice  is  given  that,  unless 
the  recorded  sharers  make  up  the  arrears  and  so  save  the 
estate,  the  whole  estate  will  be  sold.  I  pass  over  the  rules 
for  re-sale  in  case  the  auction-purchaser  fails  to  pay  the 
purchase-money  in  due  time,  and  here  only  notice  that 
there  is  an  appeal  (final)  to  the  Commissioner  against  a 
sale  in  certain  cases.  The  Commissioner  may  also  suspend  B.  Act  VII 
a  sale  in  cases  of  hardship,  and  report  to  the  Board,  on  ^  2  ' 

Act  XI  of 

1  The   detail    may  be   found   in       keeps  the  rent-roll  and  the  accounts  1859,  sec. 
chap.  vi.  Rules  of  the  Revenue  Depart-       of  each  estate,  with  the  amounts,  26. 
ment,  vol.  i.  (1878).     The  revenue       collections,  and  balances,  is  spoken 
roll  is  written  up  by  the  Taujih-       of  as  the  Taujih  Department, 
navis :    the    establishment    which 

VOL.  I.  Y  y 


6QO  LAND   SYSTEMS   OF   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

whose  recommendation  the  sale  may  be  annulled  (after  it 
Act  XI  of  has  taken  place)  by  the  local  Government.     The  jurisdic- 
3359'  se  '    tion  of  the  Civil  Courts  to  annul  a  sale,  on  a  regular  suit 
being  brought  for  the  purpose,  is  also  defined. 

As  already  noticed,  a  sale  for  arrears  hands  the  estate 

over  to  the  purchaser  with  a  clear  title  :  the  purchaser  may 

void  and  annul  all  leases  and  subordinate  tenures,  except 

those  specified  in  Section  37  of  the  Act  XI,  and  those  which 

are  protected  by  registration.     '  Tenures,'  and  interests  like 

fisheries,  and  other  interests  arising  out  of  lands  not  being 

Act  VII  of '  estates '  (land  or  shares  in  revenue-paying  land)  may  be 

^    '  sec*    sold  like  estates  for  arrears  of  revenue. 

The  sale  law,  which  at  first  worked  very  hardly,  is  now 
little  felt.  The  average  annual  number  of  defaulting  estates 
and  shares  during  the  last  ten  years,  has  been  9126,  of  which 
only  1624  or  i7'8  per  cent,  have  actually  been  sold. 

For  the  details  of  Sale  Law  Procedure  the  student  will 
naturally  refer  to  Mr.  Grimley's  Manual  of  Sale  Law 
published  by  the  Bengal  Government.  But  I  must  warn  him 
that  the  Sale  Law  is  being  consolidated  and  redrafted  by 
the  Board  of  Revenue,  but  the  Bill  will  not  be  completed 
nor  come  before  Council  in  time  for  me  to  give  any  in- 
formation about  it  in  this  chapter. 


§  3.    Certificate  Procedure. — Public  Demands  Act. 

There  is  a  Certificate  Procedure  Manual,  1885,  which 
gives  the  detailed  rules  on  this  subject *.  As  sale  of  the 
estate  is  the  only  remedy  for  revenue  default,  it  follows 
that  some  further  procedure  is  needed  for  the  collection  of 
rents  in  Government  estates  and  other  public  demands  to 
which  the  sale  law  is  inapplicable.  Bengal  Act  VII  of  1868 
was  intended  to  provide  for  the  recovery  of  such  demands , 
and  Act  VII  of  1880  amended  the  law.  It  is  only  necessary 
to  allude  to  the  subject;  the  practice  being  quite  simple. 
Briefly,  the  Collector  records  a  '  certificate  of  arrears ' 

1  To  be  had  in  the  Bengal  Secretariat  Press. 


CHAP.  VI.]    LAND-REVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PEOCEDUEE.     691 

which  acts  like  a  decree  of  Court,  and  can  be  executed 
continuously  till  all  is  paid,  subject,  of  course,  to  the  law 
of  limitation. 


SECTION  IV. — SURVEY. 

I  have  already  given  a  description  of  the  survey  work  in 
Bengal  (see  p.  456  ante).  Here  it  is  only  necessary  to 
allude  to  the  laws  applicable. 

Previous  to  1875,  as  far  as  permanently-settled  estates 
were  concerned,  the  process  of  revenue-survey  was  carried 
on  without  any  authority  given  by  law.  Regulation  VII 
of  1822  could  not  be  quoted,  since  it  applied  to  non- 
permanently  settled  estates,  and  could  not  warrant  any 
action  with  reference  to  estates  in  which  there  could  be 
no  question  of  re-settlement.  In  1847,  indeed,  a  law  had 
been  passed  regarding  the  survey  of  lands  liable  to  river 
action1,  and  the  principles  of  this  law  are  still  maintained 
under  the  Survey  Acts.  The  whole  business  of  survey  is 
now  regulated  by  Bengal  Act  V  of  i8752.  It  is  not  my 
intention  to  go  into  any  detail  as  to  the  procedure,  but 
a  general  outline  may  be  given  so  as  to  furnish  a  clue  or 
guide  to  the  study  of  the  Act  itself  when  necessary. 

The  Act  allows  a  survey  to  be  made  extending  not  only 
to  districts  and  to  estates,  but,  if  ordered,  to  defining  fields 
and  the  limits  of  tenures  3. 


1  Act  IX  of  1847  (amended  by  cannot  in   consequence  be  identi- 

Act  IV    (B.C.)   of   1868).     In   the  fied ;    also  to  ascertain  and  assess 

case  of  the  alluvial  lands  the  survey  lands  which   have  been  added   to 

is  treated  as  a  special  matter  ;  it  is  the  estates  by  accretion.'    (Board's 

required  only  along  the  banks  of  Revenue  Administration  Report,  1879- 

the  great  rivers.     At  present  the  80,  §  92.) 

special  branch   which   deals   with  2  As  amended  by  Act  VII  (B.C.) 

this  work — the   '  Diyara   (Dearah)  of  1880,  with  regard  to  the  recovery 

Survey'  as  it  is  called — is  confined  of  demands  under  the  Act  (sec.  5). 

to  the  Dacca  Division.    It  is  worked  3  But,  of  course,  has  nothing  to 

by  non-professional   agency  under  do  with  denning  or  recording  rights; 

the  Deputy-collectors.     The   object  that  has  to  be  done  under  chap.  x. 

is   to   '  identify  and  relay  on   the  of  the   Tenant   Act,   1885,    or   the 

ground  the  boundaries  of  villages  Settlement  Act  of  1879,  as  the  case 

which  have  been  subject  to  fluvial  may  be,  in   the   cases  where   it  is 

action  and  of  which  the  boundaries  lawful  to  order  it. 

Y  y  a 


692  LAND    SYSTEMS    OP   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II, 

After  provisions  relating  to  establishments,  the  Act  re- 
quires a  proclamation  to  be  issued,  and  persons  to  attend 
and  point  out  boundaries,  clear  lines,  and  so  forth,  so  that 
the  survey  may  begin. 

When  the  demarcation  is  complete,  the  persons  who 
pointed  out  the  boundaries  are  required  to  inspect  the 
papers  and  plans  representing  such  boundaries,  and  to 
satisfy  themselves  as  to  whether  the  boundary-marks  have 
been  fixed  according  to  their  information.  The  plans  and 
papers  are  to  be  signed  by  these  parties,  in  token  that  the 
marks  are  shown  in  the  maps  or  papers  in  the  places  where 
they  declared  they  should  be. 

The  Collector  can  always  set  up  temporary  marks,  and 
may  also  set  up  permanent  marks ;  after  notifying  their 
number  and  cost  and  giving  opportunity  for  objections  to 
be  heard,  he  may  direct  the  cost  to  be  apportioned  among 

Sees.  19,  the  land-owners  or  tenure-holders  concerned.  Provision  is 
made  for  the  permanent  maintenance  of  these  marks. 

Passing  over  the  detailed  provisions  for  determining  who 
shall  bear  the  cost  of  the  boundary-marks,  and  how  it  is  to 

Act,  Part   be  apportioned,  I  proceed  to  the  subject  of  boundary-disputes. 

&c&ec'  4°'  Here  the  Collector  is  to  decide  on  the  basis  of  actual  pos- 
session, and  his  order  holds  good  till  it  is  upset  by  competent 
authority.  If  possession  cannot  be  ascertained,  the  Collector 
may  attach  the  land  till  one  party  or  the  other  obtains  a 
legal  decision ;  or  the  Collector  may,  by  consent  of  the 
parties,  refer  the  matter  to  arbitration.  There  are  also 
excellent  provisions  for  relaying  any  boundary  which  has 
once  been  decided,  but  which  has  become  doubtful  or 
disputed. 

Full  provisions  also  will  be  found  for  protecting  boundary- 
marks  from  injury  and  restoring  them  when  damaged. 

The  Act,  it  will  be  observed,  does  not  say  anything  about 
the  records  and  registers  which  the  Survey  Department 
prepare. 

These  particulars,  and  rules  about  the  scale,  and  so  forth, 
must  be  sought  for  in  the  Board's  Revenue  Rules. 


CHAP,  vi.]    LAND-REVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE.     693 


SECTION  V. — PARTITION  OF  ESTATES. 

This  generally  finds  a  place  among  the  topics  of  revenue 
procedure.  Owing  to  the  fact  that  by  the  native  laws  the 
sons  or  other  heirs  succeed  together,  it  follows  from  our 
modern  ideas,  that  any  one  of  a  joint  body  may  re- 
quire that  his  interest  and  share  should  be  separated  off 
and  assigned  to  him.  This  process  is  called  '  batwara '  or 
partition.  But,  then,  such  a  separation  may  affect  the 
Government  revenue  :  since,  if  an  estate  assessed  with,  and 
liable  as  a  whole  for,  one -sum  of  revenue,  is  afterwards 
divided  into,  say,  four  properties,  the  Government  interest 
would  be  considerably  affected,  unless  the  whole  group 
remained,  as  before,  liable  for  the  entire  revenue. 

This  fact  has  led  in  Northern  India  to  a  distinction  between 
'  imperfect '  and  '  perfect '  partition.  When  the  partition  is 
imperfect,  the  different  shareholders  get  their  private  rights 
separated  and  declared,  but  the  whole  estate  still  remains 
liable  to  Government  for  the  whole  revenue.  In  '  perfect ' 
partition  the  responsibility  to  Government  is  also  divided, 
and  the  shares  henceforth  become  separate  estates,  entirely 
independent  one  of  the  other.  It  has  always  been  therefore 
a  moot  question  how  far  partition  should  be  allowed.  The 
question,  indeed,  has  most  interest  in  those  provinces  where 
the  village  Settlement-system  is  in  force.  That  system,  as 
the  student  will  have  sufficiently  gathered  from  the  Intro- 
ductory Chapters  in  Book  I,  is  based  on  the  joint  respon- 
sibility of  the  community,  for  the  lump  sum  assessed  on 
the  village  area. 

In  Bengal  the  land  unit  is  different ;  but  still  the  break- 
ing up  of  a  compact  estate  liable  to  sale  as  a  whole,  for 
the  revenue  assessed  on  it,  into  a  number  of  petty  holdings, 
each  separately  liable  for  its  fractional  assessment,  and 
possessing  a  very  reduced  market  value  in  consequence  of 
its  small  size,  has  been  felt  to  be  a  real  difficulty.  On  the 
other  hand,  there  are  interests  which  benefit  by  partition. 


694  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BRITISH    INDIA.         [BOOK  II. 

The  tenants  on  a  joint  estate  are  often  seriously  harassed 
by  having  to  pay  their  total  rent  in  a  number  of  fractions 
to  different  shareholders,  each  insisting  on  collecting  his 
own  separate  payment.  A  separation  of  the  interests  tends 
to  alleviate  this1.  The  question,  therefore,  of  regulating 
partition  long  remained  under  discussion.  It  had  been 
dealt  with  by  Regulations  in  1793,  1801,  and  1803.  In 
1807  a  limit  had  been  put  to  the  division,  and  no  share 
assessed  with  less  than  R.5oo  revenue  was  allowed  to  be 
separated.  This  Regulation,  however,  was  thought  to  go 
too  far,  and  was  afterwards  repealed2.  The  subject  has 
been  more  recently  set  at  rest  by  the  passing  of  Bengal  Act 
VIII  of  1876. 

This  Act  contemplates  only  one  kind  of  partition,  i.  e.  the 
complete  separation  of  the  estates,  not  only  as  regards  the 
private   rights,  but  as  regards  the  responsibility  for  the 
revenue.     But  no  partition  made  after  the  date  of  the  Act 
coming  in  force  (4th  October,  1876)  other  than  under  its 
provisions,  though  it  may  bind  the  parties,  can  affect  the 
responsibility  for  Government  revenue.     There  is  a  limit, 
but  only  a  very  low  one,  to  partition :  if  the  separate  share 
would  bear  a  revenue  not  exceeding  one  rupee,  the  separa- 
tion cannot    be   made,  unless  the  proprietor  consents  to 
redeem  the  land-revenue,  under  the  rules  for  this  purpose. 
B.  Act       Partition  can  be  refused  when  the  result  of  it  would  be  to 
1876  lees  break  UP  a  compact  estate  into  several  estates  consisting  of 
11-13         scattered  parcels  of  land,  and  which  would,  in  the  opinion 
of  the  Collector,  endanger  the  land-revenue. 

For  the  procedure  of  a  partition  case,  how  disputes  are 
settled,  how  the  final  order  is  recorded,  the  Act  must  be 
referred  to.  The  proceedings  are  held  'on  the  Revenue 
side '  before  the  Collector. 

1  This  difficulty  of  fractional  pay-       Macneile's  Memorandum,  chap.  xvii. 
ments  will  be  found  discussed  in          2  By  Regulation  V  of  1 8 10. 


CHAP.  VI.]    LAND-EEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PEOCEDUEE.     695 

SECTION  VI. — ESTATE  MANAGEMENT. 
§  i.    Government  Estates. 

While  speaking  of  the  Collector's  general  revenue  duty, 
it  is  impossible  to  avoid  mentioning  one  branch  which  is 
not  represented  by  any  particular  Act.  I  refer  to  what  is 
called  '  khas,'  or  direct  management,  of  estates  belonging 
to  Government,  where  no  one  is  entitled  to  a  Settlement. 
or  of  estates  where  a  person  entitled  declines  the  terms  of 
Settlement  and  is  therefore  excluded  for  a  term  (with 
a'malikana'  allowance).  'It  was  formerly  the  custom  to  let 
estates  of  this  kind  in  farm,  but  in  1873  the  practice  was 
condemned  as  injurious  to  the  interests  of  the  property,  and 
the  tenantry.  .  .  .  There  are  1061  estates  with  an  annual 
revenue  of  R.  26,27,360  under  the  direct  management  of  the 
revenue  officers  throughout  the  Lower  Provinces  V  Estates 
are  either  managed  by  the  revenue  officers  as  part  of  their 
ordinary  duty,  or,  in  case  of  larger  estates,  by  special 
managers  with  suitable  collecting  establishments.  The 
management  charges  are  met  by  setting  apart  10  per  cent, 
of  the  total  collections  as  a  fund  (credited  to  Land-Revenue 
Receipts  in  the  public  accounts)  for  meeting  the  costs ; 
74  per  cent,  is  placed  at  the  disposal  of  the  Board  of 
Revenue  for  expenses  of  management,  Settlement,  measure- 
ment, and  improvements  and  2j  per  cent,  is  devoted  (not 
under  the  Board)  to  education  and  roads. 

§  2.    The  Court  of  Wards. 

A  most  important  branch  of  management  duty  is  the 
care  of  Wards'  estates,  regulated  by  Act  IX  (B.  C.)  of  1879 
(amended  by  Act  III  of  1881).  There  is  also  an  excellent 
manual  of  rules  issued  under  the  authority  of  the  Board  of 
Revenue. 

I  cannot  forbear  making  another  extract  from  the 
Report  (on  Land-tenures]  of  1883,  on  the  results  attained 

1  This  is  exclusive  of  such  estates  as  are  still,  for  special  reasons,  farmed. 
(Report  1883,  p.  29.) 


696  LAND    SYSTEMS    OF   BEITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

by  the  management  (under  the  Court  of  Wards)  of  the  great 
estate  of  Darbhanga  (1860-1879).  The  extract  not  only 
speaks  of  the  benefits  conferred,  but  incidentally  affords  a 
vivid  sketch  of  the  varied  subjects  which  come  under  the 
Manager's  notice.  I  will  only  add  that  effort  is  made,  when 
an  estate  comes  under  the  Court  of  Wards,  to  get  a  survey 
and  record-of-rights,  but  it  is  not  always  that  the  resources 
and  circumstances  of  the  estate  make  such  a  course 
possible. 

'  The  Darbhanga  Eaj  is  the  largest  property  which  has,  for 
many  years  past,  been  under  the  charge  of  the  Court  of  Wards. 
When  the  Court  took  charge,  in  1860,  its  condition  seemed 
almost  hopelessly  bad.  The  gross  annual  rental  was  nominally 
K.  16,39,357,  and  the  Government  revenue  only  K.  4,07,484. 
But  the  management  had  for  years  been  left  entirely  in  the 
hands  of  underlings.  All  the  villages  were  leased  to  farmers, 
most  of  them  relatives  of  the  Eaj  servants,  who  had  got  their 
leases  on  favourable  terms.  Others  were  outsiders,  men  of 
straw,  who  had  nominally  undertaken  to  pay  rents  far  above 
the  value  of  the  lands,  and  who  made  what  they  could  by  rack- 
renting  the  ryots  and  levying  illegal  cesses,  without  attempting 
to  satisfy  the  Eaj  demand.  Security  for  payment  was  never 
taken  from  the  farmers.  Pattas  and  kabiiliyats  were  seldom 
interchanged.  The  correct  rental  of  the  villages  was  nowhere 
recorded.  Patwaris'  papers  were  seldom  forthcoming.  The 
outstanding  arrears  of  rent,  at  first  unknown,  proved  to  amount 
to  E.  56,44,972.  There  were  other  debts  due  to  the  estate, 
aggregating  E.  3,37,775.  The  debts  alleged  to  be  due  by  the 
Maharaja  to  creditors  amounted  to  a  crore  of  rupees,  of  which 
the  Court  of  Wards  was  compelled  to  admit  E.  71,88,427.  The 
estates  were  destitute  of  roads  and  bridges.  The  palace  was 
neglected  and  in  ruins  ;  its  courtyards  quagmires  ;  its  environs 
a  hopeless  waste  of  jungle,  pools,  and  filth.  Notoriously  all 
the  epidemics  of  the  town  took  their  rise  in  the  Eajbari. 
There  were  no  refuges  for  the  sick ;  no  resting-places  for  tra- 
vellers ;  not  a  school  in  the  whole  estate.  No  productive  works 
of  any  kind  had  anywhere  been  attempted. 

'  On  the  surrender  of  the  estate  to  the  Maharaja,  in  1879,  all 
this  had  been  changed.  The  rent-roll  had  been  re-adjusted  ; 
and  although  reductions  of  rental  had  been  made,  amounting 


CHAP,  vi.]    LAND-KEVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PKOCEDURE.     697 

to  E.  5,92,323,  the  gross  rental  (including  that  of  a  few  small 
properties  purchased)  was  E.  21,61,885.  The  outstanding 
arrears  of  rent  due  to  the  estate  were  E.  18,51,397  (less  than 
a  year's  demand),  of  which  E.  14,51,664  were  good  and  in  process 
of  realization.  All  debts  had  been  paid  off  long  before.  There 
was  a  cash  balance  in  hand  of  E.  2,75,733,  besides  Government 
securities  of  the  value  of  E.  38,54,500.  Over  150  miles  of  road 
had  been  constructed  and  bridged  (in  many  places  with  screw- 
pile  viaducts).  Upwards  of  20,000  trees  had  been  planted  along 
their  sides.  Feeder  and  village  roads  had  been  made  and  im- 
proved. In  Kharakpur,  extensive  irrigation  works,  securing 
that  property  against  famine,  had  been  made  and  opened.  A 
large  bazaar  had  been  built  at  Darbhanga,  including  a  handsome 
public  serai a.  The  old  palace  was  considerably  improved  and 
was  made  the  centre  of  a  pretty  garden  some  fifty  acres  in 
extent.  In  lieu  of  the  ruinous  system  of  farming  leases,  the 
whole  estate  had  been  brought  under  direct  management. 
Collections  were  made  without  friction  or  difficulty.  The  out- 
lying zirat  lands2  had  been  equitably  settled  with  indigo- 
planters,  while  those  in  the  vicinity  of  villages  had  been 
reserved  for  the  ryots,  thus  putting  an  end  to  the  constant 
disputes  between  the  factories  and  the  cultivators.  Hundreds 
of  small  embankments,  water-channels,  tanks,  and  wells  had 
been  constructed  from  advances  made  without  interest  to  the 
tenants.  Complete  surveys  had  been  made  of  the  greater  part 
of  the  property,  and  a  considerable  area  had  been  resettled  to 
the  advantage  both  of  the  estate  and  of  the  cultivators.  Twenty 
vernacular  schools  had  been  established  by  the  Eaj,  educating 
1000  children  ;  aid  being  at  the  same  time  given  to  other 
educational  institutions  not  belonging  to  the  estate.  Three 
admirable  hospitals  were  kept  up  for  the  use  of  the  tenantry, 
while  assistance  was  also  afforded  to  six  charitable  dispensaries 
in  various  places  near.  Above  all,  both  the  Maharaja  and  his 
brother  had  received  a  thorough  English  education,  were  pro- 
ficient in  manly  exercises,  and  free  from  the  vices  which  are 
too  often  the  ruin  of  native  magnates.  The  Maharaja  had  been 
trained  to  manage  his  own  affairs,  and  to  take  a  lively  interest 
in  the  welfare  of  his  people,  while  his  brother  had  been  deemed 

1  Saranor  Sarai  (P.)  is  a  public  terms  used  to  indicate  the  private 

inn  or  resting-place.  or  home  farm  of  the  landlord  :  it  is 

*  Zirat  (zira'at  A.)  means  'cul-  practically  equivalent  to  nij  or  nij- 

tivation,'  and  is  one  of  the  several  jot,  or  kamat  or  khamar  land. 


698  LAND   SYSTEMS   OP   BRITISH   INDIA.         [BOOK  n. 

fit  for  appointment  to  the  civil  service  of  the  province,  in  which 
he  is  now  an  Assistant  Magistrate. 

'  During  the  incumbency  of  the  Court  of  Wards,  the  aggregate 
demand  of  rent  due  to  the  estate  amounted  to  E.  4, 26,79,578. 
Of  this,  E.  3,54,66,458,  or  83  per  cent.,  were  collected,  and 
E.  55,39,610  remitted.  The  total  receipts  from  all  sources 
during  the  management  were  E.  4,84,50,669,  and  the  total  dis- 
bursements E. 4,80,86,228,  of  which  E. 32,90,934,  or  only  6 
per  cent,  of  the  receipts  represents  the  cost  of  management. 
E.  80,41,113  were  expended  in  payment  of  Government  reve- 
nue, and  E.  31,98,000,  or  6  per  cent,  of  the  receipts  in  the 
allowances  of  the  family,  including  social  and  religious  cere- 
monies. The  collection  of  rent  was  on  several  occasions  during 
the  management  seriously  affected  by  drought  and  scarcity. 
These  calamities  serve  to  explain  the  heavy  remissions  of  rent 
shown  in  the  accounts.  The  total  expenditure  on  public  works 
from  first  to  last  was  E.  54,92,245.' 


SECTION  VII. — OTHER  BKANCHES  OF  KEVENUE-DUTY. 

There  are  other  branches  of  a  revenue  officer's  duty 
which  occupy  a  considerable  space  in  the  Revenue  manuals. 
It  is  not  within  the  scope  of  this  work  to  deal  with  these 
branches ;  they  are  all  fully  provided  for  by  special  Acts 
and  by  Revenue  Rules. 

As  an  example  I  may  instance  the  question  of  agricul- 
tural loans  (Act  XII  of  1884),  the  rules  for  'Taqavi,'  or 
advances  made  for  land  improvements  (Act  XIX  of  1883). 

The  road  cess  assessment  and  collection  under  Bengal 
Act  IX  of  1880,  to  which  incidental  allusion  has  already 
been  made,  forms,  in  Bengal,  another  special  branch  of  a 
revenue  officer's  duty.  In  other  provinces,  as  a  rule,  a  cess 
for  the  same  purposes  is  assessed  along  with  the  land-reve- 
nue, and  is  collected  at  the  same  time  and  by  the  same 
process.  In  Bengal,  the  arrangements  of  the  Permanent 
Settlement  did  not  include  this,  and  therefore  an  Act  was 
required,  which  makes  not  only  estates,  but  every  kind  of 
tenure  and  cultivating  holding,  liable  to  pay  a  small  con- 
tribution to  the  maintenance  of  a  fund  for  roads  and 


CHAP.  VI.]    LAND-REVENUE  BUSINESS  AND  PROCEDURE.      699 

communications.  (There  is  a  Cess  Manual,  1888,  issued  by 
the  Board  which  gives  all  the  rules.) 

The  acquisition  of  lands  for  public  purposes  under  Act  X 
of  1870  is  practically  a  branch  of  revenue  duty,  as  it  is 
the  Collector  who  makes  the  first  award  of  compensation  ; 
moreover,  when  the  land  is  expropriated  the  revenue  on  it 
has  to  be  remitted,  so  that  the  '  taujih '  department  is  also 
concerned. 

Full  instructions  regarding  the  form  of  submitting  a  pro- 
posal to  expropriate  lands,  and  other  details  of  procedure, 
are  to  be  found  in  the  Board's  Rules ;  a  reference  to  these 
and  to  the  Act  X  of  1870  will  make  the  whole  matter  clear. 
Further  detail  here  is  not  required. 

The  Waste  Land  Rules  have  also  a  great  importance  in 
Bengal,  as  there  are  still  lands  available,  about  Darjiling, 
and  in  the  Sundarbans.  I  have  already  given  some  account 
of  the  working  of  these  Rules,  as  far  as  the  tenures  result- 
ing from  them  are  concerned l.  I  have  here  only  to  add 
that  some  revised  rules  were  issued  in  1888 ;  and  that  the 
whole  subject  is  now  to  be  studied  in  the  Waste  Land 
Manual,  1888. 

1  See   p.  479,  ante. 


END   OF   VOL.   I. 


HD  875  .83  1892  v.l  SMC 

Baden-Powell.  B.  H. 

The.  land  systems  of  British 

India