Liberal democracy: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
m I added more information about social media's negative influence in society when political information is either incorrect or heavily controlled by some countries' governments
Yobot (talk | contribs)
m References after punctuation per WP:REFPUNCT, WP:CITEFOOT, WP:PAIC + other fixes
Line 91:
The bourgeois class becomes wealthy through a drive to appropriate the [[surplus value|surplus-value]] of the creative labours of the working class. This drive obliges the bourgeois class to amass ever-larger fortunes by increasing the proportion of surplus-value by exploiting the working class through capping workers' terms and conditions as close to poverty levels as possible. Incidentally, this obligation demonstrates the clear limit to bourgeois freedom even for the bourgeoisie itself. Thus, according to Marx parliamentary elections are no more than a cynical, systemic attempt to deceive the people by permitting them, every now and again, to endorse one or other of the bourgeoisie's predetermined choices of which political party can best advocate the interests of capital. Once elected, this parliament, as a dictatorship of the bourgeoisie, enacts regulations that actively support the interests of its true constituency, the bourgeoisie (such as bailing out Wall St investment banks; direct socialisation/subsidisation of business—GMH, US/European [[agricultural subsidy|agricultural subsidies]]; and even wars to guarantee trade in commodities such as oil).
 
[[Vladimir Lenin]] once argued that liberal democracy had simply been used to give an illusion of democracy while maintaining the dictatorship of the [[bourgeoisie]].{{cncitation needed|date=November 2020}}
 
====Campaign costs====
Line 99:
The cost of political campaigning in representative democracies favors the rich, a form of [[plutocracy]] where only a very small number of wealthy individuals can actually affect government policy in their favor and toward [[plutonomy]].<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Draper|first1=Hal|title=Marx on Democratic Forms of Government|date=1974|journal=The Socialist Register|volume=11|url=https://socialistregister.com/index.php/srv/article/view/5326/2227|access-date=22 October 2018|archive-date=5 August 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190805130248/https://socialistregister.com/index.php/srv/article/view/5326/2227|url-status=live}}</ref>
 
Other studies predicted that the global trend toward [[plutonomy|plutonomies]] would continue, for various reasons, including "capitalist-friendly governments and tax regimes".<ref> Kapur, Ajay, Niall Macleod, Narendra Singh: "Plutonomy: Buying Luxury, Explaining Global Imbalances", Citigroup, Equity Strategy, Industry Note: October 16, 2005. p. 9f.</ref> They do, however, also warn of the risk that, since "political enfranchisement remains as was—one person, one vote, at some point it is likely that labor will fight back against the rising profit share of the rich and there will be a political backlash against the rising wealth of the rich."<ref> Kapur, Ajay, Niall Macleod, Narendra Singh: "Revisiting Plutonomy: The Rich Getting Richer", Citigroup, Equity Strategy, Industry Note: March 5, 2006. p. 10.</ref>
 
Liberal democracy has also been attacked by some [[Democratic socialism|socialists]]<ref>{{cite journal|title=Democracy|journal=Left Party in Germany|url=https://www.linksfraktion.de/themen/a-z/detailansicht/demokratie/|access-date=15 December 2017|archive-date=16 December 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171216091214/https://www.linksfraktion.de/themen/a-z/detailansicht/demokratie/|url-status=live}}</ref> as a dishonest farce used to keep the masses from realizing that their will is irrelevant in the political process. Stringent [[Campaign finance reform|campaign finance laws]] can correct this perceived problem.
Line 108:
However, Levitt's response were also criticised as they miss the socialist point of view, which is that citizens who have little to no money at all are blocked from political office entirely. This argument is not refuted merely by noting that either doubling or halving of electoral spending will only shift a given candidate's chances of winning by 1 percent.<ref>{{cite web|last1=Mandle|first1=Jay|title=How Freakonomics Gets Campaign Financing Wrong, January 2006|url=http://www.democracymatters.org/money-on-my-mind-2/how-freakonomics-gets-campaign-financing-wrong/|access-date=15 December 2017|archive-date=16 December 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171216034534/http://www.democracymatters.org/money-on-my-mind-2/how-freakonomics-gets-campaign-financing-wrong/|url-status=live}}</ref>
 
On September 18, 2014, Martin Gilens and Benjamin I. Page's study concluded "Multivariate analysis indicates that economic elites and organized groups representing business interests have substantial independent impacts on U.S. government policy, while average citizens and mass-based interest groups have little or no independent influence. The results provide substantial support for theories of Economic-Elite Domination and for theories of Biased Pluralism, but not for theories of Majoritarian Electoral Democracy or Majoritarian Pluralism."<ref>Gilens, M., & Page, B. (2014). Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens. Perspectives on Politics, 12(3), 564–81. {{doi|10.1017/S1537592714001595}}</ref>
 
====Authoritarianism====
Line 115:
 
=== Media ===
Critics of the role of the media in liberal democracies allege that [[concentration of media ownership]] leads to major distortions of democratic processes. In ''[[Manufacturing Consent: The Political Economy of the Mass Media]]'', [[Edward S. Herman]] and [[Noam Chomsky]] argue via their [[Propaganda Model]]<ref>Edward S. Herman [http://www.chomsky.info/onchomsky/199607--.htm "The Propaganda Model Revisited"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120106195120/http://www.chomsky.info/onchomsky/199607--.htm |date=6 January 2012 }}, ''Monthly Review'', July 1996, as reproduced on the Chomsky.info website</ref> that the corporate media limits the availability of contesting views and assert this creates a narrow spectrum of elite opinion. This is a natural consequence, they say, of the close ties between powerful [[corporation]]s and the media and thus limited and restricted to the explicit views of those who can afford it.<ref>James Curran and [[Jean Seaton]] ''[[Power Without Responsibility: the Press and Broadcasting in Britain]]'', London: Routledge, 1997, p. 1</ref>. Furthermore, the media's negative influence can be seen in social media where vast numbers of individuals seek their political information which is not always correct and may be controlled. For example, as of 2017, two-thirds (67%) of Americans report that they get at least some of their news from social media,<ref>{{Cite web|last=Shearer|first=Elisa|last2=Gottfried|first2=Jeffrey|date=2017-09-07|title=News Use Across Social Media Platforms 2017|url=https://www.journalism.org/2017/09/07/news-use-across-social-media-platforms-2017/|access-date=2021-01-14|website=Pew Research Center's Journalism Project|language=en-US}}</ref>, as well as a rising number of countries are exercising extreme control over the flow of information.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Chapman|first=Terri|date=2019-10-27|title=Liberal democracy is under threat from digitisation as govts, tech firms gain more power|url=https://theprint.in/opinion/liberal-democracy-is-under-threat-from-digitisation-as-govts-tech-firms-gain-more-power/312081/|access-date=2021-01-14|website=ThePrint|language=en-US}}</ref>. This may contribute to large numbers of individuals using social media platforms but not always gaining correct political information. This may cause conflict with liberal democracy and some of its core principles, such as freedom, if individuals are not entirely free since their governments are seizing that level of control on media sites
 
Media commentators also point out that the influential early champions of the media industry held fundamentally anti-democratic views, opposing the general population's involvement in creating policy.<ref>Noam Chomsky and Gabor Steingart [http://www.chomsky.info/interviews/20081010.htm "The United States Has Essentially a One-Party System"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100128113437/http://www.chomsky.info/interviews/20081010.htm |date=28 January 2010 }}, ''Der Spiegel Online'', 10 October 2008, as reproduced on the Chomsky.info website</ref> [[Walter Lippmann]] writing in ''[[The Phantom Public]]'' (1925) sought to "put the public in its place" so that those in power would be "free of the trampling and roar of a bewildered herd"<ref>Lippmann cited by Henry Beissel [http://thehumananimal.com/usa/?p=381 "Mutation or Demise: The Democratization of Democracy"] ''Living with Democracy'', #155, Winter 2005, as reproduced on the ''Humanist Persrpectives'' website</ref> while [[Edward Bernays]], originator of public relations, sought to "regiment the public mind every bit as much as an army regiments their bodies".<ref>[http://www.historyisaweapon.com/defcon1/bernprop.html Propaganda by Edward Bernays (1928)] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100319141306/http://www.historyisaweapon.com/defcon1/bernprop.html |date=19 March 2010 }}. Historyisaweapon.com. Retrieved on 2010-09-29.</ref>
Line 178:
The political stability of liberal democracies depends on strong economic growth, as well as robust state institutions that guarantee free elections, the [[rule of law]], and individual liberties.<ref>{{cite journal|doi=10.1146/annurev-polisci-052918-012050|title=Democratic Stability: A Long View|year=2020|last1=Carugati|first1=Federica|journal=Annual Review of Political Science|volume=23|pages=59–75|doi-access=free}}</ref>
 
One argument for democracy is that by creating a system where the public can remove administrations, without changing the legal basis for government, democracy aims at reducing political uncertainty and instability and assuring citizens that however much they may disagree with present policies, they will be given a regular chance to change those who are in power, or change policies with which they disagree. This is preferable to a system where political change takes place through violence.{{cncitation needed|date=June 2020}}
 
One notable feature of liberal democracies is that their opponents (those groups who wish to abolish liberal democracy) rarely win elections. Advocates use this as an argument to support their view that liberal democracy is inherently stable and can usually only be overthrown by external force, while opponents argue that the system is inherently stacked against them despite its claims to impartiality. In the past, it was feared that democracy could be easily exploited by leaders with dictatorial aspirations, who could get themselves elected into power. However, the actual number of liberal democracies that have elected dictators into power is low. When it has occurred, it is usually after a major crisis has caused many people to doubt the system or in young/poorly functioning democracies. Some possible examples include [[Adolf Hitler]] during the [[Great Depression]] and [[Napoleon III]], who became first President of the [[Second French Republic]] and later Emperor.{{cncitation needed|date=June 2020}}
 
=== Effective response in wartime ===
Line 231:
=== Democratic peace theory ===
{{main|Democratic peace theory}}
Numerous studies using many different kinds of data, definitions and statistical analyses have found support for the democratic peace theory.{{citation needed|date=August 2016}} The original finding was that liberal democracies have never made war with one another. More recent research has extended the theory and finds that democracies have few [[militarized interstate dispute]]s causing less than 1,000 battle deaths with one another, that those militarized interstate disputes that have occurred between democracies have caused few deaths and that democracies have few [[civil wars]].<ref>{{cite journal |author=Hegre, Håvard, Tanja Ellington, Scott Gates, and Nils Petter Gleditsch |title=Towards A Democratic Civil Peace? Opportunity, Grievance, and Civil War 1816–1992 |journal=American Political Science Review |year=2001 |volume=95 |pages=33–48 |url=http://www.worldbank.org/research/conflict/papers/peace.htm |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060209113811/http://www.worldbank.org/research/conflict/papers/peace.htm |archive-date=9 February 2006 |doi=10.1017/s0003055401000119}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=Ray, James Lee |title=A Lakatosian View of the Democratic Peace Research Program From Progress in International Relations Theory, edited by Colin and Miriam Fendius Elman |url=http://sitemason.vanderbilt.edu/files/g/gDf5Ty/6%20ray%20demo%20peace%20FIRST%20PROOFS.pdf |publisher=MIT Press |year=2003 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060625203811/http://sitemason.vanderbilt.edu/files/g/gDf5Ty/6%20ray%20demo%20peace%20FIRST%20PROOFS.pdf |archive-date=25 June 2006 }}</ref> There are various criticisms of the theory, including at least as many refutations as alleged proofs of the theory, some 200 deviant cases, failure to treat "democracy" as a multidimensional concept and that correlation is not causation.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Haas |first1=Michael |title=Deconstructing the "democratic peace" : how a research agenda boomeranged |publisher=Publishinghouse for Scholars |location=Los Angeles, CA |isbn=9780983962625}}</ref>{{page? needed|date=January 2021}}
 
=== Minimises political violence ===