Economics Join our invited guests to debate economics
The question is:

Was the Fed right to do QE2?

Nov 19th 2010 by CT1792 | The Economist

The Federal Reserve recently announced a plan to purchase an additional $600 billion in Treasury securities, citing the need to address an inflation rate below the level it deems "consistent, over the longer run, with its dual mandate". Has the Fed made the correct policy decision? Has it adequately taken into account potential risks, and what should it have done, if not this?

Guest contributions: 
11
Viral Acharya wrote on Nov 19th 2010, 14:33 GMT

I REMAIN concerned about the opportunity cost of Fed actions. During the crisis, excessive reliance on liquidity injections helped the Treasury delay the inevitable recapitalisation of banks. I wonder if the Fed going down the path of QE2 similarly prevents a stronger fiscal action through recapitalisation of households (principal write-downs, as I commented earlier on in this forum), stronger unemployment insurance and more growth-friendly stimulus.

Of course, other costs such as the possibility of dislocations and bubble formation elsewhere make the costs even higher. Is there substantial gain from the underlying risks of QE2? On the other hand, QE2 is not as large as it might have been, unless its just the beginning of more QEs to follow.

Yang Yao wrote on Nov 19th 2010, 16:00 GMT

IT IS not certain that the Fed’s QE2 is going to boost American consumption and investment. Consumers are not sensitive to interest rates when they plan daily consumption. In this time of severe recession, they may also not respond to low interest rates by buying more houses or cars. Firms are more sensitive than consumers to interest rate changes, but the slow growth of demand can delay their willingness to invest domestically. In the end, excessive liquidity will flow to other countries where real demand growth and asset values are more robust, putting pressure on those countries.

Stephen King wrote on Nov 19th 2010, 16:02 GMT

QUANTITATIVE easing is being pursued because central banks have run out of conventional weaponry and they don't want to admit they've lost their powers. It is the equivalent of waving a magic wand and sprinkling some fairy dust onto the economy. In other words, it requires a leap of faith.

Michael Bordo wrote on Nov 19th 2010, 16:05 GMT

THE Fed may be on thin ice with its recent quantitative easing. The stated reasons for the programme have been that inflation is too low and bordering on the risk of deflation, and unemployment is too high. The fear of deflation is as overblown as it was from 2002-2005. If the Fed is following a credible nominal anchor then it shouldn't fear a temporary bout of falling prices because the public would understand that it is only temporary. Furthermore, having low inflation may be an opportunity for the Fed to start a price-level targeting regime. The high unemployment rate is the real reason why the Fed has followed its strategy just as it did in the previous two jobless recoveries. It is unclear the extent to which the elevated level of unemployment reflects a shortage of aggregate demand or problems on the supply side such as the extension of unemployment benefits, the problems in the housing market that make it difficult for people to move and other structural problems.

Scott Sumner wrote on Nov 22nd 2010, 14:02 GMT

THERE has been a great deal of misleading commentary about the recent Fed decision to inject another $600 billion in reserves into the banking system. Much of it is based on people inappropriately applying monetarist models that were constructed to evaluate permanent changes in non-interest bearing base money. The new injections are probably not permanent and the reserves are interest-bearing, which eliminates the so-called “hot potato” mechanism by which excess cash balances can cause inflation.


Laurence Kotlikoff wrote on Nov 22nd 2010, 16:19 GMT

WITH QE2, the Fed is on the path of quadrupling the monetary base relative to its 2007 value. If the banks decide to lend out their excess reserves, M1 and M2 could quadruple relative to their 2007 levels, leading the price level to rise by a factor of four, i.e., we could see hyperinflation.


Now this would have some advantages.

Richard Koo wrote on Nov 23rd 2010, 14:16 GMT

QUANTITATIVE easing has no reason to work in an economy where the private sector is deleveraging even at zero interest rates in order to repair its battered balance sheets following the bursting of an asset price bubble. In both the US and UK, private sectors are continuing to minimize debt instead of maximizing profits in what may be called balance sheet recession. With both borrowers and lenders’ balance sheets under water or nearly so, both groups are unable to respond to monetary signals coming out of the central bank. Moreover, when the private sector is paying down debt, the money multiplier is negative at margin, meaning that additional liquidity in the system cannot enter the real economy to become part of its money supply. Indeed the Fed chairman Bernanke admitted in his Washington Post article on Nov. 4th that the QE 1 failed to increase currency in circulation or the rate of inflation. The same outcome was observed in Japan between 2001 and 2006 when a similar policy was tried. The portfolio rebalancing effect of the central bank purchases of government bonds may make the basically ineffective policy work infinitesimally better. But if the Japanese example is any guide, that effect is minuscule, if any, and is far from sufficient to turn the economy around.

Guillermo Calvo wrote on Nov 29th 2010, 15:58 GMT

AS I see it, the subprime crisis started as a run on shadow banks, which troyed much of the liquidity of financial instruments supported by shadow banking. This lowered their price and cut credit lines to activities supported by those instruments. In particular, the meltdown of mortgage-backed securities led to a significant decline in mortgage supply, resulting in a collapse of real estate prices, and massive wealth loss in the household sector. This depressed consumption and put a downward pressure on the stock market. Wealth loss also hit financial intermediaries, forcing them to recapitalize and lower their exposure to risky assets. This helped to spread the credit crunch across other sectors not directly exposed to shadow banking activities, further depressing the stock market. In the US, in particular, this gave rise to over-indebtedness and loss of credit access by households, small firms and State governments, a subset of the US economy that I am tempted to call "Emerging US" (E-US).

In contrast, however, "Advanced US" (A-US), composed of large corporations and the US Federal government, is awash with liquidity and can borrow at negligible interest rates. Can growth be spearheaded by A-US? A serious problem is that since E-US is unwilling or unable to spend and, as a result, A-US has no incentive to invest, unless exports are expected to increase at a high rate. Advanced economies are running into problems that are as serious as those in the US, so they are not a promising outlet of US exports. Emerging market economies (EMs), on the other hand, are a better bet but, as I will argue below, they have reasons to be leery about a sharp increase in imports driven by a surge of capital inflows.

Stephen Roach wrote on Nov 29th 2010, 16:02 GMT

THE problem is less with the Fed and more the dual mandate, itself. At low levels of inflation and nominal interest rates, “mandate-deficient growth” – today’s new buzzword – requires additional central bank easing. With US unemployment far too high and inflation now too low, the US central bank has little choice in the context of legally binding requirements. Out of basis points, the Fed has no ammunition on the price dimension of its standard policy tool. Ergo, the push on the quantity side.

Jean Pisani-Ferry wrote on Nov 29th 2010, 16:04 GMT

WHATEVER the US domestic debate, the rest of the world is highly doubtful about QE2. The Europeans have been especially vocal but many in the emerging world are also fearful of its consequences. The question is, can QE2 be characterised as beggar-thy-neighbour?

Advertisement

Advertisement

Products & events
Stay informed today and every day

Subscribe to The Economist's free e-mail newsletters and alerts.


Subscribe to The Economist's latest article postings on Twitter


See a selection of The Economist's articles, events, topical videos and debates on Facebook.

Advertisement