American politics

Democracy in America

  • Phoning it in

    The magic of Bob Herbert

    Feb 16th 2011, 20:20 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    I READ this Bob Herbert column first with incredulity. "As the throngs celebrated in Cairo," Mr Herbert begins, "I couldn’t help wondering about what is happening to democracy here in the United States." Because, really, nothing on Earth is so important that it should keep our minds turning immediately to the only subject that really matters: us. Thus, when we encounter the first exhilarating steps of an oppressed people struggling toward popular self-rule, we simply can't help wondering about democracy here in the US of A.

    Then I read it again, with annoyance. Mr Herbert wanted to say that American democracy is broken because it's been hijacked by the rich. This is one of approximately five columns liberal pundits phone in when they are uninspired or feeling lazy. Not that you can sleepwalk through a phone-in! Oh, there's work to do. First, you've got to find a piping hot news hook. This can be accomplished by staring at the headlines until you run across a word that also appears in one of your ready-made gotta-get-to-brunch op-ed templates. So, let's see... Egyptians have cast out a dictator in hopes of one day establishing a democracy. Democracy! Rich people have hijacked our democracy! Then it's just a matter of peppering the thing with au courant Pavlovian keywords: "corporate stranglehold", "Citizens United decision", "Koch brothers". Finally, one must summon the energy to loop back to the hook. "The Egyptians want to establish a viable democracy, and that’s a long, hard road. Americans are in the mind-bogglingly self-destructive process of letting a real democracy slip away." Boom! This is is how they do it in the bigs, folks. 

    None of this is to say that worries similar to Mr Herbert's about the undue influence of money in politics are unworthy of a careful substantive response. I started this post intending to offer such a response. It just turns out that this particular column's paint-by-numbers roteness slaps you in the face so hard that I couldn't help concluding it doesn't merit one. 

  • Climate change

    Americans and global warming, continued

    Feb 16th 2011, 17:59 by E.G. | AUSTIN

    AS A follow-up to last week's post wondering why Americans don't care about global warming, I wanted to mention a few things drawn from the comments and elsewhere around the web.

    One theme from commenters was that they're not concerned about climate change because they don't believe in climate change. This is exactly the view that infuriates some people who do believe in climate change. However, let's keep in mind that there's a lot of variation within the group of climate-change sceptics. Similarly, as Matt Ridley points out on his blog, to the extent that there's a consensus about climate change, it's a consensus that admits to differing views about the likely causes and consequences. As the Intergovernmental Panel for Climate Change put it, for example: "Most of the observed increase in global average temperatures since the mid-20th century is very likely due to the observed increase in anthropogenic greenhouse gas concentrations." (Emphasis from Mr Ridley.)

    A related concern was the politicisation of scientists. As commenter RestrainedRadical pointed out, most of the prominent climate hawks are Democrats. On its face, that looks awfully political, although there may be a causal confusion (if people who care about the environment become Democrats). The New York Times had an article last week about a conference for social psychologists in San Antonio, where Jonathan Haidt of the University of Virginia, based on a show of hands in a ballroom, estimated that 80% of the people in the room were liberals:

    “This is a statistically impossible lack of diversity,” Dr. Haidt concluded, noting polls showing that 40 percent of Americans are conservative and 20 percent are liberal. In his speech and in an interview, Dr. Haidt argued that social psychologists are a “tribal-moral community” united by “sacred values” that hinder research and damage their credibility—and blind them to the hostile climate they’ve created for non-liberals.

    He was talking about social psychologists in particular—a group that we would assume would be more interested in squishy issues than a random sample of Americans—but other academics have found that university professors are overwhelmingly Democratic. It's pretty interesting to think about the possible reasons for that—and maybe it's a discussion we can have in the future on this blog—but for the current context, let's just note that sceptics aren't being unreasonable to suspect some bias.

    This doesn't mean that people should give up worrying about climate change, but it does suggest that the issue is overly polarised between the believers and the sceptics. Some commenters had the provocative thought that environmentalists should emphasise the effect (climate change) rather than the cause (anthropogenic). I was mulling this before the first post; in the Rasmussen poll linked there, there's a segment of people who believe in climate change but not that it's man-made. Presumably they would be particularly prone to dropping out of the debate if the emphasis on anthropogenic climate change discredits scientists in their eyes. However, if climate change is indeed caused by human behaviour, then it could be important to bring that forward, as slowing climate change would likely necessitate changing human behaviour. Any more thoughts on that?

    Moving on, the World Bank has a cross-country poll of views on climate change. Their results for the United States roughly correspond to Rasmussen's, and do show Americans being less exercised about climate change than other countries. The poll also suggests a logical inverse relationship between levels of carbon emissions and levels of concern over the environment. On particularly American issues, Tzimisces was the first commenter to pull out an assumption implicit in the idea that America is more committed to heavy carbon use than most states—that America has a car culture most states do not. Tzi points out that cars are a symbol of freedom and autonomy, and that they're the only viable mode of transportation for a lot of working people. "Why don't Americans care about public transport?" is another question, one answer to which is that America's physical size and settlement patterns make public transportation an implausible way to commute in all but the densest metro areas. The United States also has a structural issue that affects its international participation, which is that the Senate has to approve international treaties by a two-thirds vote.

    Following on from that, note that the original post, "Why don't Americans care about global warming?" is one of the most-discussed items on the entire website this week, a category typically filled with major news stories and caption contests. This suggests an additional question: "Why do people care so much about why Americans don't care about global warming?" A few possible answers suggest themselves—maybe people love a chance to pick on America—but the most plausible is that people care about America's views on the issue because, as I suggested in the earlier post, America is big enough that its involvement may be necessary for a global fight against climate change. This is a dynamic that persists in other issues and suggests a hypothesis: hegemonic states are prone to lag on collective-action problems, because other states value their activity more highly than they do. For a different take on global leadership, or the lack thereof, see Nouriel Roubini, writing today in Slate.

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Picturing politics

    Sumner's wheel of ideology

    Feb 16th 2011, 14:13 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    SCOTT SUMNER isn't just one of the internet's finest economic commentators. He's also a crack gentleman amateur political theorist. In a recent post, Mr Sumner offers a fresh and intriguing political typology. Behold:

    Scott Sumner's political typology

    And here's how Mr Sumner describes his classificatory scheme:

    My goal here is to set things up in such a way that each group has a values affinity to those on one side, and an ideological affinity to those on the other side. So you could circle any two adjoining groups, and describe a common feature:

    1.  Progressives/Pragmatic libertarians:  Both tend to be secular utilitarians, or at least consequentialists

    2.  Pragmatic and dogmatic libertarians:  Both favor very small government

    3.  Dogmatic libertarians and idealistic conservatives:  Both are nostalgic for the past, and revere the (original intent of) the Constitution.

    4.  Idealistic conservatives and corrupt Republicans:  Both are Republicans.

    5.  Corrupt Republicans and corrupt Dems:  Both believe in realpolitik, are disdainful of fuzzy-headed, idealistic intellectuals.

    6.  Corrupt Democrats and idealistic progressives:  Both are Democrats

    Thus on values there are three pairings:  utilitarian, natural rights, and selfish.  On ideology there are three different pairings:  Democrat, Republican and libertarian.

    By "corrupt", Mr Sumner means politicians and pundits who prioritise the interests of the pressure groups within their party's politcal coalition over their publicly-espoused ideals. (How can you implement your ideals if you don't win elections!) I would suggest Mr Sumner include among the corrupt those who, through flights of wishful thinking, are able to convince themselves that their conservative or progressive principles conveniently align almost perfectly with the clientele of the Republican or Democratic Party.

    I find Mr Sumner's typology quite congenial probably because I have Mr Sumner's politics, more or less, and his way of carving up the ideological space places us where we see ourselves: as "pragmatic libertarians" leaning a bit more toward "progressive idealism" than "dogmatic libertarianism". That said, there is something troubling about the lack of parallelism in Mr Sumner's scheme. While conservatism and progressivism both have "idealistic" and "corrupt" variants, libertarianism is only "dogmatic" and "pragmatic". I think the ideological influence but electoral insignificance of libertarianism goes some way toward justifying its different treatment. But I wouldn't want to leave out the possibility of conservatism and progressivism that is pragmatic in the sense of pursuing conservative and progressive values through practical, empirically-tested means, and not in the "corrupt" sense of catering to the electoral interests of a partisan faction.

    Indeed, Mr Sumner argues that policy-minded intellectuals of all ideological stripes have arrived at rough consensus on a number of issues ranging from occupational licensing to urban policy, but I don't think we'd want to say that this makes the conservatives and progressives among them honorary pragmatic libertarians. Mr Sumner's illuminating diagram would make more sense to me if it made room for pragmatic but non-corrupt, non-idealistic conservatives and progressives. Maybe somebody can figure out how to draw that.

  • Family and the state

    The underlying moral logic

    Feb 15th 2011, 21:52 by E.G. | AUSTIN

    LAST month our Bagehot columnist flagged a new paper that the Nordic governments were set to present at Davos, on "The Nordic Way". Among the interesting arguments in the paper is an analysis of Nordic individualism:

    While much has been written about the institutionalized aspects of the Nordic welfare state, few have paid much attention to the underlying moral logic. Though the path hasn't always been straight, one can discern over the course of the twentieth century an overarching ambition in the Nordic countries not to socialize the economy but to liberate the individual citizen from all forms of subordination and dependency within the family and in civil society: the poor from charity, the workers from their employers, wives from their husbands, children from their parents—and vice versa when the parents become elderly.

    The paper posits a triangle, with the family, the individual, and the state in the corners, and argues that the Nordic countries prioritise a different dynamic than Germany or the United States. As Bagehot summarises:

    Americans favour a Family-Individual axis, this suggests, suspecting the state as a threat to liberty. Germans revere an axis connecting the family and the state, with a smaller role for individual autonomy. In the Nordic countries, they argue, the state and the individual form the dominant alliance. The paper cited, by the way, is entitled: "Pippi Longstocking: The Autonomous Child and the Moral Logic of the Swedish Welfare State". It hails Pippi (the strongest girl in the world and an anarchic individualist who lives without parents in her own house, with only a monkey, horse, a bag of gold and a strong moral compass for company) as a Nordic archetype.

    This framework provides a way to think about how Americans think about the state. My colleague notes below that America has an exceptionally small government, and that the reasons may be historical, cultural, or institutional, or all of the above, and that the causal connections reinforcing the small-state approach would be difficult to untangle. Whatever the causes of America's underlying moral logic, though, it's interesting to think how this plays out today. It makes sense that if America posits a strong family-individual axis—as a hedge in the absence of state support, if not in opposition to it—that Americans would be more preoccupied with issues that pertain to individuals and the family, and would drag those issues into the political realm. (This new bill from South Dakota, however, which would make it a "justifiable homicide" if you kill someone to prevent them from killing a fetus, is taking it rather far.)

  • Obama's budget

    Keeping the olds

    Feb 15th 2011, 19:35 by E.G. | AUSTIN

    EVERY so often I get a document from the Social Security Administration in a green-edged envelope, and I open it straight away, thinking it might be important. Instead, I find that it's just a statement of my Social Security earnings and future benefits, a concept so absurd that I immediately recognise it for fiction. The last time it happened, I paused over the form, looking at the taxes I've paid in the past 15 years, remembering the thousands of hours when I earned that money: the awful uniforms, the long stretches of standing, the Cher songs on loop (and that was just at The Economist's DC office). If I stopped working now, this document says, I would receive a couple thousand dollars a month in benefits at whatever age it is they suggest I retire, something I obviously do not expect to ever be able to do.

    So I'm sympathetic to Matt Yglesias's argument that it's "politically and morally vital" that any cuts to Social Security or Medicare should affect current beneficiaries as well as us future ones, and to Andrew Sullivan's complaint that Barack Obama's FY2012 budget proposal, which proposes no serious intervention in entitlements, "has betrayed those of us who took him to be a serious president prepared to put the good of the country before his short term political interests." Clearly America will have a better chance of taming its monster deficit if it could muster the energy to change an entitlement policy that was established when life expectancies and career trajectories were much different than they are now. That may be more important than our intuitions about fairness. But the intuitions about fairness are politically powerful, and the idea that you can change the rules of the game so late in the game violates some fundamental feeling on the subject. Current beneficiaries are going to fight any such proposal just as hard as anyone would expect.

    I would expect any changes to Social Security benefits to be written to affect future beneficiaries only. In terms of entitlement benefits, their (our) sense of fair treatment is less fully developed. Young people are more likely to accept that this pyramid scheme is bound to fall apart eventually. Politicians have to pounce before they start to think about their long years of work and before they start to believe the claims that are made in those Social Security letters about what they can expect in their old age. It's a generational injustice, as Mr Sullivan puts it, but if the political constraint is as it seems—that the people who are the current beneficiaries are going to balk like mules—then the generational injustice is inevitable, and it's better to take that hit sooner rather than later.

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • America the not-so-weird

    How exceptional is America, really?

    Feb 15th 2011, 15:34 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    IN AN unjustly overlooked series of posts on the unjustly neglected Pileus blog, Jason Sorens, a professor of political science at the University at Buffalo, casts a sceptical eye on the common assumption that the United States is an unusual or "exceptional" country. According to Mr Sorens, America is not exceptionally free, American government is not exceptionally small, and that American inequality is not exceptionally high.  

    Americans take pride in standing as the beacon of freedom unto the world. And America is pretty free. However, as Mr Sorens observes, it's beacon is not exceptionally bright. America comes in sixth in the Fraser Institute's 2010 "Economic Freedom of the World" rankings, between Chile and Canada. Mr Sorens doesn't mention it, but matters look worse if we look at the Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal's "2011 Index of Economic Freedom", which ranks America ninth, just behind Denmark and well behind our frostbitten northern neighbours. It's worse if we move on to non-economic liberties. Mr Sorens reports that America rates merely average on Amnesty International's government repression index in the period from 2004-2008. One might come to the defence of the city on the hill by noting that America gets top marks in political rights and civil liberties from Freedom House, but then so do scores of other countries. The Freedom House ratings aren't very fine-grained. If you think the extent of liberty is not unrelated to the rule of law, you may be interested in America's place in Transparency International's latest corruption perceptions index. It's 22nd, which isn't bad—better than France!—but not what you'd call exceptional.

    In the second post of his series, Mr Sorens looks at the size of the American state, and finds a strong claim to exceptionalism. American government really is exceptionally small. But does America's relatively small government mean there is something in the American character and culture that especially prizes it? To answer this question, Mr Sorens examines a number of variables associated with government spending as a percentage of GDP. If it turns out that the size of America's government is smaller than would be predicted by the model, it is reasonable to conjecture that the "unexplained variance" is due to a cultural preference for smaller government. After running the numbers, Mr Sorens finds that

    If anything, the U.S. has a slightly bigger government than average, once you control for its economic, religious, and institutional profile. The really parsimonious citizens (on government consumption) are apparently found in Hungary, Ireland, Switzerland, and Japan, while the least egalitarian peoples (on social spending) are Japanese, Slovaks, Icelanders, and Norwegians.

    In summary, there is very little evidence that Americans favor smaller government than Europeans and that that is the reason the American state is small—or if there is some small-government tendency among Americans, it is captured fully by their religious diversity. (Not religiosity, mind. I tested that—no effect.) More religiously diverse countries typically accommodated religious minorities early on or even disestablished their state religions; thus, they have some history of liberalism in this sphere, and that history may account for some of the results found. If the U.S. had French institutions, we’d have something close to their government too.

    This is a bit tricky. Mr Sorens is not saying that America does not have an exceptionally small government when compared to similar countries. It does. He's saying that American exceptionalism in this domain is accounted for not by distinctively American small-government norms, but instead by the long-term effect of a high level of religious diversity on America's institutions. If an evil demon pushed a button that instantly reorganised American institutions along French lines, there is nothing about Americans that would keep them from demanding French levels of government spending. I'm not sure this quite follows. Of course, if a country is exceptional in some respect, there's going to be a reason for it. Mr Sorens' argument seems to suggest that in accounting for our exceptionalism, we are likely to make a culture-wide version of the fundamental attribution error—to assume that our country's proud peculiarity flows from something special about us, as a people, as opposed to a unique external feature of our history that we had nothing to do with, and can't take credit for. But, as Mr Sorens acknowledges, the pathway from religious diversity to small government may be at least partly cultural. In that case, Americans, bearing the imprint of their unique history, might demand less than French levels of government spending even in an institutionally French counterfactual America. Still, Mr Sorens' finding takes some air out of puffed-up exceptionalism.

    The dark side of American exceptionalism is America's allegedly exceptionally high levels of economic inequality. In the final post of his series, Mr Sorens' argues that America should not be compared to similarly wealthy European countries, but instead to countries with a similar history of slavery and the subjugation of natives.

    The U.S. has the least inequality, by a fair margin, of these [formely slaveholding] countries. Of course, the U.S. also has a smaller combined percentage of blacks and Amerindians than all of these other countries except Costa Rica, Chile, Argentina, and Uruguay. But that’s precisely the point—the overriding factor determining inequality in New World countries is the white or mestizo percentage of the population. When you control for that, the U.S. actually has very low inequality.

    If the U.S. is exceptional at all, it is exceptional for its high GDP per capita and low income inequality, relative to similarly situated countries.

    Perhaps American pundits should devote more columns to explaining why it is that America, despite its baleful history of slavery, has managed to keep inequality so low. In addition to the purely demographic factors Mr Soren's points out, my first guess would be that the United States, unlike most other countries in the New World, made it over the hump of the Kuznets curve.

    (Photo credit: Beverly & Pack via Flickr)

  • Obama's budget

    "Friday Night Lights" and FY 2012

    Feb 14th 2011, 23:01 by M.S.

    LAST week "Friday Night Lights" (FNL) aired its last episode, leaving squishy northern liberals like myself with one fewer mode for attempting to appreciate the religious South. Like the show's characters, I grew up with a passionate love of football, but the show's run coincided with a relentless drum of new evidence that football players routinely suffer chronic traumatic encephalopathy from thousands of repetitive collisions, and by the time the last episode aired I was watching it sort of the way one watches boxing pics: a document of the greatness of the human spirit pitted in antiquated contests that should probably be illegal. Also, I was desperately in love with the show, and with half its characters, male and female, but I made a mental reservation for the way it stacked the deck by making its characters' quest to win at football synonymous with their quest to go to college. For some of the show's characters, like Vince Howard, the idea was that football brought discipline and forward perspective to their lives; with it they'd go to college, without it they'd end up in jail. For other characters, like Luke Cafferty, football was supposed to bring them the scholarship they needed to afford college. For others still, like Tim Riggins, it was a bit of both. But the whole football-as-path-to-college thing always seemed like a bit of a cheap trick, a way to defuse liberals' suspicion that high-school football is basically an anti-academic vice indulged by mainly suburban or rural communities to the detriment of their kids' educations. I mean, is college really so unaffordable in America? Surely these kids could have put together the money to attend a state school without a football scholarship?

    While FNL was wrapping up, Louis Lataif (hat tip Derek Thompson) published an article in Forbes proving that I'm a cosseted northern liberal who doesn't know what regular people's lives are like.

    Higher education in America, historically the envy of the world, is rapidly growing out of reach. For the past quarter-century, the cost of higher education has grown 440%, according to the National Center for Public Policy and Education, nearly four times the rate of inflation and double the rate of health care cost increases. The cost increases have occurred at both public and private colleges...

    Just 10 years ago the cost of a four-year public college education amounted to 18% of the annual income of middle-income families. Ten years later, it amounted to 25% of that family's average annual income... Over the past 14 years the average debt for a graduating college student has doubled. Today the loan obligation of graduating seniors is more than $20,000 for public university grads and more than $27,000 for graduates of private universities. More than two-thirds of all college graduates have student loan obligations. The number of graduates in debt increased by 27% over just the past five years. And, not surprisingly, the default rate has grown each year.

    Mr Lataif points out that federal student aid has also doubled over the past ten years, to $120 billion per year, but that this merely fuels rising tuitions. He suggests radical changes in educational delivery, notably using online learning to shorten course length and making the three-year college degree standard. But he also touches on one of the deep sources of rising tuitions: schools spend money to increase their perceived status in the eyes of potential students. It's hardly surprising that in an economy of rising inequality and stagnating middle-class wages, upper-middle-class parents are willing to pay ever-higher premiums for schools that are seen as one of the few guarantors of staying on the upper edges of the income curve. That puts those schools out of reach for less wealthy kids.

    So, with college becoming unaffordable, what are the big educational moves in the FY 2012 budgets proposed by Barack Obama and by congressional Republicans? Well, Barack Obama only wants to eliminate Pell grants for summer tuition, Dave Leonhardt reports. That's not such a huge cut, since the summer tuition grants were new and didn't seem to be improving graduation rates, unlike traditional Pell grants, which do. Meanwhile Republicans, Jonathan Cohn explains, want to make cuts to the entire programme, reducing the maximum grant for 2011 from $5,550 to $4,750, with deeper cuts further out.

    Although House Republicans haven't provided details of their long-term plans for the program, their rhetoric and their existing proposals suggest they would cut Pell Grant funding at least in half. Awards would drop dramatically, starting with this fall's grants, and making it difficult if not impossible for millions of students to attend college...

    Sorry about that, Luke Cafferty. But, while we're busy putting higher education out of reach for America's working class, we're leaving another career option largely unscathed. Our grotesquely bloated military budget will be cut by just $78 billion over the next ten years in the administration's proposal. "Compare [that] to the $400 billion they're cutting from domestic discretionary spending—that's education, income security, food safety, environmental protection, etc.—over the next 10 years," writes Ezra Klein. "And keep in mind that the domestic discretionary budget is only half as large as the military's budget. So if there were equal cuts, the military would be losing $800 billion."

    This may explain why, in the closing shots of that final FNL episode, we see Luke Cafferty getting on a bus, wearing fatigues, having apparently just signed up to serve in the one branch of American government whose budget no politician dares threaten. Smart kid.

  • Egypt's military rule

    A coup for democracy?

    Feb 14th 2011, 19:30 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    EGYPT is now ruled by a gaggle of generals, which may or may not be an improvement upon rule by Hosni Mubarrak. As Daniel Larison of The American Conservative notes:

    It is a measure of how strange the situation has become that many Westerners seem to be celebrating what everyone would otherwise be calling a military coup (which is effectively what it is) as a moment of liberation.

    My sense is that many Westerners were celebrating because masses of Egyptians were celebrating. Perhaps it is a measure of how strange the situation has become that Egyptians have responded with delirious rejoicing to what would otherwise be called a military coup.

    All the same, there are some hopeful signs. The New York Times reports this morning that Egypt's Supreme Military Council has informed certain opposition leaders of their "plan to convene a panel of distinguished jurists to submit a package of constitutional amendments within 10 days for approval in a national referendum within two months, setting a breakneck schedule for the transition to civilian rule." Whether the generals really mean it remains to be seen. But, again, there are reasons for hope. Erik Voeten, a professor of government at Georgetown, points to new research by political scientists Hein Goemans and Nikolay Marinov indicating that post-coup military rulers have become increasingly likely to make the transition to democracy. Here's the abstract from their interesting working paper:

    In this paper, we use new data on coup d'etats and elections to uncover a striking change in what happens after the coup. Whereas the vast majority of successful coups before 1990 installed their leaders durably in power, between 1991 and 2001 the picture reverses, with the majority of coups leading to competitive elections in 5 years or less. We argue that with the end of the Cold War, outside pressure has produced a development we characterize as the "electoral norm"—a requirement that binds successful coup-entrepreneurs to hold reasonably prompt and competitive elections upon gaining power. Consistent with our explanation, we find that post-Cold War those countries that are most dependent on Western aid have been the first the embrace competitive elections after the coup. Our theory is also able to account for the pronounced decline in the non-constitutional seizure of executive power since the early 1990s. While the coup d'etat has been and still is the single most important factor leading to the downfall of democratic government, our findings indicate that the new generation of coups have been considerably less nefarious for democracy than their historical predecessors. 

    What is most captivating here is Messrs Goemans and Marinov's hypothesis that "outside pressure" has helped establish an "electoral norm" to which post-coup military regimes feel at least somewhat bound. Here's a bit more on what they have in mind in this regard: 

    With the end of the Cold War, the West has begun to promote free elections in the rest of the world. While elections have not always been free and fair, nine of every ten countries in the world today hold regular elections that are significantly more competitive than the forms of political contestation most of these countries had before 1990. Furthermore, Western pressure to hold elections has been felt especially strongly by the set of countries most likely to undergo a coup: countries with weak, underdeveloped economies, and with poorly developed or unstable domestic authority structures.

    The authors do not look past 2001, so this study says nothing about the effect of the "democracy promotion" efforts of the United States and its allies, whether truculent or diplomatic, on the development of this "electoral norm". However, the apparently salutary effect of earlier Western pressure to hold democratic elections certainly does suggest the question Lexington explored recently: "Was George Bush right?"

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • A day of joy

    Egypt's euphoria

    Feb 11th 2011, 19:42 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    JUBILATION is catching. It is impossible, for me at least, to watch the crowds in Egypt, overjoyed at Hosni Mubarak's hotly-desired resignation, with dry eyes and an unclenched throat. The best explanation I have heard today for the mass euphoria rippling through Egypt came earlier this morning when one Al Jazeera reporter, choking back sobs, described the rise of Egypt's people and the fall of Egypt's dictator as "everything I've ever hoped for". Everything! Another correspondent, reporting from Alexandria, described Egypt's collective elation as the release of 30 years of bottled-up emotion. He said he had seen birth, that he had seen marriage, but he had never seen happiness like this, and it is everywhere. This is sublimely powerful stuff. It may be the most powerful stuff. 

    I admit that I am more than a little tempted to rain on the parade and note that Mr Mubarak's departure guarantees nothing and that it is not unreasonable to fear a turn for the worse. There's a tiny, stability-loving Burke on my shoulder, and I'm afraid he's no devil. All the same, for now I'm not listening. Well, I did listen a little, but I've heard enough. It is partly due to my Burkean worries that I feel the pessimist in me should just stuff it for now. Whether or not Egypt flowers into a model democracy, whether or not Egyptians tomorrow live more freely than Egyptians today, today they threw off a tyrant. The surge of overwhelming bliss that has overtaken Egyptians is the rare beautitude of democratic will. The hot blush of liberation, a dazzled sense of infinite possibility swelling millions of happy breasts is a precious thing of terrible, unfathomable beauty, and it won't come to these people again. Whatever the future may hold, this is the happiest many people will ever feel. This is the best day of some peoples' lives. The tiny Dionysian anarchist on my other shoulder is no angel, but I cannot deny that there is something holy in this feeling, that it is one of few human experiences that justifies life—that satisfies, however briefly, our desperate craving for more intensity, for more meaning, for more life from life. Whatever the future holds, there will be disappointment, at best. But there is always disappointment. Today, there is joy. 

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Libel and the Redskins

    Hail to the City Paper

    Feb 11th 2011, 14:15 by J.F. | ATLANTA

    daniel snyderLET'S start with some disclosure: I grew up in Washington, DC in the 1980s. DC has always been the strangest American city; in fact, it has never really been much of a city, more an inchoate layering of different cities—the transient political class (elected officials, their staffs) and the permanent political class (remoras attached to the former grouping: lobbyists, lawyers, thinktankers, etc), neither of which had much in the way of civic roots or involvement; the city's black elite and white elite, a multiethnic suburbia whose members came to work in the city but otherwise had nothing to do with it, and, of course, a vast black underclass. I realise that these same groupings exist in other places, but for a variety of reasons extraneous to this post they never really cohered together in DC.

    The only thing that united the city was the Redskins. Rich white Washingtonians and poor black ones, Democrats and Republicans, people who voted for Marion Barry and people who couldn't stand him: we all sat in the same rickety stands at RFK to cheer the same team while the stadium swayed. If the 1980s were DC's lowpoint (and, man, were they ever), they were the Redskins' high point. The team not only won consistently, but they managed to be both classy (I'm thinking here of Art Monk, whose jersey I still sport most Sundays, George Starke and Russ Grimm—names that probably mean little or nothing to 98% of the people reading these sentences but to those of my age and background connote giants) and colourful (the mohawked Dexter Manley, the Hogs and of course John Riggins, a massive, lumbering running back who at a black-tie dinner told Justice O'Connor to "loosen up, Sandy baby. You're too tight," and then promptly fell asleep under the table during a speech from then Vice-President George H.W. Bush).

    All of which is by way of saying that Daniel Snyder (pictured) does not just own a football team; he stewards what may be Washington, DC's only real civic institution. In both of those roles he has been a consistent failure, as Dave McKenna's article in the Washington City Paper last November detailed. Mr Snyder, unsurprisingly, disliked the article. Rather than shaking it off, or writing a response, however, he decided to sue the paper. He is suing for $2m in New York, not Washington; and he announced his suit not by contacting the paper's editor (another disclosure: Michael Schaffer, who edits the City Paper, is an old friend and someone I respect a great deal, but I would be writing this even if he weren't), but by threatening the investment company that controls the media company that owns the paper. "We presume that defending such litigation would not be a rational strategy for an investment fund such as yours," threatened a letter from David Donvan, the Redskins' general counsel. "Indeed, the cost of the litigation would presumably quickly outstrip the asset value of the Washington City Paper." The letter also claims a number of Mr McKenna's claims are false; the newspaper is standing by them. It also accuses the paper of "demeaning" his wife's role as a "national spokesperson on breast-cancer awareness". In fact, the article makes no mention of breast cancer and refers to his wife only twice, regarding her claim that her husband has "grown and evolved". Perhaps most egregiously, Mr Donovan's letter accuses the City Paper of trafficking in "anti-Semitic caricature" for the illustration accompanying the article, which was a picture of Mr Snyder with devil's horns and a beard scribbled on.

    To be sure, the first amendment is no defence against making libellous statements. But it is, and should be, a defence against bullying, thuggish threats of litigation like this. To its credit, the paper is standing firm. It has established a legal-defence fund that raised $18,000 in five days, and its parent company has retained Floyd Abrams. It is a mystery what Mr Snyder thought he could get by filing such a suit. Judges tend to take a dim view of using lawsuits to intimidate, especially when doing so vitiates first amendment principles. And as Mr Schaffer writes, "Every journalist dreams of someday being in the middle of one of those epic, David-and-Goliath, right-versus-wrong First Amendment showdowns." But then, it's a mystery what Mr Snyder thought he'd get by signing 34-year-old Donovan McNabb to a five-year, $78m contract extension two weeks after they benched him.

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Mandates and the constitution

    The commerce clause and health reform

    Feb 10th 2011, 19:01 by M.S.

    JUST how much of American economic life should the federal government's constitutional power to regulate commerce between the states be understood to cover? Pretty much all of it, say liberals. A clearly limited amount of it, say conservatives. Which is a fine argument to have, Matthew Yglesias writes, so long as conservatives aren't arguing that the restrictive interpretation of the clause is not just correct, but "obviously correct. So obvious that the disagreement about it can’t just reflect larger disagreements about political principles but obviously represents bad faith on the part of liberals."

    A more generous interpretation of why liberals believe that the commerce clause allows the federal government broad authority to regulate economic activity might be that liberals share this interpretation of the  clause:

    What is this power? It is the power to regulate; that is, to prescribe the rule by which commerce is to be governed. This power, like all others vested in Congress, is complete in itself, may be exercised to its utmost extent, and acknowledges no limitations, other than are prescribed in the constitution. These are expressed in plain terms, and do not affect the questions which arise in this case, or which have been discussed at the bar. If, as has always been understood, the sovereignty of Congress, though limited to specified objects, is plenary as to those objects, the power over commerce with foreign nations, and among the several States, is vested in Congress as absolutely as it would be in a single government, having in its constitution the same restrictions on the exercise of the power as are found in the constitution of the United States. The wisdom and the discretion of Congress, their identity with the people, and the influence which their constituents possess at elections, are, in this, as in many other instances, as that, for example, of declaring war, the sole restraints on which they have relied, to secure them from its abuse. They are the restraints on which the people must often they solely, in all representative governments.

    Thus Chief Justice John Marshall in 1824, in Gibbons v Ogden. The specific issues in that case are obviously not all the same ones as would be faced today, as they lean a lot on inland navigation, but it's clear that this is a very expansive reading of the power, and it's not exactly a newfangled post-modern one unrooted in American tradition. Another way to describe the growth of federal authority under the commerce clause is the one outlined by John Paul Stevens in Gonzales v Raich:

    The Commerce Clause emerged as the Framers' response to the central problem giving rise to the Constitution itself: the absence of any federal commerce power under the Articles of Confederation. For the first century of our history, the primary use of the Clause was to preclude the kind of discriminatory state legislation that had once been permissible. Then, in response to rapid industrial development and an increasingly interdependent national economy, Congress “ushered in a new era of federal regulation under the commerce power,” beginning with the enactment of the Interstate Commerce Act in 1887 and the Sherman Antitrust Act in 1890.

    Basically, the scope of the federal government's power to regulate interstate commerce led to increased federal regulation of the economy because the portion of the economy consisting of interstate commerce grew. America's economy is a national economy. It's not surprising that, as agriculture, industry, services and finance have come increasingly to be dominated by national or multinational firms, the government that has the power to regulate national and international commerce has had increasing sway over economic regulation.

    The really crazy thing is that we're having this argument because the GOP wants to argue that the federal government's power to regulate interstate commerce doesn't entail the power to create an individual mandate to buy health insurance, since the act of not buying health insurance shouldn't be seen as engaging in interstate commerce. And yet the number one plank of the GOP's counter-proposal for health-insurance reform is to "let families and businesses buy health insurance across state lines," which would clearly place health insurance in the category of "interstate commerce". That ought to give the federal government all the regulatory powers the states currently have to regulate health insurance—including Massachussetts' Romneycare system, with an individual mandate whose constitutionality has never been challenged in court.

  • Voting rights and federalism

    Not there yet

    Feb 10th 2011, 17:04 by J.F. | ATLANTA

    AIN'T it always the way? The day I filed my piece on legal challenges to the Voting Rights Act (VRA), a federal district court in Washington, DC heard just such a challenge. It was brought by Shelby County, Alabama, which contends that the "preclearance" requirement of section five of the VRA—which requires covered jurisdictions to obtain approval from the Justice Department for any changes to their election procedures—is unconstitutional. The 15th amendment guarantees that "[t]he right of citizens of the United States to vote shall not be denied or abridged by the United States or by any State on account of race, color, or previous condition of servitude", and it grants Congress the "power to enforce this article by appropriate legislation." Shelby County's suit contends that the VRA is no longer appropriate: when Congress reauthorised the act for 25 years in 2006, it failed to show the existence of "pervasive voting discrimination", "electoral gamesmanship" and "widespread intentional discrimination on the basis of race". 

    John Bates, who presided over the hearing, seemed to take a sceptical view of the VRA's extension. As its baseline, the act uses the 1964 election: any locality that used a test or device (such as a literacy test) and had voter turnout of less than 50% must "preclear" any changes to their electoral procedure. "We're now looking at a situation," said Mr Bates, "where that information is at least 45 years out of date, and by the time the 2006 extension of the Voting Rights Act runs its course, it will be 70 years. That wouldn't seem to be a current coverage formula, would it?" I am unmoved by this line of thinking, for two reasons. First, it is sophistry: of course the VRA, written in 1965, used the 1964 election as its baseline. But in 2006 Congress found enough evidence of continuing discrimination to warrant a 25-year renewal. Now, was there something wrong with that evidence? If so then make the argument. But age alone should not disqualify the act. Second, let's remember that slavery was in place for centuries. For another century, Southern whites did all they could to deny Southern blacks the rights guaranteed them by the 15th amendment. The VRA ended such practices. But in the broad sweep of history, 70 years really isn't all that much.

    Having said that, the American South in 2011 is not the American South in 1964—as Justice Roberts wrote in 2009, "in part due to the success of [the VRA], we are now a very different Nation." There are no more literacy tests. Black officeholders and candidates abound. The registration gap between blacks and whites is minimal and sometimes non-existent in the covered states. The electoral votes of Virginia and North Carolina went to a black man in 2008. The crucial question today in much of the South—where black voters tend to be Democrats and white voters tend to be Republicans—is whether electoral changes such as redistricting are driven by racial bias or driven by politics. Challenging the VRA today seems less obviously petulant than doing so in 1965, as South Carolina did. One appellant I spoke to argued that the act has "great branding": say you want to challenge it and people think you're trying to keep black people from voting, which is not the case; challenging section five, which subjects some jurisdictions to an extra level of federal control, is not the same as challenging section two, which bars racial discrimination in voting.

    That same appellant pointed out another less than salutary effect of the VRA: it keeps districts safe for incumbents. Conservative white Republicans and liberal black Democrats both benefit from districts drawn to ensure that the minority vote is neither packed, stacked nor cracked, as the saying goes (that is, neither too concentrated nor too diffuse). Consider my home state: the 4th, 5th and 13th districts, which comprise central Atlanta and its largely black southern suburbs, are represented by liberal black Democrats. The 6th, 7th, 11th and 3rd belong to conservative white Republicans. In those districts the competitive races are in the primaries, when candidates try to outflank each other to the right or the left. Would it not be better, the appellant wondered, if the districts were drawn to include more balanced numbers of Democrats and Republicans, so candidates in the general election have to appeal to the broad centre?

    And where the Warren and Burger courts were inclined to grant the federal government broad leeway, the Roberts court has taken a narrower view of federal power and racial preferences. In a 2007 case that prohibited using race to determine school assignments (the district in this case was in Seattle, had no history of segregation, and was trying to achieve racially balanced schools), Justice Roberts wrote: "The way to stop discrimination on the basis of race is to stop discriminating on the basis of race." The VRA may not quite fit: it does not discriminate on the basis of race; it discriminates (if I can be permitted a little leeway in using that word in this clause) on the basis of history, of what actually happened, over and over again, in the areas it covers (and let's not forget it doesn't just cover the South; it protects Hispanic, Native American and Asian voters in numerous other localities scattered across seven states). The act was not simply willed into being; it, like other mid-century civil-rights legislation, came at great cost. It should not be lightly cast aside.

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Reaganomics debased

    Paul Ryan's Republicanomics

    Feb 10th 2011, 14:46 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    YESTERDAY, Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Federal Reserve, appeared on Capitol Hill to field questions from the House Budget Committee. The committee's new Republican chairman, Paul Ryan of Wisconsin, pressed Mr Bernanke to defend the Fed's efforts to quicken recovery through it's latest round of "quantitative easing", citing "a sharp rise in a variety of key global commodity and basic material prices" as a herald of inflation. In his opening statement, Mr Ryan acknowledged that "these cost pressures have not yet been passed along to consumers"—emphasis on "yet"—before worrying aloud that Mr Bernanke and his Fed minions threaten to wreck the economy.

    "Our currency should provide a reliable store of value—it should be guided by the rule of law, not the rule of men," Mr Ryan informed Mr Bernanke. "There is nothing more insidious that a country can do to its citizens than debase its currency". And who would disagree? Yet why all this hand-wringing about inflation now? Mr Bernanke sensibly pointed out that rising prices in global commodities markets reflect rising demand in emerging markets and, in some markets, constrained supply. American monetary policy? Not so much. Furthermore, inflation is low, and inflation expectations remain steady, as Mr Bernanke duly noted. Nevertheless, the breathless rhetoric of insidious currency debasement continues to spill forth even from sober, economically-literate Republicans such as Mr Ryan. 

    In yesterday's edition of The Daily, Jonathan Rauch draws a useful contrast between "Reagonomics", the actual economic-policy stance of the Reagan presidency, and "Republicanomics", a vulgar, acontextual cartoon of Reagonomics. Reagan met the specific challenges of the American economy in the early 1980s through tax cuts and tight money, among other things. Republicanomics transformed the policies of the Reagan administrations and the Volcker/Greenspan Fed into hardened ideology. "Reagan's embrace of a tight monetary policy in a high-inflation environment had hardened into a dogmatic insistence on tight money and anti-inflationary policies all the time," Mr Rauch writes. And thus:

    At a time when most economists saw deflation and long-term, Japanese-style stagnation as a far greater danger than inflation, and when high unemployment and below-target inflation indicated that monetary policy was too tight, Republicans were hyperventilating about "currency debasement" and denouncing the Fed's efforts to expand the money supply.

    I think if we add to this the reinforcing influence of an especially simplistic strain of Austrian monetary theory, we have a fairly solid account of the source of Mr Ryan's inflated worries about inflation. 

    Yes, yes, conservatives: there is an analogous Donkeynomics (or whatever you'd call it) that combines cold-fusion Keynesianism, occult health-care cost-curve bending, green-energy magic beanism, etc. But today is Mr Ryan's day to shine. 

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Congress and climate change

    Congress, climate change and incompetent grandstanding

    Feb 9th 2011, 22:18 by E.M. | WASHINGTON, DC

    MY COLLEAGUES have been discussing climate change, and it's worth noting that global warming used to be the subject of genuine political debate in Washington as well. Al Gore made a movie about it. Barack Obama vowed to put a stop to it (indeed, he claimed that he had begun to lower sea levels simply by being nominated for the presidency). Congress pored over a series of detailed laws designed to tackle it. The House of Representatives even passed one.

    No longer. The bill the House passed made no headway in the Senate, even with a filibuster-proof Democratic majority. Now that the Democrats have lost the House and seen their majority shrink in the Senate, the chances of an emissions-cutting measure getting through Congress are nil. Indeed, Republicans want to move in the opposite direction, and strip the EPA of its authority to regulate greenhouse gases under the Clean Air Act. But the chances of that succeeding are also close to zero, since the president has promised to veto any such move.

    lisa jacksonIt should be of little surprise, then, that the hearing held today by the House’s Energy and Commerce Committee on reining in the EPA was more about grandstanding than about legislating. A series of Republicans asked Lisa Jackson (pictured), the head of the EPA, whether she was aware of how many jobs she was killing by raising energy prices and whether she was happy about it. A series of Democrats asked Mrs Jackson whether she was aware of how many lives she was saving by fighting pollution, and whether it would be a good idea to let those people die. Mrs Jackson, the supposed star witness, had only a minor role in it all.

    Committee hearings are always like this. After smarmy exchanges about how delighted they are to be speaking to one another, congressmen ask grotesquely biased “Gotcha!” questions that the witnesses, usually harried officials, do their best not to respond to in a meaningful fashion. There are a lot of requests, almost always ignored, for yes or no answers. Mrs Jackson, for example, expended considerable time and effort not saying that greenhouse-gas regulation would raise energy prices and thus harm the economy.

    Sometimes, the pretence of give-and-take is abandoned altogether. This morning, Joe “Sorry BP” Barton, a Republican from Texas, asked a laughably leading question, requested a yes or no answer, and then—before receiving one—told Mrs Jackson, “The answer is no.” When she asked, with faux naivety, whether Mr Barton wanted her to answer the question herself or comment on his remarks, he replied with admirable honesty that he didn’t.

  • Sustainable Texas

    Conservationist conservatism

    Feb 9th 2011, 17:23 by M.S.

    I AGREE with everything my colleague writes about liberal-conservative divides, why so many Americans doubt the reality or seriousness of global warming, and what to do about it. And I think one helpful way to think about why American conservatives, and particularly business elites, are mainly sceptical of climate change is to look at why business elites elsewhere mainly aren't.

    As an illustration: over the weekend I had dinner with a successful European entrepreneur whose current venture is a lumber factory in East Africa. He's in the project because 1. it will be profitable; 2. it can qualify for subsidies on various grounds; and 3. he finds it interesting. To get the subsidies, he has to fulfill various requirements. One is an anti-AIDS programme for the employees. Another is that the factory must use 100% Forest Stewardship Council-certified sustainably harvested timber, from forests managed so that their net carbon loss is zero. My acquaintance's politics are what a European would consider centre-right "liberal" and anti-statist, and this was reflected in his approach to the project. The anti-AIDS programme, he said, doesn't interest him a bit; he'll put one in place in order to satisfy the requirement, but his basic attitude is that he's willing to provide a lot of condoms, and if the employees don't use them, that's their tough luck. The sustainable timber harvesting, on the other hand, is a big deal for him. To extrapolate his attitude, perhaps unfairly: he's not responsible if his employees are too dumb to keep their pants zipped, but he'd like to make sure planet Earth doesn't get destroyed.

    You get a fair bit of this sort of no-nonsense environmentalism among European businessmen. As my colleague notes, the economic background is important, and it's probably related to the fact that European economies are relatively stingy energy users, so they may benefit from a shift to global carbon taxes or emissions limits. Still, it also seems to me to be a type of conservative conservationist attitude that might play well in Texas.

  • Public and private unions

    What's the difference exactly?

    Feb 9th 2011, 14:55 by M.S.

    SOMETHING about public employees' unions certainly feels different from private-industry unions, as my colleague points out. But I'm not sure I follow the way he draws the distinction. In private industry, my colleague thinks, unions make sense because they compensate for uneven bargaining power between owners and workers in the struggle over how to split up profits. Public-sector unions, he thinks,

    ...don't work like this. They aren't bargaining against capitalists for a fair cut of the cooperative surplus. They're bargaining against everybody who pays taxes and/or benefits from government spending. The question of distribution in democratic politics isn't about splitting up jointly-produced profits. It's about interest groups fighting to grab a bigger share of government revenue while sticking competing groups with the tax bill.

    The thing is, if one were a hardcore neo-classical type, one might argue that private-sector unions are merely bargaining against everyone who buys the products they produce, in an effort to drive up prices. Unions are trying to set industry-wide uniform wages, not argue with the owners of a particular firm about how to divide that firm's profits based on this year's results. That would result in different wages for workers at different firms, which is one thing unions generally don't want. In a platonic-idealist capitalist world where competition is always driving down prices and profits, and where firms have to compete on efficiency, you'd think the only way unions could make more money for workers is by raising prices for everyone.

    In fact, the world isn't ideal, there's a whole lot of wiggle room for firms to increase profits by driving down wages, and, as my colleague writes, private-sector unions provide workers with a counterweight to management power in bargaining over compensation. And the evidence is very clear that, while they may also lead to reduced investment, unions provide a wage premium for their workers in the firms and industries where they operate. If you had a situation in which the private sector was largely unionised and the public sector wasn't, you'd expect to see private-sector workers making more than public-sector ones for similar jobs.

    In fact, however, we don't have such a world. We have a world in which private-sector unions have shriveled while public-sector ones have grown. And I think it's pretty clear how this came about. Back in the 1940s and 1950s, the standard jobs that provided decent salaries and job security for the working and middle class were all pretty heavily unionised, whether private- or public-sector. Auto workers were unionised, police officers were unionised, newspaper reporters were unionised, postal workers were unionised. In my family, one branch was in the (private) ladies' garment workers' union, the other branch was in the (public) teachers' union. (Then there was my Great-aunt Marcia, who was in the Screen Cartoonists' Guild, which Walt Disney claimed was a Stalinist front group taking orders directly from Moscow. She used to draw a mean Popeye.) In that generation, people who worked in government jobs would have reacted angrily to the idea that they didn't have the right to organise and demand better wages the same way their private counterparts did.

    Private-sector unionisation began to decline in the 1970s for a reason: private industry had an incentive to seek a non-unionised labour force and to break union control wherever possible, in order to increase profitability. So the auto and steel industries shifted factories to right-to-work states, leading to the tautological result trumpeted in papers like this one that unionised areas have lower rates of investment than non-unionised ones. The government doesn't have such a clear incentive to seek low-cost non-unionised labour. Moreover, a lot of governing tasks can't be outsourced to cheap non-union locales; you can't move an elementary school to Arkansas because the unionised teachers in New Jersey are too expensive. So government unionisation has risen from 23% in 1973 to 36% today, while private-sector unionisation has declined from 24% in 1973 to 7% today. In this environment, it's quixotic to argue that private-sector unions (which are withering) are legitimate, while public-sector ones aren't. It might be interesting to consider the merits of an economy with 50% private-sector unionisation and no public-sector unionisation at all, but that's not an economy we could conceivably get at this point.

  • Rhetoric and rationality

    The fallacy of careless contrarianism

    Feb 8th 2011, 21:54 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    LAST week, I posted a video of an impressive young man delivering a moving short speech in opposition to the attempt to add an amendment to Iowa's constitution outlawing gay marriage. Steven Landsburg, an economist at the University of Rochester, was not impressed.

    In a video that’s begun to go viral, University of Iowa engineering student Zach Wahls attempts to refute this notion [that gay people, on average, are less successful as parents] without offering a shred of evidence beyond a single cherry-picked case (his own) to prove that children of gay parents sometimes turn out just fine (except, perhaps, for their ability to reason)...

    What’s particularly disturbing to me is all the chatter about how eloquent this kid is, as if eloquence in the service of intellectual misdirection were somehow something to be admired.

    There are a number of things one might like to say to Mr Landsburg, but let me congratulate him instead for his inspiring opposition to fallacious arguments from anecdote. One may wonder, however, whether this commonplace error is among our society's most pressing problems, much less among our society's most serious epistemological failings. I take it that Mr Wahls' problem, the problem he was addressing in his uplifting oration, is that a powerful political faction convinced of the essential evil of homosexuality by a magical book seeks to injure his family by voiding his mothers' marriage of its legal standing and stripping his family of the status and respect that flow from that. The science-minded Mr Landsburg may be shocked to learn the assault on marriage equality in Iowa and elsewhere is not predicated upon the modest empirical hypothesis "that gay people, on average, are less successful as parents"; it is based on a conviction of faith that homosexuality is a sinful perversion inherently corrosive to the values that make healthy families possible. Mr Wahls' upstanding, A-student, Eagle-Scout character together with his normatively wholesome family life is sufficient to cast rational doubt on this rather sweeping article of faith.

  • Climate change

    Why don't Americans believe in global warming?

    Feb 8th 2011, 20:03 by E.G. | AUSTIN

    FIRST of all, I apologise for the slightly inflammatory headline of this post. The fact is that a majority of Americans (58%) do think climate change is a serious problem, according to the January 2011 Rasmussen Energy Update, and fully one-third, 33%, "see it as a Very Serious problem." Still, the United States is less exercised about climate change than a lot of countries, and it's one of the few places where you can turn on the television and catch a debate between mainstream figures about whether climate change is even real. Over the weekend, for example, Charles Krauthammer suggested that a belief in global warming has the same epistemological status as a religious belief.

    I've been wanting to take a step back and think about why America is a laggard in the fight against climate change. I would posit a handful of explanations:

    Psychological: The consequences of climate change are too awful to contemplate. Therefore, we're denying the issue, as we used to deny monsters in the room by hiding under the blanket. If you don't look at it, it can't look at you.

    Economic: The costs of a large-scale effort to fight global warming are too steep to bear. Therefore, we're trying to ignore the issue, or pretending it doesn't exist, or we believe that the economy (including development) is more important.

    Political: The fact that Democrats are always hammering on about climate change and Republicans aren't suggests that this is a political issue, not a scientific one. This creates a feedback loop: if climate change were real, why is it so polarising? Because it's so polarising, it must be slightly suspicious.

    Epistemological: Why should we believe in climate change? Where's the evidence? All we know is what scientists say, and scientists are sometimes wrong. And don't even get me started on Al Gore.

    Metaphysical: God isn't going to let millions of people die in an epic drought.

    I suspect the metaphysical denial is quite rare—but given the comparative religiosity of American culture and the stereotypes thereof, it gets a lot of air time. It is also the least valid of the reasons for denial (partly because in the given system, God obviously does let people die). The other explanations are more common. In the Rasmussen poll, for example, a plurality of respondents said that "there is a conflict between environmental protection and economic growth."

  • Budgets and bargaining power

    Government workers don't need unions

    Feb 7th 2011, 22:06 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    TODAY'S New York Times editorial wisely comes out against the proposal to allow states to declare bankruptcy as a union-busting, budget-saving move. (Josh Barro's reasoning against state bankruptcy rings sound to me.) However, I think the Times' goes wrong here:

    It is true that many public employee unions have done well during a time of hardship for most Americans. The problem, though, isn’t the existence of those unions; it is the generous contracts willingly given to them by lawmakers because of their lobbying power and bloc-voting ability.

    The Times' contention that the existence of public-employee unions is not the problem is true, if it is true, only because the unions "fix" a bargaining-power deficit public workers don't have. Without public-sector unions, government workers would lobby their way to padded paychecks, unobtanium-plated pensions, and hermetic job security anyway. Which is just to say, government workers don't really need unions at all. Indeed, the strategic logic behind private- and public-sector unions is fundamentally different. "The process of collective bargaining, as usually understood, cannot be transplanted into the public service," as some little somebody called Franklin Delano Roosevelt put it back in 1937. 

    In any productive joint enterprise, there’s a question of how to split the gains from cooperation. Our native sense of fairness tells us that our shares should be roughly proportional to the value of our contributions. But distributive fairness doesn’t automatically prevail. What we actually get—whether we get a fair share or get used—depends on our bargaining power. Individual workers with few options hardly stand a chance against managers backed by massive capital. Workers are most likely to get a cut that reflects the value of their contributions when they band together and bargain collectively. "To each according to his or her individual bargaining power" is hardly a compelling principle of distributive justice, which is why institutions that equalise bargaining power, such as private-sector labor unions, make moral sense.

    The thing is, public-sector unions don't work like this. They aren't bargaining against capitalists for a fair cut of the cooperative surplus. They're bargaining against everybody who pays taxes and/or benefits from government spending. The question of distribution in democratic politics isn't about splitting up jointly-produced profits. It's about interest groups fighting to grab a bigger share of government revenue while sticking competing groups with the tax bill. Because of the sheer size and relatively uniform interests of the group, public employees constitute a politically powerful bloc with or without unions. As the percentage of the labour force employed by the government rises, the heft of this group only increases. Public-employee unions simply consolidate an already impressive concentration of political bargaining power. Moreover, as the Democratic Party comes increasingly to rely on patronage from the public-sector unions, the determination of Democratic politicians to bargain against the unions on behalf of taxpayers and the beneficiaries of competing government programmes necessarily weakens. For Democratic office-seekers, generous union contracts are "willingly given", as the Times put it, in roughly the same sense that unaffiliated private-sector workers "willingly" accept low wages and poor working conditions. 

    This leaves us with a superficially ironic situation. The Republican Party emerges as the organised champion of everyone who stands to lose in the fight over the fisc when public-sector unions win. The GOP's base electoral incentive to hobble their rival's main source of campaign cash and voter mobilisation leads it to function as a countervailing force against overpowered public-sector unions to the benefit of rich people, yes, but also to the benefit of less powerful and more needy constituencies within the Democratic coalition. A bit of public-employee union busting at the state and municipal level wouldn't leave government workers vulnerable. There's every reason to believe they'd continue to function as a powerful, pampered political faction. Pushback against public-sector unions would simply make the always-unfair fight over the fiscal commons slightly less unfair, and make fiscally prudent policy slightly less unlikely.

  • Musical banking

    Just a simple melody

    Feb 7th 2011, 21:20 by M.S.

    PAUL KRUGMAN rounded out his praise for "simple models" last week with a video treatment of the "Simple Gifts" theme from Aaron Copland's "Appalachian Spring". As Mr Krugman notes, the melody is derived from an old Shaker hymn whose lyrics start:

    'Tis the gift to be simple, 'tis the gift to be free
    'Tis the gift to come down where we ought to be

    When Mr Krugman called the lyrics appropriate, I took him to be alluding to the Federal Reserve's great mission of getting interest rates to sit just where they ought to be. Of course, what we're all worried about is that central bankers may have more of the attitude expressed in the cheeseball 90s-kitsch Celtic-dance adaptation of the "Simple Gifts" melody, "Lord of the Dance":

    Dance, dance, wherever you may be
    I am the lord of the dance, said he
    And I lead you all, wherever you may be
    And I lead you all in the dance, said he

    Mostly, though, central bankers seem to have a pretty impressive respect for the tremendous responsibilities they carry. It's more the heads of private too-big-to-fail banks who seem to feel they "came down from heaven and danced on the earth," and owe no explanations to anyone.

  • The Republican race

    Jeb in 2012?

    Feb 7th 2011, 18:31 by E.G. | AUSTIN

    jeb bush, george bushJEB BUSH, the former governor of Florida, has said that he may be interested in running for president in 2016, but not now. Rich Lowry offers eight reasons why Mr Bush shouldn't wait. Among the catalogue is the inevitable confrontation with the Bush brand. Mr Lowry argues that while Jeb may not benefit from being brothers with George, it's not a category killer:

    In 2008, Jeb’s association with his brother would have been an absolute killer. That’s not true anymore. The controversies that made the Bush years so venomous have faded, and—partly through the miracle of the accelerated news cycle—2000–2008 already feels somewhat distant.

    I doubt Mr J Bush, who's always said to have been the brother who grew up thinking of himself as presidential material, appreciates this kind of complication. But whether he runs in 2012 or 2016, I doubt he can get far without addressing this head-on.

    The Bushes are the oddest of all American political families. They have a huge fragmentation issue. You have Bush-denominated politicians popping up in Texas and Florida and Connecticut. Beyond the fact there's no Bush place, there's also no Bush big idea. What is the common intellectual thread among these people, or the formative family experience? And although the number of high offices they've held would suggest that Americans like the Bush "brand", that doesn't seem to be the case. Quite the contrary: every new Bush that comes along has to shake off or distance himself from the Bushes that came before.

    We could really use a public reckoning from the Bushes about their role in American life. Neither of the Georges is much given to candour, H.W. because of his WASP-y reserve and W. because he's not a pontificator. This job would fall to Jeb. Not to be overly glib, but it might be the equivalent of Barack Obama's campaign speech on race. A painful but important discussion that could help us along the path to national healing.

    (Photo credit: AFP)

  • Inflation

    Inflation and renewable energy

    Feb 7th 2011, 16:21 by M.S.

    GLENN BECK types who warn of a coming bout of inflation typically blame it on the policies (or, often, the very existence) of the Fed, which has dramatically expanded the money supply over the past two years to counteract the fall in commercial activity due to deleveraging from the financial crisis, thereby probably preventing a second Great Depression. Fortunately, Ben Bernanke apparently pays no attention to such people. But in a post on Friday, Gavyn Davies explained where the real inflationary threat lies: the possibility that the current rise in commodity prices isn't your typical short-term fluctuation, but part of a long-term trend. As emerging markets grow richer and drive up demand for raw materials, those materials may be rising in value relative to the industrial and service products of the developed economies.

    There is a very big difference between a self-reversing up-and-down cycle in the commodity markets, and a longer term upward trend in commodity prices relative to the prices of goods and services produced in the developed economies. Because commodity prices are determined in competitive markets which need to clear at any point in time, they tend to fluctuate much more over short periods than the “sticky” prices and wages which exist in developed economies. If they are simply fluctuating around a constant or slowly rising trend, then they will quickly self-correct and the central bank should stay focused on the core inflation rate which is set in the rest of the economy.

    But what if commodity prices are instead embarked on a long term uptrend against the prices of goods and services in the developed economies, driven by the rapid growth in the emerging economies? In that case, the commodity price shock would have a permanent effect on input prices in the developed economies, and it would not be appropriate for the central banks to ignore this shock. In fact, if they ignored it, they would simply be accommodating a permanent inflation shock to the system, which is what they did in the inflationary 1970s.

    So it is a very difficult judgment. My own view, based on the arguments above,  is that the central banks are justified in waiting for more data before concluding that the rise in commodity prices is permanent.

    Paul Krugman likes Mr Davies's column but thinks the main problem is still overreaction to commodity-price fluctuations rather than the reverse. He recalls the point in mid-2008 when the European Central Bank, looking at rising headline inflation that was driven by the commodity bump, made the mistake of raising rates at the onset of a huge recession.

    To me, the main point here is just how crucial it is for Western economies, and particularly the United States, to reduce their use of commodities, and particularly oil. The capacities of human ingenuity are limitless; the amount of crude oil on planet Earth is not. If you build an economy that's entirely dependent on a non-renewable resource, you are guaranteeing yourself a nasty encounter with stagflation sooner or later when the stuff starts to run out. The idea that sustainable-resource use and renewable energy is some kind of socialist hippy hobby is incredibly naive and frivolous, and extremely damaging to the American economy.

  • Judges and ideology

    Telepathic Supreme Court vote counting

    Feb 4th 2011, 23:07 by W.W. | IOWA CITY

    IN A matter of days, it has become conventional wisdom that the constitutionality of Obamacare more or less comes down to Anthony Kennedy's considered opinion. (I can't keep from imagining conspiracies to blackmail the famously fence-straddling justice, plots to slip microscopic mind-control robots into his morning oatmeal, schemes to kidnap and replace him with a shapeshifting mutant, and so on.) But how fair is this?

    Dylan Matthews offers a useful overview of the political-science literature on the "attitudinal model" of judicial decision-making. This is the theory that the personal attitudes of judges—their beliefs, sympathies, commitments, partisan leanings, etc—more than any other factor determine how they will come down on cases. That is to say, as Mr Matthews puts it, "Courts are political, news at 11". However, Scott Lemieux points out some important limitations of the attitudinal model:

    [I]t’s worth noting that the model only applies to Supreme Court votes on the merits. Given that virtually by definition cases in the modern era only reach the Supreme Court when there is substantial legal ambiguity involved, it’s not surprising that politics generally drives votes in politically ambiguous cases. But the law matters significantly more in determining what kind of cases the Supreme Court hears and which it doesn’t, and politics alone also can’t explain why votes on the merits are structured around some issues than others. (Although Scalia and Thomas presumably believe that abortion should be illegal, their jurisprudence doesn’t require states to make it illegal.) There are also times when legal policy preferences aren’t the same as policy preferences per se. If you look at it as a case about federalism, the attitudinal model gets 7 of the 9 votes on Raich right; if you look it as a case of whether the federal government should strictly enforce anti-marijuana statutes, it arguably gets 7 of 9 votes wrong. Bush v. Gore is the absolute poster child for purely political jurisprudence, and yet if you look at it as an equal protection case it gets all 9 votes wrong.

    One question, then, is this: Is there likely to be any ambiguity over how the Justices of the Supreme Court might choose to frame the challenge to Obamacare? Are there conservatives who think it's bad policy, but constitutional. (That seems to be the opinion of Charles Fried, a classically liberal Harvard law professor.) More interestingly, is there any reason to believe that there are liberals on the court who approve of Obamacare as policy, yet may be sympathetic to the argument that the individual mandate stretches Congress' commerce-clause powers past the breaking point? This really seems worth asking since Sonia Sotomayor and Elena Kagan have, respectively, little and no record of commerce-clause jurisprudence.

  • The safety net

    Social welfare and economic irrationality

    Feb 4th 2011, 21:06 by M.S.

    MIKE Konczal writes:

    One of the more curious behavioral responses is that people hate unemployment. They hate not being part of their productive community, they hate not contributing, they hate the loss of identity that one gets as someone who works. To an economist that’s b-a-n-a-n-a-s. Unemployment should be a pleasant vacation! But, last time I checked, it wasn’t (is that consistent with the latest frontiers in happiness research?).

    Mr Konczal is contributing to a discussion that's kicked up recently over a paper written by libertarian economists Bryan Caplan and Scott Beaulier, arguing that behavioural economics provides a basis for critiquing government welfare policies. Karl Smith highlighted Mr Caplan's paper as a serious challenge to his neo-classical economic belief structure; other commentors replied that the paper had no data and no mathematical models; Mr Smith responded that often simple, data-free models can be extremely helpful in posing problems and presenting complex ideas intuitively, and cited the example of Paul Krugman's famous essay on the babysitting co-op with its crystal-clear workaday picture of how a Keynesian liquidity trap works; Mr Krugman jumped in with his favourite simple, low-on-data papers, including David Hume's thought experiment "Of the Balance of Trade" and Evsey Domar's paper grounding slavery and serfdom in land surpluses and labour shortages. (I love this stuff. Blogs are the greatest thing to happen to intellectual life in the early 21st century; one day we'll look back on them as a latter-day Bloomsbury.)

    Mr Caplan is taking up a problem for conservative critics of the welfare state who take a neo-classical economic perspective. From a neo-classical perspective, he says, giving people more choices (by giving them money, preference in university admissions, health care and so on) always makes them better off. So how can welfare hurt the poor? He thinks behavioural economics, which shows us how people often (usually, even) make decisions that are irrational from a classical economic perspective, can provide the answer:

    A simple numerical example can illustrate the link between helping the poor and harming them. Suppose that in the absence of government assistance, the true net benefit of having a child out-of-wedlock is -$25,000, but a teenage girl with self-serving bias [unrealistically optimistic and overconfident] believes it is only -$5000. Since she still sees the net benefits as negative she chooses to wait. But suppose the government offers $10,000 in assistance to unwed mothers. Then the perceived benefits rise to $5000, the teenage girl opts to have the baby, and ex post experiences a net benefit of -$25,000 + $10,000 = -$15,000.

    Mr Konczal responds that the fact that people are economically irrational shows us precisely why government safety-net programmes are necessary.

    [S]houldn’t loss aversion, overconfidence, time-inconsistent discounting and difficulty following statistical probabilities lead a behavioral person to be made better off by universal health care and old age pensions? The probability of managing an individual investment portfolio as well as estimating the chances and subjective experience of being destitute in old age is difficult to estimate individually and the tail risk of the loss that occurs in poverty would be particularly painful. The same statement should be true for health care. Same for unemployment insurance... That people are bad risk judges and hate losses should redouble our faith in social democratic insurance, not detract.

    I basically agree with what Mr Konczal is saying here, but I also agree with what Mr Caplan is saying. It's pretty obvious that systems that disburse money in ways that aren't compatible with producing social utility can create pathological cultures of dependency. To take the obverse of what Mr Caplan says: it may be difficult from a neo-classical perspective to explain why a football coach is helping his players by subjecting them to extremely painful drills, against their wishes. He's doing it because he has a better ability than they do to judge what's necessary for them to achieve their long-term goal of winning football games. What I would point out, though, is that what Mr Caplan is saying here implies a certain degree of paternalism. Mr Caplan's example posits a difference between a "true" net benefit of having a child out-of-wedlock, and the merely apparent net benefit perceived by an immature teenage girl. But who is it that judges the "true" net benefit? A teenage girl is quite likely to herself decide, at some point down the road, that having a baby was the wrong decision. But a lot of social welfare policies are directed at mature adults. Mr Caplan is implying that third parties can be better judges of what's good for people than those people are themselves. I don't disagree with that perspective, but like Mr Konczal, I'm sceptical that it generally mitigates against government social-welfare policies, as opposed to for them.

  • Corporate-tax reform

    The trouble with tax reform

    Feb 4th 2011, 19:44 by R.M. | WASHINGTON, DC

    "TODAY, the US has a non-competitive international tax system, and our companies will soon pay the highest rate among all developed countries," says the Business Roundtable, a trade association that has expressed support for corporate-tax reform. Indeed, the top federal corporate tax rate in America is 35%, which is quite high compared to other industrialised countries. But that rate is misleading, as is most of the talk we're now hearing about reform.

    In America, very few firms actually submit 35% of their taxable income to the government. According to various studies, the effective average tax rate for corporations is more like 25%, thanks to a bevy of loopholes, deductions and credits. And, as David Leonhardt pointed out in a recent column, there is also a large variation in what individual companies pay in taxes. He reports, "Of the 500 big companies in the well-known Standard & Poor’s stock index, 115 paid a total corporate tax rate—both federal and otherwise—of less than 20 percent over the last five years... Thirty-nine of those companies paid a rate less than 10 percent."

    Mr Leonhardt is correct to conclude that, in many ways, America's corporate tax code is as bad as it gets. Despite its nominally high rate, America collects less revenue (as a percentage of GDP) than most other industrialised countries, thanks to all those loopholes and credits. And the complicated nature of the system leads firms to waste much time and money coming up with tax-avoidance schemes. So the system is ripe for reform.

    And proper reform would likely address many of business's common complaints. For one, it would reduce uncertainty over the tax rate, a popular peeve. If a new set of rates is agreed upon and the myriad loopholes and credits discarded, firms would have a much more reliable idea of what their tax burden will be year to year. Those credits and loopholes also lead to poor decisions by firms. For example, the current code rewards debt over equity, leading to more leveraged companies and a more fragile economy. In other ways the code encourages firms to buy unnecessary equipment, or perform R&D of questionable value.

    It also picks winning industries. This can seem justifiable—why shouldn't the government support nascent green industries or biotech research labs?—but it has led to the unwieldy and often irrational system that exists today, where the government plays the market's role. (The chart at right comes courtesy of the New York Times.)

    So then, reform—lower the rate and close the windows that allow revenue to escape. Barack Obama says he wants to do it. Republicans like the idea. Business is in favour. And yet I'm still doubtful it will come to pass. Why?

    Let's go back to the Business Roundtable, which says it was pleased with Mr Obama's focus on tax reform in his state-of-the-union speech. Here's how Mr Leonhardt describes the Roundtable's position:

    The Roundtable says it supports corporate tax reform. But it actually favors only a reduction in the tax rate. The group refuses to say whether it also favors a reduction of loopholes. In effect, the Roundtable wants a tax cut for its members regardless of how much the tax code is simplified—or whether the budget deficit grows.

    That's the problem with any revenue-neutral tax reform that bins loopholes: it may mean a tax cut for some, but it means a tax rise for many others. And those others have powerful lobbyists. How do you think they got those loopholes inserted into the code in the first place? Why has it been so hard to end the preferential treatment of industries like Ethanol or Big Pharma? Corporate-tax reform means taking on many of those lobbyists at once. It would create a number of obvious losers, while the benefits would be diffuse. Forgive me for doubting Congress's resolve.

    But even if Congress were to do away with "special interest" loopholes, that would only recoup a small percentage of lost revenue. The more expensive provisions may prove even more elusive.

    Eric Toder of the Urban Institute says "the ten most costly provisions benefiting business investment account for about 92 percent" of revenue losses over the next five years. First on his list is the deferral of foreign-source income of American multinational firms. This is what allows a company like GE to pay an extremely low rate. And it just so happens that GE's CEO is now the chairman of Mr Obama's Council on Jobs and Competitiveness. As Mr Toder states, "the corporate leaders now advising the president are likely pushing him to move in the opposite direction, following our major trading partners, who exempt foreign-source income." Go down the rest of Mr Toder's list and you'll find more cause for pessimism. The expenditure accounting for the second largest loss of revenue—the accelerated depreciation of machinery and equipment—has just been increased. The credit for research and development is unlikely to be cut, as are credits for low-income housing. The one area Mr Obama has specifically targeted—tax breaks for fossil fuels—is relatively small (and unpopular).

    In some cases the existing credits are worthwhile. And taxing multinational corporations in a way that keeps them competitive and benefiting America is difficult, to say the least. But if the administration wants to substantially lower the corporate-tax rate, then it must take on its most expensive provisions. And if it wants to achieve reform, it must take on all those who benefit from the current system. "It can be done," the president said in his state-of-the-union address. I don't share his confidence.

About Democracy in America

In this blog, our correspondents share their thoughts and opinions on America's kinetic brand of politics and the policy it produces.

Advertisement

Advertisement

Latest blog posts - All times are GMT

Link exchange
From Free exchange - February 16th, 21:50
I, reporters
From Babbage - February 16th, 20:22
The magic of Bob Herbert
From Democracy in America - February 16th, 20:20
The latest Fed projections
From Free exchange - February 16th, 19:51
The Cassez case comes to a head
From Americas view - February 16th, 19:48
What's the equilibrium here?
From Free exchange - February 16th, 19:21
The drama of climate change
From Prospero - February 16th, 18:54
More from our blogs »
Products & events
Stay informed today and every day

Subscribe to The Economist's free e-mail newsletters and alerts.


Subscribe to The Economist's latest article postings on Twitter


See a selection of The Economist's articles, events, topical videos and debates on Facebook.

Advertisement