Economics

Free exchange

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Mar 2nd 2011, 21:42 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Europe's banks are in great danger (Spiegel)

    More on growth-reducing structural change (Dani Rodrik)

    How bad is the state pension funding mess? (Marginal Revolution)

    Global imbalances without tears (Project Syndicate)

    Who is John Williams? (Real Time Economics)

  • Fiscal policy

    About that Goldman estimate

    Mar 2nd 2011, 21:10 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    LAST week, many of us quoted stories on a new Goldman Sachs analysis of proposed Republican spending cuts. House Republicans, recall, want to slash spending in the current fiscal year, which is half over, by $61 billion. A Goldman analysis by Alec Phillips suggested that this would cut growth this year by 2 percentage points. Chin scratching began when Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke said in testimony yesterday that this was an overstatement; the cuts would likely trim no more than a few tenths of a percentage point off of growth. How to explain the gap?

    As it turns out, Goldman's analysis was misrepresented. They've since clarified:

    In our own budget deficit projections, we assume that some spending cuts would indeed be enacted. As a placeholder—neither the president's budget nor the final House package had yet been released—we assumed a $25 billion cut to non-defense discretionary spending in the current fiscal year...

    How large is this impact? We estimate that the $25bn cut in our budget projections reduces growth in Q2 by around 1 percentage point (annualized); this effect is already incorporated in our forecast that real GDP will grow 4% (annualized). In addition, we estimated that the $61bn cut passed by the House would reduce growth in Q2 and Q3 by 1.5-2 percentage point (annualized) in Q2 and Q3. (In other words, relative to the assumptions currently embedded in our forecast, the House-passed package would imply an additional 0.5-1 percentage point drag on growth in Q2 and an additional 1.5-2 percentage point drag in Q3.) Spending would then be maintained at that lower level thereafter, and the effect on GDP growth would dissipate quickly in Q4 and would be essentially neutral by 2012 Q1.

    So when Goldman's analysts forecast 4% real GDP growth for 2011, they were assuming that the fiscal 2011 budget would be cut by $25 billion, and that this would trim growth by about 1 percentage point. Absent the cuts, growth would roar ahead at 5% for the year (which is more in keeping with a rebound from a recession of the depth America experienced).

    Republicans, however, want to trim a a total of $61 billion from the current budget—more than the $25 billion over all of 2011 that Goldman used as a placeholder. And so Goldman estimates that these cuts will take off an additional 0.5 to 1.0 percentage points from annualised growth rates (which is what is always reported) in the second and third quarters.

    That's nothing to sneeze at, of course, especially given the fact that Republicans have made no pretense of using cost-benefit analysis to identify wise cuts, and given that there is no immediate crisis, and given that the main fiscal imbalance is associated with long-run growth in health costs, not short-run growth in non-defence discretionary spending. But it's a smaller impact than the $300 billion in lost growth many reported, and it's much closer to Mr Bernanke's assessment. So there: mystery solved.

  • Inflation

    Judging by the headline

    Mar 2nd 2011, 18:59 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    THE Federal Reserve looks at a lot of different data points when considering the economy's rate of inflation, but its preferred measure is a core measure, which strips out the volatile energy and food components. Other central banks, including the European Central Bank, prefer to focus on headline inflation. This is understandable; people pay for the volatile components just as they pay for the core components. But making policy around headline numbers may add to instability in some cases.

    In the summer of 2008, for instance, rising oil prices caused headline consumer prices in America to soar. At the same time, however, core inflation was flat, and inflation expectations were actually falling. Had the Fed tightened policy at this time, it would have undermined the American economy just as the financial crisis was developing—essentially repeating the monetary errors of 1929. Happily, the Fed's focus on core inflation prevented this. Had the Fed focused more on inflation expectations, it would have acted more aggressively still, sparing the economy some of the pain of the second half collapse.

    I mention this because, as I noted, the ECB focuses on headline inflation and European headline inflation is rising. In January, headline producer prices jumped 1.5% from the previous month and 6.1% from the previous year. That was well ahead of economist expectations. Energy costs were the main factor; headline prices rose twice as much as core prices, and the increase in core was largely due to producers passing on their higher energy costs to consumers. This trend is sure to continue in the short-term. In the month of February, a barrel of Brent crude oil rose in price by about $15. And the hawkish, headline-oriented ECB may well respond by tightening policy.

    But this would be a mistake. For an inflation spiral to begin, it's not sufficient for firms to pass on energy costs to customers. Those customers must then demand higher wages, which are themselves higher firm costs. But most European workers are in no shape to bargain for wage increases. The euro zone unemployment rate is currently at 9.9%, essentially unchanged from a year ago.

    The problem for Europe is that its core economy, and the dominant voice in euro zone monetary policy, is Germany. Germany's unemployment rate is just 6.5%, and it's down from 7.3% a year ago. Wage pressures may well be surfacing in the German economy. And that will make some ECB officials very nervous.

    It shouldn't. Tightening in response to rising German wages would be doubly harmful to struggling peripheral countries. It would make an inappropriately harsh (for them) monetary policy harsher still. And by preventing any wage increase in Germany, it would undermine a process of internal euro-zone rebalancing that really needs to take place.

    But I don't expect these concerns to get much of a hearing in Frankfurt. And I suspect that the people making similar arguments in London may also be disregarded.

  • Economics

    The weekly papers

    Mar 2nd 2011, 17:12 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    THIS week's interesting economics research:

    Personality psychology and economics (Mathilde Almlund, Angela Lee Duckworth, James Heckman, and Tim Kautz)

    A post-racial strategy for improving skills to promote equality (James Heckman)

    Information technology and economic change (Jeremiah Dittmar)

    Is employer-based health insurance a barrier to entrepreneurship? (Robert Fairlie, Kanika Kapur, and Susan Gates)

    Has consumption inequality mirrored income inequality? (Mark Aguiar and Mark Bils)

    International capital flows and returns to safe assets in the United States, 2003-2007 (Ben Bernanke, Carol Bertaut, Laurie Pounder DeMarco, and Steven Kamin)

  • China's economy

    Get a piece of the stamp action

    Mar 2nd 2011, 16:03 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    AN INTERESTING story from FT beyondbrics:

    The wave of Chinese money that has crashed through the markets for fine wine, art and antiques is now flooding into the altogether sleepier world of stamp collecting.

    At an auction in Hong Kong this week, a rare block of four stamps from the Cultural Revolution sold for HK$8,970,000 (US$1.1m) – an all-time record for a Chinese stamp or multiple. Including a 15 per cent buyer’s fee, the anonymous buyer paid over US$1.3m for the stamps.

    Here's a fun sentence:

    The 3,000-lot Hong Kong auction has sent ripples of excitement through the stamp collecting world because it raised a total of HK$98.7m (US$12.6m), almost double the pre-sale estimate of HK$50m.

    Stamp collectors haven't been this excited since, I don't know, some previous stamp auction. The guy who runs the firm that handled this particular sale is quoted in the piece, and he attributes the soaring price of stamps to Chinese growth. It's of a piece with the rise in wine prices, which is due to a soaring Chinese interest in wine-drinking ("though some grumble that wealthy mainlanders have been known to commit the ultimate faux pas of smoking cigarettes or chewing gum at wine tasting events").

    But here's the thing. When prices for consumption goods soar consumption growth falls, which limits further increses, OR rising prices feed back into wage increases and generate broader inflation. That's not an ideal situation for the Chinese economy, but it would have some positive effect on rebalancing, it's an easily observable process, and it's curable with an expectations-adjusting period of monetary tightening and slower growth (or recession). But when prices for investment goods soar, demand for investment goods may increase as new buyers speculate that price rises will continue. The result is a bubble, and the impact can be extremely pernicious. In the present, serious misallocations of capital can result. In the future, the inevitable crash may lead to a deeper, more painful downturn.

    I know China is trying to rein in exuberant investors cautiously to avoid a sudden crash. But the more these kinds of stories appear, the more one suspects they may be acting too slowly.

  • Industrial policy

    Moving the movie business

    Mar 2nd 2011, 15:02 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    THIS (via Alex Tabarrok) is pretty amusing:

    [Former New Mexico Governor Bill] Richardson says that the film and TV subsidy has brought "nearly $4 billion into our economy over eight years" and has created 10,000 jobs. By "our," he means New Mexico. He says every state should emulate this success.

    The joke, I'm sure I don't need to explain, is that not every state can succeed by poaching productions from other states, since what's made in one state can't be made in another. But that's not quite right. A subsidy allows a business to cut prices and artificially raise demand. Given generous enough subsidies, many more movies would be made, and each state could, potentially, have a thriving film industry. This is how higher education works, more or less. New Mexico has state universities just like California and Iowa and Alaska. These schools are understandably viewed as foundations of the local economies in which they're located, as well as important cultural institutions. And we obviously view the subsidisation of the production of college graduates as a worthwhile contribution to long-run growth, again, understandably.

    Yet it's worth thinking about why it's absurd to argue that every state should try to subsidise up a local film industry but not crazy to support local universities. Certainly, there are huge efficiencies being sacrificed by duplicating administrative capacity all around the country. And academics benefit from close proximity to those working on similar problems; the efficacy of research is reduced when it's spread more thinly around the country. If America had fewer, bigger states, it would probably have fewer, bigger universities, and that might well be a very good thing.

    We're all attached to our hometowns and want them to succeed, but efforts to spread economic activity out artificially are costly. It would be better to move more people to the growth than growth than growth to the people.

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Mar 1st 2011, 22:16 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Globalization and the expanding moral circle (Marginal Revolution)

    Working on the railroad (Slate)

    Obama trade plans are stalled (New York Times)

    Annals of white-collar crime (Felix Salmon)

    IMF economists on current account imbalances (Real Time Economics)

  • Privatisation

    Today in helium

    Mar 1st 2011, 22:06 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    IF YOU'RE looking to invest for the long term, consider helium:

    In 1996, Congress passed the Helium Privatization Act, which directed the Secretary of the Interior to sell off the entire Helium Reserve by 2015. Of course, this was at a time when there were more uses for Helium than ever. But here’s the problem: the price that the helium is being sold at in order to deplete the reserves by 2015 is incredibly below market. It’s practically a liquidation sale. But the low prices are necessary in order to meet the Congressional directive to eliminate the helium reserve.

    What’s more, not only is helium being sold below market, but getting rid of the helium reserves is creating a temporary glut in supply. As a consequence, helium is too cheap. Far, far, too cheap. So there’s no incentive to recycle it (possible in industrial applications). Right now, once it’s used, it’s gone.

    As a result, it’s estimated that the world could actually run out of helium in as little as 30 years. It’s because of this that the National Research Council recommended that helium reserve prices be set to market, rather than an arbitrary price, and that some reserves are kept in place. If they’re not, the NRC estimates that the United States could become a net importer of helium, a dwindling resource, within a decade.

    Let me remind everyone again: once the helium is gone, the cheapest way to get more is to get it from the Moon.

    Sadly, the helium never seems to stay in the balloons for very long. Otherwise, I'd have a basement full.

  • Business

    The confidence to compete

    Mar 1st 2011, 19:17 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    NOT long ago, I had occasion to visit a small, independent hardware store in the Washington neighbourhood I used to call home. While checking out, I noticed a flyer taped to the counter, calling on local residents to oppose the planned opening of four Wal-Mart stores around Washington. I first found this perplexing; the store is less than a mile from a massive Home Depot (which I'd patronised earlier in the day); if big-box retail was going to kill the store, it would be dead already. But after reading an anti-Wal-Mart missive from another small business owner, I've been wondering: what message do these guys think they're sending?

    I mean, can you imagine a television station running ads asking you to complain to your government about the existence of other channels? Or if every brand of peanut butter on the shelf carried a sticker demanding that other brands of peanut butter be removed?

    As a customer at the hardware store, I have to say I was a little insulted. The message couldn't be more clear—as a business we're concerned that your decision to seek a better selection of goods at lower prices will force us to close. Actually, I suppose it's worse than that—we think you, enlightened customer, appreciate the benefits of an uncompetitive business enough to deny others the option to buy from a store with more attractive goods and prices than our own. Honestly, what sort of patron is moved to action by the call to kill off the competition?

    Where Wal-Mart is concerned, complainers typically argue that its practices are somehow unfair. Here's Andy Shallal, a local restaurateur who somehow manages to stay in business despite the presence of other nearby food vendors, some of which sell meals at shockingly low prices:

    Some would reason that our most vulnerable neighborhoods, where the stores are planned, are desperately underserved.

    Others argue that low prices are necessary for low-income families.

    Yes, we do need economic development. But Walmart's traditional poverty-level jobs are not the solution. They will continue to depress wages and labor standards and deepen the ranks of the working poor.

    Community leaders and local business owners have started to organize to stop Walmart from coming to D.C. These stakeholders are not lulled by Walmart's newly-polished image.

    Rather than giving in to Walmart's assault, we need a sustainable economy: innovative local businesses, better tax incentives, improved infrastructure and a more prepared work force.

    Local, independent businesses give a neighborhood character. And they create more local jobs, pay more taxes and keep more money in the community.

    Nothing like a rich man arguing that new jobs aren't likely to be good enough for workers who are currently unemployed. Here's the truth. If Washington's poor are able to obtain needed household goods at lower prices, they'll have more money left over to buy other products. Those products could include a coffee at Mr Shallal's business, or healthier food, or a training course that will enable them to find a better job. What's more, Wal-Mart can only pay rock-bottom wages in Washington if there's surplus labour. And if there's surplus labour, well, that may be because businessmen like Mr Shallal are so anxious to shut potential employers out of the city of Washington.

  • Migration trends

    Supply, supply, supply, don't forget supply

    Mar 1st 2011, 16:20 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    WHEN analysing markets, it's important to remember that there is both a supply side and a demand side. Economists know this. But sometimes they forget. Wendell Cox (who is not an economist) could be forgiven for forgetting about the supply side, but Richard Green should know better. The issue is this: Mr Cox looks at the Census 2010 data and reports population growth rates for a handful of central cities relative to their suburbs. Since 2000, he says, suburbs have generally grown faster, and this indicates that the "Back to the City" movement isn't real. Mr Green takes him at his word and writes:

    I have long rooted for cities (although I confess that I myself live in an "urban" suburb). But facts are facts, and the facts from the 2010 census at this point do not support the idea of a reversal from suburbanization to urbanization.

    Well, ok, if someone was arguing that suburbs would empty out while cities grew, then yes, they were mistaken. But I don't think that's the claim that urbanists are generally making. Rather, the suggestion is that demand for central city life has grown relative to demand for suburban life. And the data are consistent with this argument.

    Let me make three brief points. First, the turnaround in central city population dynamics over the past decade is quite dramatic. In 2000, the city of Washington was shedding population, continuing a trend that began decades before. But in the ten years to 2010, the city ended up with a net increase in population of over 30,000 people. (And this is in an area of just 66 square miles.) Washington is not alone. New York City's population is at its highest ever level. Philadelphia's population recently shifted from shrinking to growing. To the extent that population trends tell us something, they indicate a sharp reversal in the migration trend that prevailed for most of the second half of the 20th century.

    But of course, population growth is an unreliable indicator of demand, because of the all important supply side of the market. Imagine two areas: Gotham and Pleasantville. Say the demand to live in Pleasantville increases a little while the demand to live in Gotham soars. And say that due to differences in land use restrictions, housing supply responds dramatically in Pleasantville and very little in Gotham. Then what we'll observe in Pleasantville is a rapid increase in population and slower growth in prices, and what we'll observe in Gotham is rapid growth in prices and slower growth in population. And this is exactly what we have observed in the real world. Suburbs have seen massive housing growth and rapid population growth, but prices in central cities have soared, even in many places where population numbers are level or falling. If no one wanted to live in central cities, prices for homes there would not rise. And indeed, several decades ago, prices for homes in big central cities were dropping. But that trend has clearly reversed. You can't draw conclusions about demand shifts from population numbers alone. This is a very simple point, and yet its repeatedly ignored.

    Finally, it's worth noting that suburban areas are increasingly adding new housing capacity by copying urban development forms. Here in the Washington area, the two largest suburban jurisdictions are Virginia's Fairfax County and Maryland's Montgomery County. Both are in the process of redeveloping major jobs centres from an automobile orientation to tall, dense, walkable, city-like development patterns based around transit.

    Suburbanisation in America was the norm for over a generation, so it's a little early to conclude that these trend breaks represent a new development paradigm. But the data from the past decade are consistent with an increase in demand for city life relative to suburban life.

  • Australia's house prices

    Iron, coal, bricks and mortar

    Mar 1st 2011, 11:06 by S.C. | HONG KONG

    IT PAYS to pick your drinking buddies carefully. It's nice if they enjoy a pint as much as you do. But if they hold their liquor too well, you may wake up regretting trying to keep up with them.

    In the years before the financial crisis, Australia's economy set a hard, fast pace for the rest of the Anglo-Saxon world. Its house prices rose faster than Britain's or America's (although Ireland's outstripped them all) and its current-account deficit gaped wider for longer. But its economy proved strong-livered. House prices fell from March 2008 to March 2009 (as measured by the weighted average of the eight state capitals), then resumed their rise. In the year to the first quarter of 2010, they jumped by 18.8%!

    This week in The Economist we will publish our quarterly index of house prices around the world. Australia's homes are the most overvalued in the index. The ratio of prices to rents in the country is fully 56% above its long-run average (see chart).

    Australia's overvalued housesThe question now is whether Australia's hair of the dog treatment will work, or whether the property market will suffer another bite. Yesterday the RP Data-Rismark index showed prices rising by just 1.2% in the year to January. Compared with the previous month, they fell by 1.6%.

    Many economists in Australia argue that the country's lofty property prices are justfied by a variety of fundamentals. Immigration has swelled the population, and zoning regulations, infrastructure charges and the like have imposed artificial constraints on the availability of land. (I must confess that I smile when I read about land scarcity in Australia. I am writing this from the 60th floor of an office tower in one of the most crowded places in the world. If Australia were as densely populated as Hong Kong, it could accommodate all of the world's people seven times over.)

    These fundamentals no doubt matter. But one of the virtues of a price-to-rent ratio is that it takes them into account. If immigration is putting upward pressure on house prices, it should put upward pressure on rents too. And if developers can't build homes, they can't build rental homes either. Those factors may justify high prices. They don't justify high price-to-rent ratios.

    The difficulty in using these ratios (or any other) as a measure of overvaluation is knowing what the ratio should be—what counts as an equilibrium? In our house-price index we take a simple historical average from 1975 to 2010. But perhaps something has changed in Australia in that time that now warrants a higher ratio. The chart above is certainly suggestive of some kind of structural break after 2000*. If you compare today's price-to-rent ratio with its average over the past ten years, it is overvalued by 12%, not 56%. Compared with its five-year average, it is overvalued by just 3%. 

    If things are different now, why might that be? Low interest rates and financial liberalisation is one answer. But Ireland, Britain and America enjoyed those too. What marks Australia out of course is its extraordinary resource boom. The country's terms of trade (the price it can fetch for its exports, relative to the price it pays for its imports) is at its highest since the 1950s (see chart). So perhaps lucrative exports of iron and coal justify rich valuations for bricks and mortar?

    In a recent paper, Patrizia Tumbarello and Shengzu Wang of the IMF show that a 10% improvement in the terms of trade tends to lift Australian property prices by about 5%. What they don't investigate is whether it raises the ratio of prices to rents. I think it's at least possible that a resource boom affects asset prices, like houses, differently from the price of a service, like rental accommodation. The bright prospects in mining and minerals will attract capital inflows into the resource sector, which might bid up the price of other assets in the economy. And in buying a house, the average Australian might see a way to crystallise the future income he expects will trickle down to him from the commodities boom.

    Thanks to the improvement in the terms of trade, the average Australian's expected lifetime wealth has increased. In theory, he should be able to enjoy some of that windfall in the present, by borrowing against his future gains. But his bank might prefer it if he borrows to buy a concrete, collaterisable house instead. That way, he can either withdraw housing equity, if he wants to consume his future earnings, or accumulate it, if he wants to save them.

    It's a bit like lining your stomach, before you go out drinking.

    *Only suggestive. Charts for Ireland before the crisis looked very similar. See Fig III.4.

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Feb 28th 2011, 22:00 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Unions versus the right to work (Wall Street Journal)

    The overpayers' club (Steve Waldman)

    Commodity shock (Tim Duy)

    The ten most systemically risky banks (Vox)

  • Fiscal reform

    Fix the easy problems first

    Feb 28th 2011, 20:55 by A.S. | NEW YORK

    WHITE HOUSE officials announced last week that we need not worry about Social Security, for now anyway. They reckon it should not be included in the upcoming discussions on how to reduce the deficit. They figure it’s a future problem, so it has no place in a current deficit reduction plan. But entitlements make up almost the entire structural debt problem. That’s far more dangerous than current deficits from discretionary spending. Leaving Social Security off the table means that reform of the programme probably won't happen any time soon. White House Budget Director Jacob Lew and the deputy director of President Barack Obama’s National Economic Council, Jason Furman, explain:

    In a Feb. 22 editorial in USA Today, Lew said the retirement program’s trust fund will have adequate resources to pay full benefits to retirees for the next 26 years, that the nation’s debt “problem is not Social Security” and that strengthening the program should be handled separately.

    Speaking to NDN, a Democratic-leaning advocacy group, Furman said talk of a Social Security overhaul “is not one you care about” if “you are worried about our long-run fiscal future.” He said the program is “the bedrock of retirement security” and solvent for another 26 years, until 2037.

    I am not sure if Messrs Lew and Furman genuinely believe this or if they’re innumerate. It is akin to saying that since I am working now, earning money, and have a new infant who will probably become a millionaire someday and take care of me, I don’t need to save for retirement. It is true Social Security is not currently adding to the deficit. But it is projected to run an actuarial deficit by 2037. Does it threaten to make the American government insolvent? No, but without reform it does add to the structural deficit. If no action is taken, obligations will run to 3.3% of taxable payroll or 1.2% of GDP. Perhaps not a fiscal crisis, but a non-trival amount of spending. These assumptions look far into the future so there is a fair bit of uncertainty, but that's no reason to feel better. They assume that the American economy will experience the same rates of growth it has in the past. If the American birth rate continues to decline the figures will be even larger.

    Restoring long-run solvency will cost money, either in the form of tax increases or benefit cuts, or some combination of the two. The sooner action is taken, the smaller benefit cuts and tax increases must be. Politicians who claim that Social Security is not a problem are really saying they have no qualms about sticking future retirees and taxpayers with an enormous bill and additional retirement insecurity. The alternative is to simply ask everyone to start paying a little more now.

    It is true that Medicare is a bigger fiscal threat and harder to solve, but that does not mean Social Security is not a problem. Ignoring it is like not treating a broken leg because the patient already has cancer. As former budget director Peter Orszag points out, fixing Social Security sends a strong signal to bond markets that America is serious about addressing its long-run debt. What sort of message does it send that America lacks the fiscal discipline to solve even relatively easy problems?

    In addition to the addition cost delay passes to future taxpayers, a refusal to change the programme now also leaves young people with uncertainty regarding a large part of their retirement income. I often hear people say, “Social Security won’t be there for me”. That’s probably not true; the programme will continue in some form. But until credible reform occurs, it’s impossible to know exactly how large a benefit one can expect. This known unknown makes it very difficult to save and invest for retirement. Evidence suggests that Social Security uncertainty does impact investment decisions. Individuals with private pension accounts have enough uncertainty to deal with as is: asset return rates, life expectancy, and so on. Social Security is supposed to be the thing they can count on. It's unfair to kicking that problem down the road.

  • China

    Wen, will there be slower growth?

    Feb 28th 2011, 17:49 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    THIS morning brings news of a seemingly big change in Beijing:

    China's premier said the government wants slower economic growth to avoid inflation and to restructure the economy, even as much of the developed world is struggling to accelerate expansion.

    Premier Wen Jiabao said the government's official target for average gross domestic product growth over the next five years will be 7% annually...

    My, that could dramatically reshape views of the prospects for global rebal...

    ...down from a target of 7.5% in the past half decade.

    Ah, there's the rub. Given that Beijing was perfectly happy to let scorching, double-digit growth occur despite the 7.5% target, it's not clear whether any real shift is in the offing. As the chart at right shows, actual growth has routinely overshot the target in recent decades, and a decline in the government's goal needn't correspond with a drop in growth rates.

    Chinese officials aren't shy about acknowledging this:

    Chinese economists cautioned the 7% goal shouldn't be taken literally, but as a signal to the world and to provincial authorities that the government is serious about shifting the drivers of growth toward domestic consumption.

    Obviously, there are more meaningful metrics available. The dollar exchange rate is one. Inflation is another. One could even follow actual growth to see what growth rates the government is interested in pursuing. I don't doubt that China's leaders are interested in rebalancing the economy and cutting inflation, and I suspect that they might not mind a slightly slower rate of growth if that reduced the potential for instability. But however enlightened China's officials are, their actions are constrained by domestic interests. And it will take more than a target change to build an internal consensus in favour of slower growth.

  • Labour mobility

    Move the people to the growth, not the growth to the people

    Feb 28th 2011, 16:29 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    ON FRIDAY, I attended an event at the Brookings Institution called "State Roads to Economic Recovery". The gist of the programme was pretty clear. Washington is gridlocked. State governments are slashing away at core spending. What can be done to draw some growth-supporting policies out of this mess? If useful actions are likely to emerge from governments, the assumption seemed to be, it's at the state level where the policy experiments will take place, and where good ideas will be found. Though the participants were all fairly clear on what those ideas should include: spare crucial investments in things like education and infrastructure, get more efficient in operation and use of revenue, get more efficient in the raising of revenue, and so on.

    I suppose it ended up being a mildly encouraging event. The great hope is that at least some of the state governments out there will use the crisis as an opportunity to adopt politically difficult policies that are nonetheless very good ideas—things like congestion tolling on crowded roads, or the use of public-private partnerships to build infrastructure. And perhaps some states will rise to the occasion.

    But the thing that kept bugging me throughout the day was the problem in focusing on a state-level approach to recovery. Every state wants to retain residents, retain businesses, invest in key assets, and so on. But one of America's great strengths has historically been its fluid national labour market. When deep recessions hit, labour can move relatively easily from places where conditions are slow to improve to places where recovery is occuring faster. This mobility speeds national adjustments and gets the economy back up to speed faster than would otherwise be the case.

    There was a sort of sideways acknowledgment of this truth whenever the subject of Texas came up. Aside from the advantages of having an oil industry amid high oil prices, what can we learn from Texas' success? Well, that it's an economic boon to absorb several hundred thousand new people when your economy is lagging. The extra demand helps make up for the reduced spending by existing residents, preventing the economy from declining as steeply (thereby attracting still more new residents).

    But not every state can benefit from adding new people (nor should they). One panel featured two officials from the state of Michigan, which has suffered from a long period of decline and which continues to seek ways to right the ship. It would be possible, even easy, to resurrect Michigan. What would it take? Start with a special visa programme, in which skilled immigrants from other countries are offered easier visa terms and an expedited road to citizenship if they accept a visa that requires them to work in the Detroit area for five years. Follow that up by endowing a massive, DARPA-style energy research laboratory in the Detroit area. Set up special venture capital funds that offer excellent loan terms to start-ups connected with the lab or area universities, if they're willing to locate their new business in Michigan. Set up a special economic zone in southeastern Michigan that features an "invisible" border with Canada. Build high-speed rail lines from Detroit to Chicago and Toronto. Do all that, and I guarantee you that Detroit will be growing like mad in ten years. Honestly, even the visa programme alone might generate a turnaround.

    The question is: to what end are we resurrecting Michigan? If the goal is to help the residents of Michigan, it would be much cheaper and easier to do so by investing in those individuals, in order to help them move to more successful local economies. Indeed, without investments in the people of Michigan, it's not clear how much a turnaround in the state's fortunes will benefit existing residents. Many have stayed in the state because they love the place, no doubt, but many others have not left because they're unprepared to find success in growth industries elsewhere. Moving the growth industries to their backyard won't change that fact.

    If you're the governor of a declining state, you can't help but do everything you can to return your state to growth. But it's important to remember that the best thing for the American economy as a whole will often be for people to leave lagging areas.

  • Recommended economics writing

    Weekend link exchange

    Feb 28th 2011, 0:41 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    The debate that's muting the Fed's response (New York Times)

    The things we teach that aren't true (Scott Sumner)

    Why New Keynesian macroeconomists are against labour unions (Worthwhile Canadian Initiative)

    On the stimulus package (Econbrowser)

    Do mayors matter? (New Republic)

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Feb 25th 2011, 21:38 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Avoiding the coming growth slowdown (Brink Lindsey)

    College costs aren't the main problem (Economix)

    The economic silly season is upon us (Wall Street Journal)

    Are friends important in educational outcomes? (Vox)

  • Growth

    A disappointing day

    Feb 25th 2011, 14:07 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    I AM attending a conference this morning, and so blogging will be light. But let me draw your attention to two stories before I go. First, America's fourth quarter GDP growth has been revised down:

    Real gross domestic product -- the output of goods and services produced by labor and property located in the United States -- increased at an annual rate of 2.8 percent in the fourth quarter of 2010, (that is, from the third quarter to the fourth quarter), according to the "second" estimate released by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. In the third quarter, real GDP increased 2.6 percent...

    The downward revision to the percent change in real GDP primarily reflected an upward revision to imports and downward revisions to state and local government spending and to personal consumption expenditures (PCE) that were partly offset by an upward revision to exports.

    And Britain's economy shrank by more than initially thought:

    Britain’s economy shrank more than initially estimated in the fourth quarter, complicating the task of the Bank of England as a split deepens among policy makers on whether to withdraw stimulus.

    Gross domestic product fell 0.6 percent from the previous three months, compared with an initial estimate for a 0.5 percent drop, the Office for National Statistics said today in London. The statistics office said its “best estimate” for the impact of cold weather on the data remains 0.5 percent. The slump was led by construction and investment.

    The American data helps explain labour market figures that looked unusually bad given growth. In both cases, the fiscal and monetary authorities should be asking themselves whether they've overestimated the performance of these economies and their ability to handle big, and largely unnecessary, short-term budget cuts.

  • On the American Economic Review

    Eleven things I learned at work this week

    Feb 24th 2011, 22:43 by S.C. | HONG KONG

    IN THE course of writing this week's Economics focus about the 20 best papers ever published in the American Economic Review, I learned that:

    1. Some acronyms age better than others.
    2. Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz once made a case for taxing American football and subsidising opera. (See p.307)
    3. Paul Douglas of Cobb-Douglas fame was a remarkable man. (A Quaker, he nonetheless joined the Marines at the age of 50, earning two purple hearts, before serving three terms as Martin Luther King Jr's favourite senator. Most memorable, however, were his prewar tussles with his fellow Chicago aldermen, "the smartest bunch of bastards I ever saw grouped together").
    4. Remarkable though Douglas was, he and Charles Cobb did not invent the Cobb-Douglas production function.
    5. Even if they had, perhaps they shouldn't have.
    6. There's nothing new under the blistering sun. On p.48, Thomas Means, a former project engineer with Truckee-Carlson, anticipates Hernando de Soto by about 75 years. And on p.947/8 does Kenneth Arrow not anticipate John Rawls?
    7. Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller thought whole milk was better than skimmed. (See p.279)
    8. The word "adverse" in the term "adverse selection" is an adjective not an adverb.* (See p.964)
    9. The average bill for surgery in Birmingham, Alabama, in 1953 was $99. (See p.963)
    10. This I already knew: the third part of Friedrich Hayek's 1945 article, "The Use of Knowledge in Society", is one of the best intellectual tributes ever paid to society's chancers, opportunists and wheeler-dealers. Being in the right place at the right time, argues Hayek, is quite as socially useful as being the "right" man for the job in some abstract sense.
    11. The 20 best papers in the AER's history average about 1.3 numbered equations per page

    * Update: I realise that's a bit cryptic, or possibly illiterate. All I mean is that the term refers not to the process of selecting adversely, it refers to the result: an adverse selection. 

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Feb 24th 2011, 22:20 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Climate reformists challenge old economic models (Grist)

    On the macro effects of higher oil prices (Macroadvisers)

    China's January inflation (Michael Pettis)

    Private hiring and government layoffs (Economix)

  • Labour unions

    What's the goal?

    Feb 24th 2011, 22:13 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    A NUMBER of critics of pro-labour leftists have pointed out the ways in which labour unions have impeded important reforms in recent years. Perhaps, responds Kevin Drum, but if you look at the language used by anti-labour Republicans, you see that crushing labour isn't about clearing a path to reform. It's about something more like defeating a spiritual enemy. So maybe we shouldn't cheer their fight against unions as a step toward a better run state.

    But let's turn the question around. To many without a dog in the labour fight, the outpouring of support for unionised workers in Wisconsin looks like cheering for one's own team. That impulse is understandable, but what lies behind it? What's the end to which stronger unions is a means?

    In a long piece at Mother Jones, Mr Drum gives some sense of what he's looking for:

    If unions had remained strong and Democrats had continued to vigorously press for more equitable economic policies, middle-class wages over the past three decades likely would have grown at about the same rate as the overall economy—just as they had in the postwar era. But they didn't, and that meant that every year, the money that would have gone to middle-class wage increases instead went somewhere else. This created a vast and steadily growing pool of money, and the chart below gives you an idea of its size. It shows how much money would have flowed to different groups if their incomes had grown at the same rate as the overall economy. The entire bottom 80 percent now loses a collective $743 billion each year, thanks to the cumulative effect of slow wage growth. Conversely, the top 1 percent gains $673 billion. That's a pretty close match. Basically, the money gained by the top 1 percent seems to have come almost entirely from the bottom 80 percent.

    Underlying this argument is the view that changes in the income distribution over the past few decades had everything to do with power and nothing to do with anything else. It suggests that growth produces a pool of money which is then divided among citizens based on their clout in Washington. But this is not a very realistic description of recent economic history. As Mr Drum acknowledges, manufacturing employment has declined steadily, and this has been true across the rich world. Labour unions were powerless to prevent it, except by closing off the American economy. And the loss of manufacturing jobs meant the end of a unique era, in which a large share of the population could earn a healthy paycheque doing work that didn't require a college education.

    And so several trends have buffeted all of the rich world. Inequality has grown as the demand for skills has increased while college completion has leveled off. Top inequality has grown in no small part because of the rise of superstars; it's easier than ever for an individual talent to turn themselves into a global megabrand. And yes, part of the rise in incomes at the very top has been due to a related effect: the ability of a small group of people to manage enormous sums of money and take home eye-popping returns.

    But is this what labour is about: finding the political will to tax billionaires at a higher rate? Perhaps a worthy cause, but not the sort of thing on which one builds a middle class. Is it to look more like Europe? Inequality has grown there, as well, though transfers have mitigated the impacts. But in Europe, incomes and growth are also lower, and many countries are saddled with unsustainable budgets. I think there is a workable northern European model of higher taxes, stronger safety nets, freer markets, richer populations, and more equal distributions of income. But these goals are often achieved at a cost, like reduced immigration. Neither is it clear that America ever had the political temperament to move toward such a model.

    I can imagine a world in which better and more equitable decisions were taken in recent decades, and I can imagine that a larger union presence would have facilitated some of those better decisions. I can also imagine unions blocking others that might have been justified. Who knows what the net result would have been. But one thing seems clear—labour supporters in the grip of nostalgianomics (not my coinage) are doing too little to grapple with the real economic changes that have taken place alongside and accelerated union decline.

  • Fiscal policy

    Cutting recovery short

    Feb 24th 2011, 19:10 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    REPUBLICANS are pushing to slash federal government spending in the present fiscal year. If they don't get their way, the government will shut down. And if they do get their way?

    Spending cuts approved by House Republicans would act as a drag on the U.S. economy, according to a Wall Street analysis that put new pressure on the political debate in Washington.

    The report by the investment firm Goldman Sachs said the cuts would reduce the growth in gross domestic product by up to 2 percentage points this year, essentially cutting in half the nation's projected economic growth for 2011.

    That's just one estimate, of course. It's also possible that the Fed would react to these deep cuts by pursuing a more expansionary monetary policy than they'd planned, but the British example suggests that rising commodity prices may make this balancing act difficult.

    What really makes this so upsetting, and it's really, genuinely upsetting, is that these proposed cuts are basically useless. America doesn't face a short-term fiscal crisis; its debt is dirt cheap. America faces a long-term fiscal crisis due to projected increases in government health spending. So Republicans are cutting short-term discretionary spending to address a fiscal crisis that doesn't exist while ignoring the fiscal crisis that does exist. Their proposed cuts aren't emerging from any cost-benefit analysis; rather they seem designed to spare GOP interests at the expense of Democratic interests. And to do this, they're prepared to—potentially—cost the American economy 2 percentage points of growth.

    It's really remarkable. It's remarkable how things have deteriorated in so short a time. Last year, the president's bipartisan deficit commission recommended deficit cuts that didn't focus on the short-term, and that did put defence and entitlements on the table. Now Republicans are declaring that they'll shut down the government unless all of their demands are met—demands with virtually no redeeming value. This is no way to govern. No way at all.

  • Oil prices

    The markets watch the revolution, cont.

    Feb 24th 2011, 16:47 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    CONDITIONS have deteriorated in Libya, where open civil war appears to have broken out. Some of Libya's oil production has been disrupted, and prices continue to rise around the world. How serious are matters? Economist James Hamilton, who has done extensive work on the relationship between oil prices and business cycles, writes:

    My bottom line is that events as they have unfolded so far are not in the same ballpark as the major historical oil supply disruptions, and are unlikely to produce big enough economic multipliers that they could precipitate a new economic downturn. They might shave a half percent off annual GDP growth, but I don't anticipate a whole lot worse than that.

    And I think that's right. It's a little worrying that Treasury yields continue to fall, along with non-energy commodity prices and equity prices, but so far these shifts are not nearly as large as they were during the first months of the European crisis last year.

    But Mr Hamilton also notes:

    But the worry of course is that the big geopolitical changes we've been seeing didn't stop with Tunisia, and didn't stop with Egypt. So maybe it's not a good idea to assume it's all going to stop with Libya, either.

    The interesting thing about recent market moves is that they're pricing in the possibility that instability speads. And it well might. But for now, all eyes are on Libya, where the primary danger is not to the global economy but to those caught in the conflict.

  • Financial markets

    Why we do want stocks to go up?

    Feb 24th 2011, 14:42 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    IF YOU'RE planning on buying a lot of something in the near future, it's bad when the price of that something rises. No question about that. Millions of Americans are now in the workforce, taking a slice of each month's paycheque and using it to purchase equities, and many of them (like me) will continue to do this for the next few decades. If prices shoot up now and then plateau, that's bad. We all earn less on our investment. Ideally, stocks would fall to rock bottom levels then skyrocket the day we hand in our retirement notice. Right? So argues Felix Salmon:

    [M]ost of the people cheering for the stock market to go up are in the accumulation phase of their careers, not the spending phase. They’re still putting money into retirement funds, and they aren’t intending on spending it for decades. So why are they so happy when stocks go up, and sad when stocks go down? Shouldn’t it be the other way around?...

    The main reason...is simply psychological. If asset prices go up, that means people with assets are richer, and have made money in the markets. If you’re rich and you’ve made money, that makes you happy. Even if over the long term you’d be better off if you were able to continue buying bargains.

    I don't think this is really that complicated. Equity prices reflect a lot of things but they're a pretty good gauge of expectations of future corporate profitability. And corporate profitability is closely related to growth. In early 2009, the S&P 500 hit its lowest level in over a decade. People were unhappy with that, and not primarily because they felt less rich or because they foolishly didn't realise that they had the bargain opportunity of a lifetime. They were unhappy because it signalled that expectations for growth had plummeted; economic conditions, broadly speaking, were awful. Similarly, when markets rose thereafter, people were happy not just because they felt richer or because they foolishly didn't realise that they'd missed the bargain of a lifetime, but because rising share prices were a highly visible indicator of rising growth expectations.

    In a bad economy, shares are a bargain, but many more households are financially stressed. During the downturn, millions of unemployed workers obviously weren't plowing money into their 401(k)s. Other households cut back their contributions to make ends meet, and some had to take money out of savings funds to pay the bills. Given the choice between being flush enough to save in expensive savings vehicles and being too broke to save in cheap savings vehicles, most folks are going to opt for the former. So I don't think it's at all strange that people like a rising market, whether or not they're in the saving portion of their life.

  • Recommended economics writing

    Link exchange

    Feb 23rd 2011, 21:58 by R.A. | WASHINGTON

    TODAY'S recommended economics writing:

    Four fallacies of the crisis (Project Syndicate)

    Chicago economist's crazy idea wins backing (Bloomberg)

    Divine coincidence failure (Worthwhile Canadian Initiative)

    Why budget cuts don't bring prosperity (New York Times)

    Cooking up trouble (Vox)

About Free exchange

In this blog, our correspondents consider the fluctuations in the world economy and the policies intended to produce more booms than busts.

Advertisement

Advertisement

Latest blog posts - All times are GMT

Kabuki comes home
From Asia view - 1 hrs 55 mins ago
Link exchange
From Free exchange - March 2nd, 21:42
An abundance of activity
From Multimedia - March 2nd, 21:14
About that Goldman estimate
From Free exchange - March 2nd, 21:10
More from our blogs »
Products & events
Stay informed today and every day

Subscribe to The Economist's free e-mail newsletters and alerts.


Subscribe to The Economist's latest article postings on Twitter


See a selection of The Economist's articles, events, topical videos and debates on Facebook.

Advertisement