Financial markets

Buttonwood's notebook

  • Stockmarkets

    The buy-back delusion

    May 25th 2011, 16:21 by Buttonwood

    THE belief that share buy-backs are a universally good thing seems hard to shake, even though there was a time when they were seen as a sign of the lack of imagination in a company's management. But an excellent paper from Terry Smith, who made his fortune in the city as a broker but who was once an analyst who wrote a hard-hitting book called Accounting for Growth, puts buy-backs in their proper perspective.

    If two identical companies decide to return cash to shareholders, one via a buy-back and the other via a dividend, the earnings per share of the first group (but not the latter) will rise. This will create the impression that the first group has added value. But the return on equity of both groups will be unchanged! This can lead to potentially confusing outcomes.

    Mr Smith suggests the example of Fred Futile, the CEO of Stagnant Inc. He is awarded a 10-year option over the company's stock at the current price of $100 per share. There are initially 100m shares in issue and annual earnings are $1 billion. So he cancels the dividend and uses all the earnings (which remain flat throughout the 10 years) to buy back shares; earnings per share rise and the p.e remains the same. By the end of the 10-year period, the eps will have more than doubled from $10 to $25.8 and the share price will have risen to $258, earning Fred Futile $158m for himself. But the company isn't really more valuable, it's just more geared*.

    If you are not convinced by that example, here is another one. Smith uses the real life example of Pepsi which bought back almost $5 billion of its shares in 2008. This strategy enhanced its eps (albeit in the sense of lessening an eps fall). But what would have happened had Pepsi used the same money to buy shares in Coke, which had a similar p/e ratio to Pepsi? Then the accounting treatment would have changed; instead of reducing the number of shares in issue, the investments on Pepsi's balance sheet would have grown. The eps would not have been bolstered by this approach; more significantly, the return on equity would have fallen.

    That is because Pepsi earned a return on equity of 34%. Buying shares in Coke (or itself) on a p/e of around 20 is, in effect, generating a return of just 5% (the earnings yield is the inverse of the p/e). In short, such a purchase destroys value.

    Perhaps this is more obvious when one considers a common reason for buy-backs; to mop-up the shares created by option issuance. Executives wouldn't be exercising their options unless they were going to make a profit. So companies are selling shares to executives at a low price and buying them back at a higher one.

    This buy high, sell low policy is symbolic of the buy-back era. run a graph (as Smith does) of the S&P 500 against buy-back activity and you will see that activity goes up and down with the market. Executives are not bargain-hunters, except on their own account.

    But isn't there evidence that companies that experience buy-backs outperform the market? Yes there is, but Smith has a useful caveat. This outperformance is concentrated in the value stocks, those with the lowest price-to-book value. if the company can buy its shares back below book value, then that is indeed a good deal.

    That, however, is one of the key questions shareholders should ask. Mr Smith's rules are

    Share buy-backs should only be used if the stock is trading at below its economic value and the repurchase represents the best use of cash available

    You cannot create value by buying back overvalued shares

    Companies should be required to justify the price and returns on repurchases as they would on acquisitions or other investments

    Shares repurchased should be left on the balance sheet as an asset and equity accounted

    * Corporate finance theory would suggests the rating should fall as the company gets more risky. But it may well not fall sufficiently to offset Futile's strategy; after all this company is growing its eps.

  • Profit margins and wages

    What about the workers?

    May 25th 2011, 10:39 by Buttonwood

    BCA Research has some remarkable statistics in its research note on profit margins (no link available, I'm afraid). Since 1990, real domestic corporate profits in America have risen 200%, while real compensation for corporate employees has increased just 20% and real median family incomes are up just 2% (is this the American dream?). Since 2000, the relevant statistics are 80%, 8% and minus 5% respectively.

    Profit margins in the non-financial sector as measured by ebitd (earnings before interest, tax and depreciation) are as high as they have been at any moment in the last 50 years. there was a big drop in margins in the 1970s as wage and commodity costs soared and it has only been in the past decade that profits have returned to 1960s level. what was remarkable about the 2007-2008 subprime crisis is the speed with which margins have rebounded.

    BCA cites a number of factors to explain the rebound from aggressive cost-cutting, the use of technology, to a sharp rise in overseas margins arising from a weaker dollar and some "tax-planning" measures that routed profits to low-tax countries. On the basis of this analysis BCA concludes that

    it will be extremely hard for margins to rise further from current levels. Yet the trend in margins tends to follow the economic cycle, so it would be unusual for margins to weaken sharply in the absence of a marked slowdown in the pace of economic growth.

    Of course, a slowdown in growth might be just what's occurring at the moment.

    So why haven't workers got more of the pie? The conventional economic assumption is that compensation should keep pace with productivity. But the productivity gains have accrued to employers not employees. However BCA find that if you compared compensation with corporate prices (which companies get from selling their goods), the fit is much closer than with the consumer price index. Corporate prices have risen slowly because they are dominated by capital goods, where technology and China have kept the lid on increases. The consumer price index, by contrast, contains a lot more services where international competition is more constrained. I am not sure that this explanation is entirely satisfying - companies sell services too.

    For the lowest-paid workers, things have been getting worse not better as they spend more of their incomes on food and energy, where inflation over the last year has been particularly strong. The divergent trend between profits and incomes brings us to the Marxist question of whether demand eventually collapses because workers cannot afford to buy the goods that capitalists produce. This crisis was averted in the 1990s and 2000s because consumers borrowed money to maintain spending - an option that is no longer very popular. So if the economy is to prosper in the next few years, it seems likely that the workers will have to get a better deal - and profit margins will have to take a hit.

  • US pension funds

    From bad to worse

    May 24th 2011, 15:52 by Buttonwood

    IF YOU thought last year's rebound in the stockmarket improved the finances of US state pension funds, think again. A new report from the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College found that the official funded ratio fell from 79% to 77% last year. The counter-intuitive effect is caused by the mysteries of actuarial valuation; actuaries smooth asset values over five years so while 2010 delivered positive returns, it was not as good a year as 2005, which dropped out of the five year numbers.

    But the news is actually worse than that. This ratio is based on the official rate for discounting liabilities of around 8%, which in turn is derived from the expected return on assets. This is absurd on two counts. First, with 10 year Treasury bonds yielding 3.1%, the equity portion of a pension portfolio is going to have to return double digits to generate 8% on the whole lot. With a dividend yield of around 2%, that implies annual dividend growth of at least 8%, way too high in a low-inflation economy. Second, as the report states,

    Standard financial theory suggests that future streams of payment should be discounted at a rate that reflects their risk. In the case of state and local pension plans, the risk is the uncertainty about whether payments will need to be made. Since these benefits are protected under most state laws, the payments are, as a practical matter, guaranteed. Consequently to assess accurately the status of a plan warrants discounting its stream of future benefits by the risk-free interest rate.

    The CRR uses a risk-free rate of 5% which looks arbitrarily high but is still sufficient to turn official liabilities of $3.5 trillion into $5.2 trillion and to reduce the funding ratio to 51%. In short, the states have put aside only half the money they need.

    Such a shortfall would seem to require a period of catch-up. The annual required contribution has risen from 6.1% of payroll in 2002 to 13.5% this year, according to the CRR (and that is using the 8% discount rate). But constrained local finances mean that states are not paying up even on this basis; they are only stumping up 78% of the required contribution, down from 92% in 2008. (They haven't paid in full since 2001.)

    The legal protection granted to pension rights mean that the best way for states to cut the bull is to reduce their payrolls or freeze salaries. This seems a rum bargain. Perhaps employees might be willing to trade less secure pension rights for the ability to hang on to their jobs until they retire.

  • Sovereign debt crisis

    What rescue?

    May 24th 2011, 12:13 by Buttonwood

    IMAGINE if, one year after the Tarp scheme was unveiled to bail out the banking sector, bank shares had been even lower than before. But that is the position of European government bond yields in the affected countries. The setting up of a bailout fund in May 2010 was not the "shock and awe" package that the authorities had hoped for.  Yields on Greek, Irish and Portuguese debt are all higher, not lower.

    In part, that is because the EU has treated this as a liquidity issue, not a solvency one. They have hoped that buying time will create the scope for the government concerned to tackle their deficits and the banks time to protect themselves from default. (Similarly, the US authorities though that, after the rescue of Bear Stearns in the spring of 2008, the market would have braced itself for the failure of Lehman. That turned out to be wrong.) Private sector creditors may also be reasoning that the greater the level of official support, the more subordinated the claims of the private sector will become.

    The most worrying element for the authorities is the two countries at the bottom end of this scale; Italy and Spain. They are much larger than the three countries that have already been rescued. But, as you can see, yields have been drifting up; the Spanish cost of debt is at a 10-year high. This can be an awkward spiral; the higher the cost of debt, the more difficult it is for countries to banish their budget; the more difficult it is to balance the budget, the higher the cost of debt. The heavy defeat suffered by the Spanish government in regional elections also indicated that electorates may not be willing to endure the kind of sacrifices demanded by creditors.

    If Europe is headed towards a choice between default and fiscal union, we have already seen in Germany and Finland that electorates in creditor nations may not be willing to grant the kind of subsidies that debtors might require. 

    UPDATE: Meanwhile, on the slowdown front, eurozone industrial orders fell 1.8% in March, and Belgian business confidence declined again (although a small country, Belgium is a useful bellwether, placed between the French and German giants). However the Ifo survey of German business sentiment held up well. One should also note that gold reached a new nominal high in euro terms; the currency bears have switched their attention from the dollar to the euro. Foreign exchange markets remain a battle of the weaklings.

  • Global economy and markets

    Speed bumps

    May 23rd 2011, 9:22 by Buttonwood

    YET more signs of a global slowdown today. The Chinese purchasing managers' index dropped to 51.1 in May (from 51.8) in April, prompting the Shanghai stockmarket to lose its gains for the year. In Europe, the composite index fell to a still-healthy 55.4 but the drop was greater than expected; it looks as if the strong momentum in the first quarter is fading.

    The eurozone debt crisis looks no nearer resolution. Greece was downgraded three notches by Fitch while Standard & Poor's placed Italy on negative watch. (Italy has avoided the kind of negative scrutiny showed Spain although it has a much higher government debt-to-GDP ratio.) More seriously, perhaps, the last week has highlighted a huge rift in the European establishment. Some politicians have been edging towards the possibility of restructuring of Greek debt, by floating the idea of reprofiling the debt, i.e. giving the Greeks longer to pay on the hope, like Mr Micawber, that "something will turn up". This has outraged the ECB, which has bought acquired Greek debt and provided loans to Greek banks, with such debt as collateral. But the Greeks cannot pay their debts on their own; the choice is between default and subsidy from other European countries. If the first is unacceptable to the ECB, then the second may prove unacceptable to European voters.

    The eurozone crisis is, in a sense, the unfinished business of 2007-2008. Debt was passed up the chain, from individuals to banks to governments and now from poor governments to rich ones. But the slowdown may also turn out to be a postscript to the subrpime crisis.

    The global scale of the easing of monetary and fiscal policy was probably unprecedented. Risk assets rallied in the spring of 2009 when it was clear what the authorities were doing. This easing had a lagged effect which was probably at its strongest in 2010; now the effects may be fading. Homeowners benefited once from lower mortgage rates but they cannot benefit any further since there is no scope to lower official rates. Fiscal policy is only stimulative if governments are spending more (or taxing less) than they were a year ago; again there is little more than the authorities are willing to do.

    Here the link between the Chinese and American economies may be crucial. We know that the Chinese have been doing - tightening policy. This may be why commodity prices have been falling. And slower Chinese growth would in turn affect the German export machine. Meanwhile US policymakers have reached an impasse on fiscal matters while, on monetary policy, the Fed looks set to wait and see what happens after the end of QE2. In short, official policy has turned from a tailwind into a headwind. Add in Europe's mess and it is hardly surprising that equity markets are heading lower today.

    UPDATE: There is an interesting piece in American Prospect which suggests that, even after August 2 when the Treasury may run out of wiggle room on the debt ceiling, the Fed may be forced to extend an overdraft to the Treasury. That is because of the 14th amendment which says that

    The validity of the public debt of the United States, authorized by law, including debts incurred for payment of pensions and bounties for services in suppressing insurrection or rebellion, shall not be questioned.

    In other words, the Fed would be breaching the Constitution if it didn't allow the government to meet its debts. Mind you, there isn't much sign as yet that the markets are worrying too much about this issue, on the assumption that the politicians will cobble together a deal.

  • LinkedIn and the end of the world

    Rational man?

    May 20th 2011, 7:54 by Buttonwood

    AS LinkedIn closes its first day of trading on a valuation of 36 times sales, some of us can feel a wave of nostalgia coming on. Restricted float? Yep. Only 10% of the stock was on offer. New valuation method? Check. The FT says the stock is valued at "more than $100 per user". Remember "price-per-click" and all that nonsense? It is possible that your blogger is listed as one of those users; I had to join once to try and track down the landlord of some noisy neighbours. The revenue LinkedIn has (and will) generate from me is zero, save if it sells my name on a mailing list in which case the purchaser of that list will face a disappointment.

    Back in 1999 and 2000, of course, it was argued that dotcom mania wasn't a bubble because investors were rationally pricing in the future growth prospects of the companies concerned.

    But who are these rational men? The London Times today reports that Harold Camping, a former engineer and radio preacher, is predicting that the world will end tomorrow (rather a blow for those who bought LinkedIn shares) after a massive earthquake in New Zealand. All this was forecast in the Bible, Mr Camping has calculated, written a couple of thousands of years before New Zealand was discovered by Europeans and given that name. Some calculation.

    Now, of course, these kinds of eccentrics come around quite regularly. More alarming was the paper's report that

    30 to 40 per cent of (Americans) regularly tell pollsters that the Bible contains a specific timetable for the end of the world

    If you believe that, a price-per-user ratio of $100 may seem quite reasonable. Now some academics would argue that there may well be naive investors in the market but they merely provide the cannon fodder for the smart money that drive prices back into line. But Sir Isaac Newton also thought he could calculate the end of the world by analysing the Bible text. He also lost a fortune in the South Sea Bubble.

    So if one of the smartest men in history can be that irrational, what does that say about the rest of us?

    UPDATE: Perhaps Mr Camping is onto something. Here is the Centre for Disease Control advising citizens on what to do in the face of a zombie apocalypse. For example

    Plan your evacuation route. When zombies are hungry they won’t stop until they get food (i.e., brains), which means you need to get out of town fast!

    Apparently, the advice also works for hurricanes and earthquakes. And Mr Camping might want his own evacuation route by Sunday.

    SECOND UPDATE: In response to queries, I couldn't find the source of the poll quoted by the Times. But I did find this round-up of surveys saying that 24% of Americans thought the second coming would occur in their lifetime and that 52% thought it would occur between 2000 and 3000 CE indicating that they have a specific timetable in mind.

  • Intellectuals

    The poet speaks

    May 19th 2011, 15:05 by Buttonwood

    FURTHER to my colleague's trenchant views on intellectuals and DSK, I couldn't help recalling a verse from WH Auden

    To the man in the street, who I'm sorry to say/ Is a keen observer of life

    The word intellectual suggests straight away/A man who's untrue to his wife

  • Stockmarket valuation

    In defence of the Shiller p/e

    May 18th 2011, 12:36 by Buttonwood

    EVER since the publication of the book Irrational Exuberance, there have been critics of Robert Shiller's cyclically adjusted p/e ratio. The chart here is a reprint from my post two weeks ago but you can find all the data on the Professor's website.

    It wasn't actually a new idea on Shiller's part. Ben Graham, the value investor who was Warren Buffett's guru, had suggested a similar measure, involving the averaging of profits over an extended period to smooth out the effects of the economic cycle. Investors were paying little attention in the late 1990s. As the chart shows, the US market in the late 1990s was even more overvalued than it was before the crash of 1929. This was not a welcome message at the time when analysts talked of a "new era" and even speculated that the cycle had been abolished.

    But even though the Shiller p/e accurately predicted that the market was overdue for a fall, there are still many critics who today refuse to accept its message. That is because, as you can see, the ratio is close to one of its 20th century peaks in the mid-1960s, which preceded the long bear market of the 1970s.

    The ratio presupposes that profits revert to some sort of a mean, at least as a proportion of GDP. Some critics argue that things have changed in that capital is strongly placed relative to labour, thanks to factors such as competition from the Far East and the decline of trade union power. But even if that were the case, the ratio ought still to be mean-reverting. That is because of the nature of capitalism itself. If profit margins are high, then new businesses will be created to try to capture those profits (or existing businesses will expand); the resulting competition will drive margins back down. High profit margins could be maintained in a world of monopolies but globalisation, the same factor cited by profit bulls, erodes monopolies; if Chinese competition is depressing wages, it is also affecting the prices charged by western manufacturers.

    Stockmarket bulls prefer to look at the prospective price-earnings ratio, based on next year's profits. But there are many problems with this. First, analysts almost always forecast double-digit profits gains but profits cannot grow that fast in a world of 5-6% nominal GDP growth. The stockbrokers are very bad at forecasting downturns. In addition, bulls often use a sleight of hand that compares the prospective p/e (based on higher earnings) with the average of the historic p/e, based on the previous year's figures. Such comparisons are designed to make the market look cheap.

    A more plausible criticism is that profits in the early 20th century were not calculated on a similar basis, so one is comparing apples with pears. But this argument is also unconvincing. After the events of Enron and WorldCom, one can hardly claim that profits are not manipulated today; surely modern executives, motivated as they are by share options, have the incentive to overstate profits whereas those in the early 20th century might have been trying to avoid the taxman and thus understating them.

    A related argument is that valuations from the early 20th century are "irrelevant" because of world wars, depressions and the like. One could retort that valuations from the 1980s and 1990s are irrelevant because central banks were inflating a bubble. But the better reply is that one should only deal with the data presented; not exclude chunks of it. We can't predict events. People in 1910 didn't know they were going to have a world war and a depression in the next 25 years; Japanese investors in 1990 might have though they were set for two more decades of prosperity but they were wrong. 

    For those who doubt the valuation measure, why not look at other long-term approaches. the dividend yield is not 100% reliable; in 1932, at the market low, the stockmarket yields was very low because dividends had been slashed. But by and large, a high dividend yield is a sign of a cheap market and a low yield an expensive one; the yield on the S&P 500, according to ThomsonReuters is 2.3%, at the bottom end of the range. (Careful about arguments that you should add in a bit for share buybacks; you should offset such purchases with issuance of new equity in the form of options.)

    Another approach is the q ratio, outlined by Andrew Smithers and Stephen Wright in their book Valuing Wall Street, which came out at the same time as Shiller's opus. This compares the value of the market with the net replacement cost of corporate assets. It too is a controversial measure because of data issues but it has a mean-reverting logic of its own. When market prices are above asset values, it will be cheaper for investors to buy assets directly than it will be for them to invest in equities; arbitrage will eventually drive the two back in line. And the Q ratio, although compiled on a different basis from Shiller's approach, shows a remarkably similar picture of peaks and troughs, including the current overvaluation. 

    In short, if you don't like what Shiller is telling you, it is because you are a bull who thinks "this time is different".

    PS Finally, a couple of links. The first is a piece on the use of statistics and the dangers that face those who try to blog honestly on such a partisan issue as tax. Some of the stuff written on the DSK saga is quite amazing as my colleague Schumpeter points out in typically rollicking style. And there is more justified outrage here and here. As to the argument of the "intellectual" that that New York chambermaids arrive in brigades, not singly, words fail me but not this columnist.

  • The IMF, the global economy and British inflation

    One cheer for the Chinese

    May 17th 2011, 10:51 by Buttonwood

    IT IS not often that one finds oneself agreeing whole-heartedly with the Chinese government, but its call for the selection of the next head of the IMF to be based on "fairness, transparency and merit" is quite right. Now perhaps Beijing can apply those principles to its treatment of the artist Ai Weiwei. It was disappointing to see Wolfgang Munchau of the FT plug the idea of another European head today, particularly his suggestion of Christine Lagarde who seems in denial about Greece's problems. Mr Munchau writes that

    in assessing their merits, we should take into account that the new IMF chief will deal with largely European issues for most of their first term.

    That ought to be a dubious argument in the eyes of the rest of the world; when deciding to bail out countries from a continent, why is the ideal IMF head someone from that continent? I don't recall that the Europeans made a strong case for having a Latin American head of the IMF in the 1980s or an Asian one in the 1990s, when those continents faced debt crises. No, they just kept the job within the region as they have since 1945.

    Meanwhile, there were more signs of a slowdown today with a fall in the ZEW index of German economic confidence. And there was more bad news in Britain where consumer inflation rose to an annual rate of 4.5% (the monthly increase was a full percentage point) and core inflation hit a 14-year high. Mervyn King, the governor of the Bank of England, had to write another letter to the chancellor saying he missed the inflation target. perhaps he should just send a copy of Britney Spears's single every month: "Oops, I did it again."

    UPDATE: Mohammed El-Erian of Pimco has written about the IMF issue. Describing the previous process as "feudal" he adds that

    the post of Managing Director should be open to all nationalities, with candidates assessed on the basis of transparent job qualifications. It should also involve an internationally balanced committee to evaluate applicants and put forward 2-3 finalists for Executive Board consideration, and the final choice should emerge from a fair vote of the Board.

    Exactly.

    SECOND UPDATE: And agreement from the Chilean finance minister, interviewed on Ft.com today. Perhpas he is even a reader since he says that

    “We didn’t hear similar arguments for a Latin American candidate during the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s or an Asian candidate during the Asian crisis,” he said.
  • Global economy

    More slowdown signs

    May 16th 2011, 15:04 by Buttonwood

    LAST Friday's post showed that the global purchasing managers index (particularly for the service sector) was heading rapidly down towards 50, the flexpoint between expansion and contraction. There are more signs today. Bloomberg reports that analysts' forecasts for European profits growth have been revised down by four percentage points this year. Meanwhile, in the US, the Empire State index of manufacturing in New York fell from 21.7 to 11.9, including a fall in the new orders index. The OECD lead indicator has been turning down quite sharply.

    David Shairp of J P Morgan Asset Management notes another sign; the real yield on the 10-year TIPS has dropped from 1.4% in February to 0.75%. By and large, one would expect real yields to reflect growth expectations. (The primary reason is probably that if growth expectations are high, then investors will want a more exciting asset class than index-linked bonds. The real yield will have to rise in compensation.)  The fall in real yields thus reflects concern about the growth outlook.

    The case for slower growth is not yet overwhelming. For example, the latest evidence for American profits forecasts I have seen (dated early May) shows that forecasts are still being revised higher.

    Still one has to wonder about those forecasts. American profits are relatively high as a proportion of GDP. Paul Marson of Lombard Odier also points out that US margins are currently high. Over the long run, one would expect margins to mean revert, if only because high returns on capital will attract new businesses and the subsequent competition will drive returns back down again. there is a very good and negative link, Mr Marson finds, between high margins and subsequent profits growth.

    Over the next 5 years, current elevated margins imply negative nominal net profit growth.

    But that won't be reflected in analysts' forecasts, since they never predict a downturn.

  • The IMF and Strauss Kahn

    It makes you want to join the tea party

    May 15th 2011, 12:15 by Buttonwood

    LEAVE aside the details of the allegations against Dominique Strauss Kahn, the head of the IMF (his lawyer indicates he will plead not guilty). Just note that the New York Times states that he was staying in a $3,000 a night suite and was taking a first class flight to Paris. This is the IMF, the body that imposes austerity on indebted countries and is funded by global taxpayers. And this was the likely leading socialist candidate for the French presidency.

    UPDATE: One more detail emerged this morning. According to the London Times, Mr Strauss-Kahn had an arrangment with Air France whereby he could just turn up and be put on the first plane. Tough luck, presumably, if you had paid for the flight with your own money and the IMF man wants your seat.

    SECOND UPDATE: I have been told that Mr Strauss-Kahn, a wealthy man, would have been paying for his suite himself as he was on personal business.

  • Global economy

    Running out of steam

    May 13th 2011, 16:27 by Buttonwood

    THE first quarter growth numbers from France and Germany were very impressive, even if they owed a little to a rebound from late 2010. But a look at the purchasing managers' index (see chart) is less cheery. It adds weight to the feeling that the recent fall in bond yields and commodity prices may be pointing to a slowdown. It is not yet inevitable. There was a similar fall towards 50 in 1998 (around the time of the LTCM crisis) and in 2003 that proved to be a false alarm. But if the PMIs keep falling...

  • Monetary policy

    Getting out of QE

    May 13th 2011, 15:13 by Buttonwood

    GERRY Fitt, the late (and enormously brave) Catholic politician in Northern Ireland, once told the tale of how, in the face of Protestant violence, he called the British home secretary, Jim Callaghan, in 1969 and asked him to send in the army. "I can get the Army in," Callaghan told him, "but it will be a devil of a job to get it out." (Another anecdote from Dominic Sandbrook's White Heat.)

    Getting out of QE may also be harder than starting it. Paul Marson, the chief investment officer of Lombard Odier, points to Fisher's famous equation MV=PY, where M is the money supply, V is the velocity of circulation, P is the price level and Y is income. One reason why monetarism is much more tricky in practice than in theory is that V is very unstable. One might assume that expanding the money supply with have an automatic link with higher prices in the sense of more money chasing the same amount of goods, but if V collapses, a higher M can have little effect (in the short-term at least).

    When interest rates are low, says Mr Marson, the velocity of circulation collapses since there is no opportunity cost of hoarding it. This relationship is non-linear. The corollary is that as interest rates rise, the velocity of money will increase sharply. So if the Federal Reserve allows the liquidity to stay in the economy, there will be a sudden rise in inflation expectations. As a result, reversing QE will have to be front-loaded.

    One might have assumed that any exit from QE would be an alternative to higher rates, not an accompaniment. But if Mr Marson is right, then the markets may be hit by a rate rise and the dumping of Treasury bonds simultaneously. Mr Marson also thinks this would result in a sharp rebound in the dollar as foreign capital flooded in to buy those extra bonds, and as investors reassessed their view on the currency in the light of tighter monetary policy.

    In a speech last month, Charles Plosser of the Philadelphia Fed accepted that asset sales and higher rates would have to go hand-in-hand. In addition to increasing rates

    We would also announce that between each FOMC meeting, in addition to allowing assets to run off as they mature or are prepaid, we would sell an additional specified amount of assets. These “continuous sales,” plus the natural run-off, imply that the balance sheet, and thus reserves, would gradually shrink between each FOMC meeting on an ongoing basis.

    Of course, it would be easier for the bond market to absorb this extra supply if the budget deficit was shrinking. But that implies that the best solution for getting out of QE is for both monetary and fiscal policy to get tightened at the same time, which doesn't seem right.

  • The war on savers

    About time

    May 13th 2011, 12:05 by Buttonwood

    AT LAST. The British government needs to borrow £150 billion a year but last July it withdrew one of its most popular products, index-linked national savings, apparently under pressure from the banks, who were worried about the competition. The certificates give a return that matches the rise in the retail prices index, plus a margin on top, tax-free. Since the RPI is up 5.5% year-on-year, that's a very good deal. Compare that with the best fixed rate on offer, according to moneysupermarket, of 4.01% for three years. Since the latter is taxable, that translates into 2.4% for middle-class investors on the 40% rate and 2% for the wealthiest. In post-tax terms, real rates for savers are highly negative.

    The new range of certificates offers a real yield of just 0.5%, compared with the 1% that was on offer last July. That's perfectly fair; if there is a lot of demand for a savings product, then lower the return. They could have eliminated the real rate entirely and it would still have been a good deal.

    There is always the chance, of course, that inflation may have peaked and that it will head sharply down if Britain slips back into recession. British savers (this blogger included) will be happy to take the risk. The Bank of England's job was to meet the inflation target and it failed; savers should have some way of insuring themselves against the possibility that it will fail again.

  • Government bonds

    Don't worry, be happy

    May 12th 2011, 16:27 by Buttonwood

    SCORE one point for my colleague on Free Exchange; take one point from Pimco's Bill Gross. Even though the end of QE2 is rapidly approaching, bond investors seem unconcerned about the disappearance of the Federal Reserve as buyer of last resort. Ten year yields, at 3.2%, are around 50 basis points lower than they were in February and have fallen quite sharply over the last few weeks.

    The markets may well be going through a "risk off" phase in which investors sell equities and commodities and look for a safe haven. This week's column grapples with the issue of the commodities boom and looks at three potential explanations; the normal recovery; the inflationary bubble; and the Potemkin village argument, in which commodity and asset prices have been artificially inflated.

    Although some inflation numbers may continue to look high because of the lagged impact of previous commodity rises, a continued sell-off would dent the inflationary case. The fall in bond yields would seem to confirm this isn't a worry.

    Of course, for a conventional recovery, the commodity sell-off ought to be good news, at least in the west as I argued in a previous post. But one can't rule out the Potemkin argument. After all, Ben Bernanke himself admitted that part of the success of QE was in propping up the equity market; perhaps some of the liquidity leaked into commodities as well. The Chinese increased reserve requirements again today, the European debt crisis is still rumbling on. there is just a chance that falling bond yields are not a sign of investor sang froid about inflation and the US credit rating, but an indication of fear about what's going on in the rest of the world.

  • Currencies

    Devaluation and dancing

    May 12th 2011, 9:08 by Buttonwood

    MERVYN King was on the news last night, welcoming the decline in the pound in 2008 and 2009 as a necessary adjustment to the economy. Gone are the days, it seems, when central bankers were guardians of the currency (first witness: Ben Bernanke).

    Perhaps that's right. The Labour government of 1964-70 was holed under the waterline by its initial decision to defend the value of the pound, rather than devalue. The fear of prime minister Harold Wilson was that the Labour party, which had previously devalued in 1949, would be stuck with the label of economic failure. But the result was that the government had to introduce austerity plans which dismayed its core voters. In a sense, the government was stuck in a similar trap to that which faces Greece since the options did not look good either way.

    As Dominic Sandbrook recounts in his entertaining history of the era, White Heat:

    Wilson also knew that devaluation would inevitably be accompanied by severe cuts in public spending and a rapid slowdown in consumer growth in order to release economic resources for exports

    Perhaps devaluation was more of a fear those days when most imports came in the form of raw materials and thus any fall in the value of the currency would mean a rise in inflation (a devaluation always represents a fall in the standard of living in some form).  The US worries less about this now because commodities are priced in dollars.

    Anyway, the Wilson government had some colourful characters and this gives me an excuse to recount my favourite story from the Sandbrook book. George Brown, Wilson's number two, was a less puritanical figure than his modern namesake, Gordon, although they could both throw a fair share of tantrums. George was a notorious drunk with an eye for the ladies. At a reception in Latin America

    George made a beeline for a gorgeously crimson-clad figure and said "Excuse me, can I have the pleasure of this dance?"

    There was a terrible silence for a moment before the guest, who knew who he was, replied: "There are three reasons, Mr Brown, why I will not dance with you. The first, I fear, is that you've had a little too much to drink. The second is that this is not, as you seem to suppose, a waltz the orchestra is playing but the Peruvian national anthem for which you should be standing to attention. And the third reason why we may not dance, Mr Brown, is that I am the Cardinal Archbishop of Lima

  • Pensions

    Life expectancy in the US

    May 11th 2011, 14:49 by Buttonwood

    AS IT challenges our leader line on pensions, my eye was caught by Free Exchange's blog on the retirement age in which it quotes Ezra Klein as saying that

    much of the increase in life expectancies over the past century have come from reductions in child mortality. Life expectancy at 60 has not risen by all that much, and it's risen least for poorer workers who rely most heavily on Social Security.

    It depends on what you mean by "all that much". The data from the OECD show that, since 1958, male life expectancy in the US at the retirement age has risen by four years and is expected to increase a further year by 2050, even though the pension age is set to rise to 67. For women, the improvement since 1958 has been 3.5 years and a further 2.5 is expected by 2050. Even an increase in the retirement age to 70 would thus not reclaim all that improvement.

    It is true that the improvement in US life expectancy has not been as great as in the rest of the OECD, despite the country's massive spending on health. Since 1958, OECD expectancy at retirement age has risen by five years for males and six for females which is why we suggested that the US might not have to go as far as 70. But what makes increases in the retirement age so helpful is that it boosts output while lowering the tax burden.

    The lower life expectancy of manual workers is a fair point although it has always been the case. But the issue is very well dealt with in the excellent book Working longer by Alicia Munnell and Steven Sass, published by the Brookings Institution. For example, will older people be unable to work because of ill-health? Munnell and Sass write that

    Since the early to mid 1980s, it is clear that the percentage of older working-age men with an activity limitation has declined

    and

    Between 1984 and 2004, the share of the elderly that lacked the ability to function independently with ease declined from 26.2% to 19.2%

    Even though, the health of older workers has improved, Munnell and Sass point out that

    As recently as the mid-1960s, the median retirement age for men - the age at which half of all men are no longer in the labor force - was 66. Today, it is 63.

    So given the fiscal and demographic challenges, an increase in the retirement age hardly seems unreasonable.

  • Debt crisis

    More denial

    May 11th 2011, 14:08 by Buttonwood

    A FEW weeks ago, my column was on debt denial. There could not be a clearer case of it today than in remarks by Christine Lagarde, the French finance minister, to Le Figaro about a potential Greek restructuring.

    We totally exclude it in any form. Nor is there any question of Greece leaving the Eurozone. I want to reassure investors.

    Of course, one recognizes that politicians may feel they have to say this sort of thing. Jim Callaghan, Britain's finance minister in 1967, made the mistake of prevaricating (rather than lying) ahead of sterling's devaluation that year, provoking a further run on the country's foreign exchange reserves. But as Martin Wolf argues in today's FT, it has been a year since the Greek bailout and the problem has not been solved; yields are higher than ever, and private sector investors now face a bigger loss since they have been subordinated to official creditors.

    Your blogger spent all of Tuesday chairing the Economist's bellwether conference in London which featured historians (Niall Ferguson), economists (Glenn Hubbard) and bankers (Sir Win Bischoff). It was generally agreed that Greece had no hope of repaying its debts on its own and that the only alternative would be a push to fiscal union across the euro-zone. But that would be staggeringly unpopular with the German electorate which would have to foot most of the bill, and one doubts that Christine Lagarde could sell it to French voters either.

    Alas, Greece is in a hopeless position. Leaving the euro would solve the competitiveness problem but as one speaker put it, Greece has no great industries that could take advantage. And euro departure would lead to inevitable default in any case, since its debts are denominated in euro terms. It would cause a financial crisis as Greeks took their euros out of domestic banks and stashed them overseas (it would be interesting to see whether this is happening already). Default would cut the Greeks off from the markets, requiring the country to balance its budgets meaning they would still have to impose an austerity programme. And euro departure might also cut the country off from official support from the EU.

    Default within the euro would still leave the economy dependent on its neighbours but at least the Germans and the ECB would have a more secure claim since private sector claims would be heavily discounted. But the problem is what to do about the Greek banks that own government debt; they would need rescuing as well. Of course, the reason Ms Lagarde is so wary of Greek default is that it might prompt a further run on Ireland, Portugal and (worst of all) Spain.

    Muddling through and hoping for the best is the strategy but it ain't going to work. The Greeks won't wear it (there's another national strike today); the markets won't wear it (three year Greek bond yields are nearly 25%); and German voters won't wear it either.

  • Housing

    The great divide

    May 9th 2011, 14:29 by Buttonwood

    WHILE the equity and commodity markets have surged since 2009, the asset class that started all the trouble - US housing - hasn't rallied. An overhang of foreclosed properties is still depressing the market while tighter lending standards make things difficult for bargain-hunters. The latest data suggest some 28% of homeowners are under water. But the chart, courtesy of Tim Lee of pi Economics, illustrates that US houses now look very cheap, especially if the high gold price does indicate that we are heading for a period of rapid inflation. Of course, the chart could equally show that gold is very expensive which, incidentally, is Mr Lee's view. He thinks it is around two to three time overvalued, given the fundamentals; given that gold looks in line with equities, this implies very bad news for the stockmarket.

    Over on this side of the Atlantic, the British house price bubble has failed to burst, although on the basis of the latest data, the air is slowly deflating. Why the difference? A common argument is that Britain has a shortage of supply which is supporting the market. But if that were true, then rental rates would be increasing as fast as prices themselves; however, our latest index showed that, relative to rents, British prices were 30% above average. In America, by contrast, they are roughly in line (using the Case-Shiller data). It seems more plausible that the key factor is the type of mortgage used; more Britons than Americans have variable rate loans and the sharp fall in rates has eased the pressure on their pocketbooks and led to very few foreclosures.

    But the next year or two will provide a crucial test. The coalition government's austerity programme is starting to bite. Public sector workers will come under particular pressure - facing a pay freeze, higher pension contributions and job losses - and this will weigh heavily on the bottom end of the market. This is crucial since first time buyers are needed to allow others to trade up to bigger homes (except for Mayfair where rich foreigners are seeking boltholes). The UK price-to-earnings ratio, according to Nationwide, is 4.3 for first-time buyers, still double the mid-1990s low; in London, it is 6.2, compared with 2.6 in 1995.

    If unemployment does rise, then homebuyers can get no further help from lower interest rates. Some think interest rates will rise later this year, although the dreaded date may be put off if the economy continues to stutter. That may point to a long slow grind down for British prices rather than a sudden collapse.

  • Stockmarkets

    Megacap misfire

    May 9th 2011, 12:46 by Buttonwood

    THERE are 26 stocks in the S&P 500 with a market value of more than $100 billion. According to Morgan Stanley, such companies are cheaper than they have been, relative to the rest of the market, in the past 25 years. In practical terms, this means they stand at an average 20% discount to the market's prospective price-earnings ratio. Since March 2009, the megacaps have risen 67% compared with the rest of the market's 118%.

    Similar factors seem to be at play in Europe where, according to Newton, the biggest stocks (defined as those worth over €30 billion) have risen 60% since March 2009 while the rest of the market has more than doubled.

    So what is going on? There is a potentially simple explanation for the underperformance since March 2009. During the crisis, investors will have flocked to the biggest names in the market for defensive reasons; once sentiment recovered, there was scope to find bargains in the small and midcap prices, some of which were priced as if they were going bankrupt.

    However, that factor doesn't explain the valuation discount. there might be two other explanations.  The first could be the expectation that future growth will be generated by emerging markets; while many of the megacaps are exposed to such markets, it is a relatively small part of the business. Investors may be looking for niche plays in the small and midcap areas.  However, a second explanation seems more plausible. The moment when megacaps had the highest relative value was in 1999/2000 when the TMT stocks (tech, media and telecom) were much sought-after. Now, with the odd exception such as Google and Apple, the megacap sector looks less exciting (banks, energy companies, pharamaceuticals). These may be solid businesses but it is hard to spin a story of endless double-digit profits growth.

  • Conspiracy theories

    Bin Laden and the nature of proof

    May 6th 2011, 16:51 by Buttonwood

    SO AL Qaeda has issued a statement confirming Bin Laden's death and his wife has spoken about life in the compound to the Pakistani authorities. Of course, none of this will satisfy the conspiracy theorists who will doubtless say that the Al Qaeda statement is a fake dreamed up by the CIA, Mrs bin Laden was forced into making a statement and so on. For similar reasons, no photo would have satisfied such folk (some website commenters have argued that bin Laden never existed in the first place).

    Occam's razor suggests the simplest explanation is the best. For the conspiracy to be true, both US politicians and generals would have had to colluded into it, even though they knew that the whole thing could be disproved by one bin Laden video appearance, and that plenty of people (from the Pakistani government to al Jazzera) would be keen to disprove it.

    But while it is easy to dismiss this effort, conspiracy theories abound; and did so well before the internet. David Aaronovitch's splendid book Voodoo Histories (reviewed here) deals with many, dating back to the notorious Protocol of the Elders of Zion. Proving a positive is hard enough and debunking a conspiracy theory requires one to disprove a negative. Argue the anti-conspiracy line hard enough and you will be accused of being part of the conspiracy yourself.

    Philosophers and historians have long grappled with the problem of evidence. Can we know anything except that which occurs in our direct experience? And, given the unreliability of eyewitness accounts, can we even believe that? Documentary evidence is scanty, may be inaccurate and written by a biased observer (the winning side in a war). Physical evidence is open to (too much) interpretation; think of the endless analysis of the Zapruder footage of the Kennedy assassination. Scientists are simply not believed any more by a significant section of the population when they point to evidence of, say, evolution or global warming. 

    I am not sure how much of this is new. In the first world war, both sides believed they were defending civilisation against barbarism and easily swallowed stories of atrocities by the other side. It is a perfectly understandable reaction; in the face of an unpalatable decision (going to war) we naturally tend to accept evidence (the other side are brutal or subhuman) that makes the decision justifiable. No doubt Attila the Hun told his troops that he was bringing a necessary dose of reform to the decadent Roman Empire.

    So what does all this have to do with finance? Just as we have a political view, we are just as likely to create some thesis about the markets to enable us to deal with the blizzard of information that we face; house prices can only go up, the internet will transform corporate profits, the US is about to default and so on. Once we adopt that thesis, if we are not careful, we will tenaciously defend it and dismiss all evidence to the contrary. Back in the 1980s, high Japanese p/es were dismissed as irrational; in the 1990s, the same went for dotcom stocks. As individuals, blind acceptance of such views will cause us to lose money; as societies, we can head down the path that led to 2007-2008. Our views may not be as poisonous as those of some conspiracy theorists but they still contribute to the markets being an irrational place.

  • Commodities

    When a sell-off is good news

    May 6th 2011, 9:05 by Buttonwood

    THE sharp sell-off in commodity prices yesterday seems to be continuing this morning (May 6th). It raises a whole set of questions, particularly as equities have sold off in tandem.

    Surely a sharp fall in the oil price ought to be good news? The surge in petrol prices has acted as a tax increase on western consumers, and this fall will relieve some of the pressure on their wallets. Ole Hansen of Saxo Bank says the sell-off began when the first quarter GDP numbers from the US were weaker-than-expected; yesterday's higher-than-expected weekly jobless claims exacerbated the trend. However, one of the main bullish arguments for commodities was that emerging market demand was now driving prices; that was why prices had rebounded so quickly even though the developed world recovery was still pretty weak. There is no evidence, as yet, that the Chinese economy is faltering.

    Given those fundamentals, the case for arguing that commodity prices have been driven to excess by speculators looks rather stronger. Silver is a case in point. Its strength owes nothing to fundamentals and a lot to investors seizing upon it as a "poor man's gold"; in one recent session, the silver ETF saw more trading volume than its S&P 500 equivalent. Silver's headlong rise looked very bubble-like and the CME futures exchange has increased margin requirements sharply; as Mr Hansen puts it, traders had the choice of putting up more cash or taking profits. They have clearly done the latter. (This just shows what can be done by the authorities to pop bubbles if they wish; if only lower loan-to-value regulations had been imposed in the US housing market.)

    Nevertheless, the argument that the price rise is all down to speculators is far from proven. It is noticeable that agricultural prices have held up better than most, perhaps because weather patterns are affecting the US planting season. Oil aside, food prices are the key commodity class for developing country prosperity.

    Is this the end of the commodity bull market? It is far too early to say that; there was a similar sell-off this time last year. Until demand from emerging markets slackens, or new discoveries are brought on stream, there seem likely to be bouts of upward pressure.

    The equity market sell-off could be ascribed to the same weak growth numbers that sparked the commodity decline. Nevertheless, it does draw attention to the contradictions inherent in this long bull-run. Central banks are holding interest rates low (and using QE) because the economy is weak. But if the economy is weak, why have equity and commodity prices done so well?

  • Share prices

    Dow 38,820?

    May 5th 2011, 14:27 by Buttonwood

    IF YOU want the world to notice your prediction, aim high or low. That’s a mantra that Jeffrey Hirsch, author of “Super Boom: why the Dow will hit 38,820 and how you can profit from it”, has clearly taken to heart. His book suggests that the Dow will hit the mark by 2025, just 14 years away.

    His book comes with the obligatory superlatives in the blurb - “Read Super boom or perish!” – and with a wonderfully mixed metaphor in the acknowledgment, to his father. “I proudly stand on your shoulders and prudently ride the coattails of your life’s work.” Either Jeffrey Hirsch is a circus acrobat or he has wrenched his father’s coat round his neck.

    Mr Hirsch’s father, Yale, made a successful market call in 1976 that the Dow would rise 500% from the 1974 low to 1990 and his son is trying to repeat the trick. Now readers may remember that books with the titles Dow 36,000 and Dow 100,000 came out in the late 1990s and imagine that this tome is another example of hubris. To be fair to Mr Hirsch, he deals with the Dow 36,000 book, pointing out that it was issued after a long bull run and not in the aftermath of two bear markets, as is the case with his own volume.

    Mr Hirsch says there are three elements to a super-boom: a period of peace following large-scale global military combat, dramatic inflation and an array of enabling technologies (such as auto production in the 1920s or personal computers in the 1980s).  These will be present once the Iraq/Afghanistan military involvement winds down, the current commodity inflation shows up in the oft-adjusted CPI and improvements in the energy and healthcare industries show up.

    Well, what is to be made of this argument? First, a word about the structure of the book which appears to have been edited in a rush. For example, Mr Hirsch says there was no baby boom after World War Two, which there clearly was.  Secondly, he seems to be having his cake and eating it.  At one point, he writes that

    DJIA 38,820 by 2025 is not a market forecast; it is an expectation that human ingenuity will overcome, as it has on countless past occasions throughout history.

    So is it a prediction or not? At another point he writes that

    I concur with the general concept of restrained economic growth and a lid on stock prices over the next several years. I believe we will flirt with the lower end of the market’s range during that time. A test of the market lows in the Dow 6,500-7,500 range in the 2012-2014 time frame is entirely in the cards.

    The super boom apparently will not start till 2017 on his analysis. But Mr Hirsch seems covered whether the market rises or falls over the next few years.

    Let us deal with the specifics of the argument. Are the Iraq/Afghanistan involvements really on a par with two world wars? Defence spending was more than 40% of GDP in the latter and around 14% in the former (see link). Now it’s around 6%. Secondly, Mr Hirsch’s argument seems to be that equities “catch up” with wartime inflation, hence the gains after WWI, WWII and Vietnam. But recorded inflation is very low, not just in the US, but across the developed world; is everybody massaging the figures? And even if they are, wages are not going up very fast, so high inflation is a severe cut in our standard of living, hardly a bullish sign. Third, I’d like to see a bit more evidence of these gains from new industries; pharmaceutical companies have been struggling to produce new drugs, for example, while new energy sources are dependent on subsidies.

    But the killer argument is surely that things are quite different from 1976, when Mr Hirsch’s father made his call, as the charts show. The son is relying on a huge surge in profits but corporate profits are currently above their long-term average (as a proportion of GDP) not just below as they were in 1976. Then there are valuations; the S&P 500 yielded 3.8% in 1976 as against 1.7% now. Alternatively there is the Shiller cyclically-adjusted p/e which indicated the four great market peaks of the 20th century; this is 23.3 now as against 11-12 in 1976. Although Mr Hirsch is described as a student of market history in the foreword, it’s amazing he doesn’t mention this measure, if only to rebut it. Nor can the market expect the kind of boost it received from a sharp fall in interest rates or bond yields that it did in the 1980s; indeed if inflation surges, as Mr Hirsch expects, valuations will come under threat.

    Of course, in hyperinflation, the Dow could easily get to 38,820 and indeed 388,200 but that is not something investors should wish for.

  • The debt crisis

    Locking up your money

    May 4th 2011, 10:55 by Buttonwood

    CARMEN Reinhart (of This Time is Different fame) and Belen Sbrancia have a new paper on how governments have, in the past, eliminated debt via financial repression, defined as the maintenance of artificially low real interest rates via regulations and capital controls. The paper has already featured in a post from Free Exchange and is highlighted in the latest note from Bill Gross of Pimco (you can omit page 1 with his bathrobe reminiscence).

    Reinhart and Sbrancia note that real interest rates in advanced countries were negative roughly half the time between 1945 and 1980 and this helped to reduce British and American debt by 3-4% of GDP a year. That obviously had an enormous effect in reducing the post-WWII debt burden.

    As pointed out in previous posts, there are three main ways of getting out of a debt trap; growth, default or inflation*. Many people (including the gold bugs) think that governments will go for the inflationary option but the problem with that approach is that the markets can see it coming, and will drive yields up accordingly. For the US, with an average debt maturity of under five years, it looks a very difficult option to pull off. The bond vigilantes will be watching.

    One way of heading off the vigilantes is to get the central bank to hold down yields via direct purchases as has happened in many countries. But another is to stop them from moving their money out of the way. That implies capital controls, a key element of the Bretton Woods system. As Free Exchange writes

    But it's not clear that Bretton Woods can be duplicated. Thirty years of financial liberalisation has made markets broader, deeper, and more complex. It has also created strong constituencies in favour of liberalised finance, most of which were not dislodged by the crisis. Putting the genie back in the bottle will prove very difficult.

    One of those strong constituencies, of course, is the financial sector which is already, as Pimco illustrates, starting to complain. The sector is a very effective lobbying machine, not least because it is a huge source of finance for Presidential candidates. The practical problems of restricting capital movements, in an age where money is shifted between accounts with a click of a mouse, is another issue. Nevertheless, as Reinhart and Sbrancia point out, it is possible to see some measures, such as higher bank capital ratios (creating a captive market for government bonds), as the first steps down this road.

    My view for some time has been that the crisis will create one of those epochal shifts in the international financial system, akin to the abandonment of the gold standard in the 1930s or the collapse of Bretton Woods in the 1970s. Different systems juggle the elements of the trilemma; one can have fixed exchange rates, independent monetary policy and free capital movements but not all three. The gold standard forced governments to subordinate monetary policy to the demands of the exchange rate; Bretton Woods stabilised exchange rates at the expense of capital restrictions.  

    We tend to blithely assume that the Chinese will adapt to western ways by liberalising their capital account and letting their exchange rate float. But the Chinese are the creditors now and the creditors generally set the rules, as the Americans did at Bretton Woods. Might developed governments accept the bargain of managed exchange rates and capital restrictions if this allowed them to reduce their debt burdens without taking too heavy a toll on the voters? It's just a thought.

    * There is, of course, austerity; running a fiscal surplus for years and years to gradually reduce the burden. But the record is patchy; Greece, Ireland and Portugal didn't get far down this road before they needed an EU rescue. We shall see how well Britain copes when the cuts really begin to bite. Six tube strikes have just been announced for May/June and schools may be closed in the autumn.

  • Keynes vs Hayek

    It's a rap

    May 3rd 2011, 18:19 by Buttonwood

    OUR Buttonwood conference last autumn was livened up by a rap performance from actors playing Keynes and Hayek. Now the creators Russ Roberts (of George Mason University) and John Papola have released a new video featuring the pair. It's beautifully produced (if overlong) and features a great Bernanke lookalike. Not hard to figure out Mr Roberts's sympathies lie with Hayek - although he seems to score a knockout, the referee awards Keynes the fight. This column sympathises with the view that the authorities have inflated more bubbles, but the purity of Hayek's view would have been very difficult for governments to adopt in the circumstances of 2008.

About Buttonwood's notebook

In this blog, our Buttonwood columnist grapples with the ever-changing financial markets and the motley crew who earn their living by attempting to master them.

Advertisement

Trending topics

Read comments on the site's most popular topics

Advertisement

Products & events
Stay informed today and every day

Subscribe to The Economist's free e-mail newsletters and alerts.


Subscribe to The Economist's latest article postings on Twitter


See a selection of The Economist's articles, events, topical videos and debates on Facebook.

Advertisement