Business Day



June 2, 2011, 5:00 am

The French Determination to Run the I.M.F.

Today's Economist

Simon Johnson, the former chief economist at the International Monetary Fund, is the co-author of “13 Bankers.”

Andrew Harrer/Bloomberg News

Just a few years ago, euro-zone countries were at the forefront of those saying that the International Monetary Fund had lost its relevance and should be downsized. French authorities regarded the I.M.F. as so marginal that President Nicolas Sarkozy was happy to put forward the name of a potential rival, Dominique Strauss-Kahn, as a candidate for its managing director, in fall 2007.

Today the French government is working overtime to make sure that a Sarkozy loyalist, the leader of his economic team — Finance Minister Christine Lagarde — becomes the next managing director. Why do France and other euro-zone countries now care so much about who runs the I.M.F.?

The euro currency union has a serious problem, to be sure, with the likes of Greece, Ireland and Portugal, but it is beyond bizarre that these countries are borrowing from the I.M.F., which typically lends hard currency to countries that have balance-of-payments crises — they have been importing more than they were exporting, while the private-sector capital inflows (typically loans of some kind) that financed this current account deficit have dried up.

Greece has a current account deficit, but its money, the euro, is one of the world’s hardest currencies — a reserve currency in which central banks and private business keep their rainy-day funds (as are dollars, yen, Swiss francs and, perhaps, British pounds). The euro zone as a whole does not have a current account deficit.

I vividly recall discussions with euro-zone authorities in 2007 — when I was chief economist at the I.M.F. — in which they argued that current-account imbalances within the euro zone had no meaning and were not the business of the I.M.F.

Their argument was that the I.M.F. was not concerned with payment imbalances between the various American states (all, of course, using the dollar), and it should likewise back away from discussing the fact that some euro-zone countries, like Germany and the Netherlands, had large surpluses in their current accounts while Greece, Spain and others had big deficits.

Those euro-zone treasury and central bank officials had a point. After all, if one deficit country got into trouble, it could be helped out by other members of the currency union. As the euro is a reserve currency — and a highly regarded one; for example, it remains strong relative to the dollar — the I.M.F. is now essentially lending euros to the euro zone through its various bailout programs.

Does this make sense?

No, unless you understand that the goal of these various bailouts is to ensure that German and French taxpayers do not realize the full extent of their losses or appreciate the ways in which their banks have been mismanaged.

Take the most generous interpretation of I.M.F. lending to Greece: that it is like the Troubled Asset Relief Program in the United States, in the sense that a great deal of money will be laid out but all or most of it will be repaid in nominal terms.

Such lending could just as easily be made by other euro-zone countries, from current resources or by borrowing in the markets. Germany, for example, has plenty of fiscal credibility and issues some of the lowest-risk sovereign debt available. But even if all the money lent to Greece in this fashion were repaid, this would look bad — to German voters (and to French voters, because France would have to lend, too).

Such loans are much more risky than commonly supposed. The I.M.F. does eventually get its money back nominally, but not always in real terms (adjusted for inflation) and not on a risk-adjusted basis (that is, the interest rate charged does not include proper compensation for the risks being taken). There is a very real possibility that some or all of the monies lent will not be paid back in the foreseeable future.

The I.M.F., which is, in this regard, essentially a credit union owned by 187 countries — with voting based on ownership shares that reflect relative economic size. The European Union owns about 30 percent of the I.M.F., so 70 percent of any money at risk belongs to other countries: about 17 percent to the United States, 7 percent to Japan, 35 percent to emerging-market nations and the rest to other countries.

The managing director of the I.M.F. is the impresario of any bailout and oversees the big decisions that must be negotiated with all significant stakeholders. This leaves enormous scope for discretion.

Ms. Lagarde, or any managing director, could directly influence the terms of I.M.F. involvement — and based on her negotiating position to date within the euro zone, we can presume she will lean toward more money, easier terms and, above, all no losses for the banks that made foolish loans.

Increasingly, it looks as though the euro-zone leadership, under French guidance, will go for the full-bailout option, in which all Greek debt is bought by the I.M.F., the European Central Bank and other euro-zone entities. This debt will be held to maturity — and any creditor who did not yet sell will be made whole (those who have already sold at a loss are out of luck).

This course of action will be expensive, in terms of nominal outlays and in real risk-adjusted terms, because whatever terms Greece gets must also be offered to Ireland and Portugal. The I.M.F. may need to raise more capital or, more likely, tap its credit lines from member governments. (To be clear, the full bailout is painful for the debtor countries; their fiscal adjustments will involve spending cuts, tax increases and asset sales.)

The Europeans greatly fear their own “Lehman moment,” in which any attempt to impose even moderate losses on creditors will cause chaos throughout the financial system. The French and Germans fought hard against increasing capital requirements under Basel III and the results of various European banking stress tests have been completely noncredible — particularly because they did not take into account serious sovereign-debt default scenarios.

The French want to sway decision-making at the I.M.F. in order to use money from the United States, Japan and poorer countries to conceal from their own electorate that the euro-zone structure has led all its members into fiscal jeopardy: some borrowed heavily; others let their banks lend irresponsibly and thus created a large contingent liability.

The best way to hide the true cost is to have other people’s taxpayers foot the bill, preferably with the least possible transparency. Thus, euro-zone politicians have a lot at stake, and look for Ms. Lagarde to run the I.M.F.


Featured Economix Posts

  • Can We Afford the Military Budget?

    While many nations have cut military spending since the end of the Cold War, the United States has scarcely done so — and now needs to rethink its military priorities, an economist writes.

  • How to Cut Child Poverty in Half

    Britain’s success in reducing child poverty offers lessons for the United States in both policy and political will, an economist writes.

  • Producing More Primary-Care Doctors

    An economist asks whether medical students would respond to financial incentives that steer them to primary care rather than specializations.

  • The Economics of Men Behaving Badly

    Why do powerful men with so much to lose do such stupid things? The risk-reward tradeoff doesn’t seem to make sense. Some economic studies may shed some light on this question, though.

  • The Banking Emperor Has No Clothes

    Treasury Secretary Timothy F. Geithner seems to be marching determinedly in the wrong direction on banking regulation, an economist writes.

  • Labor Supply Always Matters

    It is supply — the huge number of students seeking full-time work — that drives the labor markets in the summer, rather than demand, an economist writes.

  • What Your Taxes Do (and Don’t) Buy for You

    The notion that Europeans pay much higher taxes that Americans does not acknowledge that in return they generally receive health care, an economist writes.

  • Vermont’s Move Toward Single-Payer Health Insurance

    A new universal health plan in Vermont represents a left-wing alternative to the changes being put into effect at the federal level, an economist writes.

  • The Virtues of Investing in Transportation

    Spending more on transportation — and spending it wisely — would create jobs and improve the nation’s competitiveness, an economist writes.

  • The French Determination to Run the I.M.F.

    The French government would like the I.M.F. to help keep its electorate in the dark about banking problems, an economist writes.

Economic Indicators

Staff Contributors

Catherine Rampell Catherine Rampell is an economics reporter for The New York Times.

David Leonhardt David Leonhardt writes the Economic Scene column, which appears in The Times on Wednesdays.

Motoko Rich

Motoko Rich is an economics reporter for The New York Times.

Steven Greenhouse

Steven Greenhouse writes about labor and workplace issues for The New York Times.

Liz Alderman

Liz Alderman writes about European economics, finance and business from Paris.

Jack Ewing

Jack Ewing writes about European economics and business from Frankfurt.

Daily Economists

Daily Economists

Economists offer readers insights about the dismal science.

Bruce Bartlett
Former Treasury Official
Nancy Folbre
University of Massachusetts-Amherst
Simon Johnson
M.I.T./Peterson Institute
Casey B. Mulligan
University of Chicago
Uwe E. Reinhardt
Princeton University
Judith Scott-Clayton
Columbia University
Laura D'Andrea Tyson
University of California, Berkeley

About This Blog

Economics doesn't have to be complicated. It is the study of our lives — our jobs, our homes, our families and the little decisions we face every day. Here at Economix, Catherine Rampell, David Leonhardt and other contributors will analyze the news and use economics as a framework for thinking about the world. We welcome feedback, at economix@nytimes.com.

Multimedia

Breaking Down the Bailout
Tracking the Bailout

An accounting of the government’s rescue package.

How the Government Dealt With Past Recessions
How the Government Dealt With Past Recessions

Three economists explain what worked and what didn’t.

Geography of a Recession
Geography of a Recession

A map of unemployment rates across the United States, now through January.

Living With Less

Faces, numbers and stories from behind the downturn.

Special Features

The Debt Trap

debt trapA series about the surge in consumer debt and the lenders who made it possible.

The Reckoning

wind powerA series exploring the origins of the financial crisis, from Washington to Wall Street.

Archive